Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Entries and Withdrawals: Electoral Coordination across Different Offices and the Brazilian Party Systems

Abstract

In this article, we present new data on electoral alliances (coligações) that were formed to contest Brazilian general elections between 1986 and 2014. We present evidence to show that alliances formed for gubernatorial and lower house elections are connected to one another. These joint alliances are part of complex coordination strategies for managing the entry and withdrawal of candidates for concomitant elections regulated by different rules. As we shall show, these joint strategies result in: 01. interlinked processes of party concentration in subnational executive elections, and party fragmentation in national lower-house elections; which is the result of 02. the emergence of political parties that specialize in contesting elections for different political offices.

Keywords:
Electoral coordination; electoral alliance; party system fragmentation; gubernatorial elections; House of Representatives


In this article, we present new data that includes all the electoral alliances1 1 We translate "coligações” as electoral alliances instead of the coalitions. We do so to stress that these are alliances formed for electoral purposes and that they do not have any "necessary” consequences for government in the legislative arena. It is important to stress that these are formal alliances that have to be confirmed by party conventions. formed for general elections in Brazil between 1986 and 2014. We show that electoral alliances for state governor and for the House of Representatives (HR) express complementary aspects of a same coordination process of entries and withdrawals in concomitant electoral contests conducted according to different principles (majoritarian and proportional). The immediate consequence of this process is the reduction of the number of viable competitors in sub-national executive elections with a corresponding multiplication of competitors in elections for the HR. This results from the emergence of political parties that are specialized in contesting elections for different political offices. The final result is, simultaneously, a reduction of party fragmentation in sub-national executive elections alongside an intensification of fragmentation in HR elections.

The literature on electoral alliances in Brazil is enormous—perhaps one of the largest in Brazilian political science. Some of the main research stems from Soares's (1964)SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon (1964), Alianças e coligações eleitorais: notas para uma teoria. Revista Brasileira de Estudos Políticos. № 17, pp. 95-124. original idea that parties join alliances for strategic reasons, that is, to maximize gains while minimizing effort (see, for example, BRAGA, 2006BRAGA, Maria do Socorro (2006), Dinâmica de coordenação eleitoral em regime presidencialista e federativo: determinantes e consequencias das coligações partidarias no Brasil. In: Reforma política: lições da historia recente. Edited by SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon and RENNÓ, Lucio R.. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Getúlio Vargas. pp.228-248.; DANTAS, 2007DANTAS, Humberto (2007), Coligações em eleiçoes majoritárias municipais: a lógica do alinhamento dos partidos políticos brasileiros nas disputas de 2000 e 2004. Doctoral thesis. Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Ciencias Humanas. Universidade de São Paulo.; KRAUSE, 2005KRAUSE, Silvana (2005), Uma análise comparativa das estratégias eleitorais nas eleições majoritárias (1994-1998-2002): coligaçoes eleitorais X nacionalização dos partidos e do sistema partidario brasileiro. In: Partidos e coligações eleitorais no Brasil. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana, and SCHMITT, Rogério. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. UNESP, pp. 115-142.; LAVAREDA, 1991LAVAREDA, Antonio (1991), A democracia nas urnas: o processo eleitoral brasileiro. Rio de Janeiro: IUPERJ/Rio Fundo Editora. 187 pp..; LIMA JR., 1983LIMA JR., Olavo Brasil de (1983) Os partidos políticos brasileiros: a experiencia federal e regional: 1945-1964. Rio de Janeiro: Graal. 157 pp..; MIGNOZZETTI et al., 2011MIGNOZZETTI, Umberto Guarnier; GALDINO, Manoel, and BERNABEL, Rodolpho (2011), Um modelo para explicar as coligações eleitorais para a Câmara federal brasileira (1998-2006). Revista Política Hoje. Vol. 20, № 02, pp. 741-788.; NICOLAU, 1996NICOLAU, Jairo Marconi (1996), Multipartidarismo e democracia: um estudo sobre o sistema partidário brasileiro (1985-1994). Rio de Janeiro: FGV. 120 pp..; SANTOS, 1987SANTOS, Wanderley Guilherme (1987), Crise e castigo: partidos e generais na política brasileira. São Paulo: Vértice. 208 pp..). Most studies, however, have concentrated on describing the characteristics of electoral alliances and on examining - as Soares (1964)SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon (1964), Alianças e coligações eleitorais: notas para uma teoria. Revista Brasileira de Estudos Políticos. № 17, pp. 95-124. did for the years 1960-1962 - whether alliances have ideological consistency (see, for example, CARREIRÃO, 2006CARREIRÃO, Yan (2006), Ideologia e partidos políticos: um estudo sobre coligações em Santa Catarina. Opinião Pública. Vol. 12, № 01, pp. 136-163.; LEONI, 2011LEONI, Eduardo (2011), Coligações e ideologia nas eleições para vereadores no Brasil: uma analise econométrica. In: O Congresso por ele mesmo: autopercepções da classe política brasileira. Edited by POWER, Thimoty. J. and ZUCCO JR., Cesar. Belo Horizonte: UFMG. pp. 42-73.; MACHADO, 2005MACHADO, Aline (2005), A lógica das coligações no Brasil. In: Partidos e coligações eleitorais no Brasil. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana and SCHMITT, Rogério. São Paulo, Rio de Janeiro: Editora Fundação Konrad Adenauer and UNESP. pp. 43-83.; MIGNOZZETTI et al., 2011MIGNOZZETTI, Umberto Guarnier; GALDINO, Manoel, and BERNABEL, Rodolpho (2011), Um modelo para explicar as coligações eleitorais para a Câmara federal brasileira (1998-2006). Revista Política Hoje. Vol. 20, № 02, pp. 741-788.; NOVAES, 1994NOVAES, Carlos Alberto Marques (1994), Dinâmica institucional da representação: individualismo e partidos na câmara dos deputados. Novos Estudos. Vol. 38, pp. 99-147.; SCHMITT, 2000SCHMITT, Rogério Augusto (2000), Partidos políticos no Brasil (1945-2000). Rio de Janeiro: J. Zahar. 96 pp..; SOUZA, 2010SOUZA, Vivaldo de (2010), Reeleição de governadores e posicionamento ideológico das coligações eleitorais nas eleições de 1998, 2002 e 2006. In: Coligações partidárias na nova democracia brasileira: perfis e tendencias. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana; DANTAS, Humberto, and MIGUEL, Luis Felipe. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. ENESP. pp. 135-165.).

While such research has tended to privilege alliances formed to contest seats for the HR, this is changing. Research on alliances for other offices has grown, including research that links alliances formed for different types of office (BORGES and LLOYD, 2016BORGES, André, and LLOYD, Ryan (2016), Presidential coattails and electoral coordination in multilevel elections: comparative lessons from Brazil. Electoral Studies. Vol. 43, pp.104-114.; CARREIRÃO and NASCIMENTO, 2010CARREIRÃO, Yan S. and NASCIMENTO, Fernanda Paula (2010), As coligações nas eleições para os cargos de governador, senador, deputado federal e deputado estadual no Brasil (1986/2006). Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política. № 04, pp. 75-104.; DANTAS, 2007DANTAS, Humberto (2007), Coligações em eleiçoes majoritárias municipais: a lógica do alinhamento dos partidos políticos brasileiros nas disputas de 2000 e 2004. Doctoral thesis. Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Ciencias Humanas. Universidade de São Paulo.; KRAUSE and GODOI, 2010KRAUSE, Silvana and GODOI, Pedro (2010), Coligações eleitorais para os executivos estaduais (1986-2006): padrões e tendâncias. In: Coligações partidárias na nova democracia brasileira: perfis e tendencias. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana; DANTAS, Humberto, and MIGUEL, Luis Felipe. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. ENESP, pp. 41-99.; MIRANDA, 2013MIRANDA, Geralda L. (2013), Coligações eleitorais: tendências e racionalidades nas eleições federais e majoritárias estaduais (1990-2010). Revista de Sociologia Política. Vol. 21, № 47, pp. 69-90.; SOARES, 2013SOARES, Marcia Miranda (2013), Influencia majoritária em eleições proporcionais: os efeitos presidenciais e governatoriais sobre as eleições para a câmara dos deputados brasileira (1994-2010). Dados. Vol. 56, № 02, pp.413-437.). This article follows this new line of research, from a perspective that has been largely neglected since Lavareda (1991)LAVAREDA, Antonio (1991), A democracia nas urnas: o processo eleitoral brasileiro. Rio de Janeiro: IUPERJ/Rio Fundo Editora. 187 pp..: we investigate the link between the alliances formed for gubernatorial elections and those formed to contest the seats in the Lower House. However, we are not interested in the ideological or partisan consistency of these alliances, and much less the extent to which these decisions affect voters via coattail effects between different offices (see BORGES and LLOYD, 2016BORGES, André, and LLOYD, Ryan (2016), Presidential coattails and electoral coordination in multilevel elections: comparative lessons from Brazil. Electoral Studies. Vol. 43, pp.104-114.; SAMUELS, 2005SAMUELS, David J. (2005), The gubernatorial coattails effect: federalism and congressional elections in Brazil. The Journal of Politics. Vol. 62, № 01, pp. 240-253.; SHUGART and CAREY, 1992SHUGART, Mathew Soberg and CAREY, John M. (1992), Presidents and assemblies: constitutional design and electoral dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 332 pp..; SOARES, 2013SOARES, Marcia Miranda (2013), Influencia majoritária em eleições proporcionais: os efeitos presidenciais e governatoriais sobre as eleições para a câmara dos deputados brasileira (1994-2010). Dados. Vol. 56, № 02, pp.413-437.).

Rather, our emphasis constitutes a return to the original strategic analysis of Soares (1964)SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon (1964), Alianças e coligações eleitorais: notas para uma teoria. Revista Brasileira de Estudos Políticos. № 17, pp. 95-124.. We stress, though, that strategic decisions are made in a game where alliances for governor and for representatives are negotiated and formed simultaneously. As we will show, this pre-coordination of entries for different electoral contests is the backbone of the national party system in Brazil. As such, we endorse the interpretations of Abrucio (1998)ABRUCIO, Fernando Luiz (1998), Os barões da federação: os governadores e a redemocra-tização brasileira. São Paulo: Hucitec/USP. 253 pp.. and Samuels (2003)SAMUELS, David J. (2003), Ambition, federalism, and legislative politics in Brazil. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 248 pp.., for whom gubernatorial elections are the epicenter of politics in Brazil. However, we adopt a different perspective. Our focus centers on a stage prior to the electoral process: that of launching candidacies. We place the gubernatorial race at the center of this process for two reasons.

First, given their political and financial resources, governorships are the most important elected offices in the country after the presidency. Second, electoral legislation itself makes elections for state governments the central axis for the formation of electoral alliances. It determines that all alliances for offices elected by proportional representation (as is the case of HR elections) in a given state must be a subset of the alliance for majoritarian offices (which is the case of gubernatorial elections) in the same state.

This means that party elites engage in a typical electoral coordination game (COX, 1997COX, Gary (1997), Making votes count: strategic coordination in the World's electoral systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 360 pp..) within each district (state), but they also negotiate entries and withdrawals for all concomitant electoral contests — for governor, senator and representatives (national and state). That is to say, the optimal entry strategy for a given party in a given state has to consider the combined effects of this decision over all majoritarian and proportional elections taking place simultaneously. Also, in Brazil decisions about entries are not dichotomous. A party may decide not to have its own candidate for governor, but it may still participate in the election indirectly by supporting the candidate of another party. The party that withdraws from a gubernatorial election and then formally enters into an electoral alliance led by another party, almost always does so in exchange for being included in the alliance for the House of Representative elections.

The reason for that is well known: the Open-List Proportional System adopted in Brazil allocates seats per electoral alliances, hence votes cast for a party can - and usually do - benefit an alliance partner. In fact, it has already been shown that electoral alliances for the Lower Chamber are one of the causes of the high level of party fragmentation in the Brazilian legislature (BRAGA and ROMA, 2002BRAGA, Maria do Socorro and ROMA, Celso (2002), Sistema partidário, eleições e a questão federativa no Brasil (1986-2000). In: Partidos no cone sul: novos ângulos de pesquisa. Edited by PINTO, Céli Regina and SANTOS, André Marenco dos. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad Andenauer Stiftung. Vol. 01, pp. 47-82.; DALMORO and FLEISCHER, 2005DALMORO, Jefferson and FLEISCHER, David (2005), Eleição proporcional: os efeitos das coligaçoes e o problema da proporcionalidade. In: Partidos e coligações eleitorais no Brasil. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana e SCHMITT, Rogério. Rio de Janeiro/SãoPaulo: Konrad-Adenauer Stiftung/Editora Unesp. pp. 85-113.; NICOLAU, 1996NICOLAU, Jairo Marconi (1996), Multipartidarismo e democracia: um estudo sobre o sistema partidário brasileiro (1985-1994). Rio de Janeiro: FGV. 120 pp..), specifically because alliances for proportional elections in Brazil end up transferring seats from big parties to small ones (see, among others, CALVO et al., 2015CALVO, Ernesto; GUARNIERI, Fernando, and LIMONGI, Fernando (2015), Why coalitions? Party system fragmentation, small party bias, and preferential vote in Brazil. Electoral Studies. Vol. 39, pp. 219-229.; DANTAS and PRAÇA, 2010DANTAS, Humberto and PRAÇA, Sérgio (2010), Pequenos partidos no Brasil: uma analise do posicionamento ideológico com base nas coligações municipais de 2000 a 2008. In: Coligações partidárias na nova democracia brasileira: perfis e tendâncias. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana; DANTAS, Humberto, and MIGUEL, Luis Felipe. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. UNESP. pp. 99-133., 2010; MACHADO, 2005MACHADO, Aline (2005), A lógica das coligações no Brasil. In: Partidos e coligações eleitorais no Brasil. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana and SCHMITT, Rogério. São Paulo, Rio de Janeiro: Editora Fundação Konrad Adenauer and UNESP. pp. 43-83.; NASCIMENTO et al., 2016NASCIMENTO, Willber; SILVA JR., José Alexandre da; PARANHOS, Ranulfo; SILVA, Denisson and FIGUEIREDO F○, Dalson Britto (2016), Does size matter? Electoral performance of small parties in Brazil. Brazilian Political Science Review. Vol. 10, № 02, pp. 01-26.; RODRIGUES, 1995RODRIGUES, Leôncio Martins (1995), Eleições, fragmentação partidaria e governabilidade. Novos Estudos CEBRAP. Vol. 41, № 01, pp. 78-90.). However, the consequences of alliances for gubernatorial elections are rarely discussed, much less the relationship between these and alliances for proportional elections.

Considering the fact that both types of alliances are formed through joint, interdependent decisions, we propose that the notorious level of party fragmentation in the HR is actually the other face of the alliance formation process which seeks to maximize the chances of success for gubernatorial candidates. In other words, we argue that the partisan concentration in sub-national executive elections is interwoven with the fragmentation of the HR, and that they are both defined by parties’ strategies of entry, which, depending on their relative strength, privilege different offices.

To address this point empirically, we start by showing that the dominant strategy of electoral entry adopted by Brazilian parties is to build alliances. It is already known that this happens in proportional elections, but we show that this is also the rule for gubernatorial elections. Almost all Brazilian political parties participate in gubernatorial contests in all states; a small minority with their own candidates and the majority as members of alliances. Hence, while the number of parties with candidates for the HR has been increasing, the number of parties with nominal candidacies for state government has either decreased or at most remained steady. The number of parties that lead an alliance, that is, those that have their own candidates to gubernatorial races, is limited.

Next, we show that this scenario is also reflected in final electoral results. To do this, we run a simulation that demonstrates that the parties who most lose HR seats due to the existence of alliances are precisely those who are at the head of gubernatorial alliance. Conversely, the parties who benefit the most from proportional alliances are those which opt to not run their own candidates for governor. With this analysis we go beyond existing research to more clearly identify the winners and losers from proportional alliance and thus, we substitute the usual typology—big versus small parties—for another that refers to the state-wide contexts within which elections take place.

This leads naturally to the question identified by Lavareda (1991)LAVAREDA, Antonio (1991), A democracia nas urnas: o processo eleitoral brasileiro. Rio de Janeiro: IUPERJ/Rio Fundo Editora. 187 pp..: why would big parties accept this equilibrium—which seems sub-optimal for them—in which smaller parties take their seats? His hypothesis about the elections of the period 1950-1962 was that the big parties negotiated political support for gubernatorial elections, “in which even a small contingent of votes directed by a small party or leadership in isolation could be vital at the polls (or even before) to the extent that they would give the appearance of strength and help make candidacies viable” (LAVAREDA, 1991LAVAREDA, Antonio (1991), A democracia nas urnas: o processo eleitoral brasileiro. Rio de Janeiro: IUPERJ/Rio Fundo Editora. 187 pp.., p. 116). Nicolau (1996)NICOLAU, Jairo Marconi (1996), Multipartidarismo e democracia: um estudo sobre o sistema partidário brasileiro (1985-1994). Rio de Janeiro: FGV. 120 pp.. suggested that, because of heterogeneity at the state level in terms of party size, forming alliances for the HR were in the interest of both small and big parties, thereby privileging the contextual rationality introduced by Lima Jr. (1983)LIMA JR., Olavo Brasil de (1983) Os partidos políticos brasileiros: a experiencia federal e regional: 1945-1964. Rio de Janeiro: Graal. 157 pp.. in his study of the pre-1964 period. Other authors such as Braga (2006)BRAGA, Maria do Socorro (2006), Dinâmica de coordenação eleitoral em regime presidencialista e federativo: determinantes e consequencias das coligações partidarias no Brasil. In: Reforma política: lições da historia recente. Edited by SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon and RENNÓ, Lucio R.. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Getúlio Vargas. pp.228-248. and Melo and Saez (2007)MELO, Carlos Ranulfo and SAEZ, Manuel Alcantara (eds) (2007), A democracia brasileira: balanço e perspectivas para o Século 21. Belo Horizonte: Editora UFMG. 488 pp.. also followed this line of argument and suggested, in passing, that campaign time on radio and television could offer a viable explanation.

We revive these arguments and make Lavareda's suggestion (1991) more concrete. For parties with a chance in gubernatorial contests, what is at stake when an alliance is built (besides getting potential opponents out of the way) is the competition for (and the transfer of) electoral resources like fractions of time in the Free Electoral Advertising Slot (Horario Gratuito de Propaganda Eleitoral - HGPE) on TV and radio. Forming alliances increases the amount of time available for candidates while reducing that of their direct competitors. We present new data that provide evidence for this strategy. Based on electoral results and data supplied by electoral courts, we estimate the percentage of the HGPE that each candidate for governor in Brazil has had since 1986. With this, we show that in gubernatorial elections there has been a strong correlation between the candidate's fraction of the HGPE and her electoral performance in the first round. We also show that alliances assure the predominance of big parties and reduce the effective number of direct competitors in gubernatorial elections.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. The second section introduces our database and the simulations that we carried out. The third section defines the object of study—strategies for launching candidacies for gubernatorial and HR elections—and shows how these strategies are circumscribed by the legislation that regulates both the formation of alliances and the distribution of HGPE time. The fourth section brings in a simulation of HR seats in the absence of proportional alliance, as well as cross-checking HGPE distribution with the electoral performance of gubernatorial candidates. In addition to this, we discuss the consequences of the strategies identified in the previous section for the structure and development of the Brazilian party framework. The last section presents our conclusions.

Data and methodology

Official datasets from the Electoral Repository of the Superior Electoral Court (TSE)2 2 URL: <http://www.tse.jus.br/eleitor-e-eleicoes/estatisticas/repositorio-de-dados-eleitorais-1/repositorio-de-dados-eleitorais>. do not contain information about the composition of the electoral alliances, in terms of parties, that were formed for the elections of 1994, 1998, 2006, and 2010. For some office- years, the official source only had the name of the alliance. For 1994, all official data, including nominal electoral results, were restricted to only 16 states. The parties that made up each alliance are identified only for the elections of 1986, 2002, and 2014, but in the case of 1986 (and, in part, 2002 as well), the data contain inconsistencies and are incomplete.

Such limitations have made researchers either restrict the timespan of their analyses, privilege big parties and big alliances, or use unofficial data. Originally built for tests conducted in Vasselai (2015)VASSELAI, Fabricio (2015), Nationalization and localism in electoral systems and party systems. Doctoral thesis. Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Ciencias Humanas. Universidade de São Paulo., the database that we use solves these problems. To create the database, we complemented the online repository data with internal TSE data obtained over several years through direct contact with TSE technical staff. Some sources, such as electoral reports, are digital, whereas others were obtained personally in print. In some cases, information was collected directly from state-level Regional Electoral Courts. Through these primary materials, we have manually reconstructed information about which parties were members of each electoral alliance for every non-municipal election between 1986 and 2014, including complete coverage of the 1994 elections. The analyses presented in this article therefore take into account all alliances and candidacies during the period 1986-2014.

We first use our data set to construct descriptive statistics about electoral entries and alliances. Next, we use our data to simulate the party composition of the HR if electoral alliances had not been allowed. In other words, we implement an algorithm that replicated the TSE's calculations for the distribution of seats—in accordance with the legislation that was in effect in each year—but without considering the transfers of votes between parties that takes place within alliances3 3 To simulate precisely the number of legislators that would be elected by each party in the House of Representatives if there were no alliances, it is necessary to know not only the number of votes for each candidate, but also the number of votes that each party received solely for the party itself. In 1986 and 1990, the official electoral results in some states (including records from the results of vote counts) do not differentiate between votes for specific parties in the case of alliances. In these few cases, we imputed the number of votes for each party in the electoral alliance based on the percentage of votes for individual candidates within each party. . In addition to this, for each year-state-party, we identified the type of electoral entry in the gubernatorial election (e.g. head or member of alliance, solo candidate). As a result, we make it possible to link the participation of parties in gubernatorial elections to gains and losses of seats in the HR.

Finally, we use our data to calculate the distribution of HGPE time for every candidate for governor in every state since 1986. We follow all the nuances of each of the many laws that regulated these elections, and even manually identify the number of seats held by every party in the national legislature for the official dates used by the TSE to allocate HGPE. Finally, we refer to information obtained from various Regional Electoral Courts (TREs), such as media plans and HGPE distribution records, as well as consultations with the press, in order to validate these estimations.

Running candidates: parties' entry strategies

In every election, parties come face-to-face with a basic choice: to enter an electoral contest or not. Obviously, this decision takes into account the costs and benefits involved in running candidates. Since Duverger (1954)DUVERGER, Maurice (1954), Political parties: their organization and activity in the modern state. London: Methuen. 439 pp.., it has been assumed that parties tend to prudently withdraw from races in which they believe they have slim chances of success. In these cases, expected costs exceed expected returns. The optimal decision of each party depends, however, on the decisions made by others potential entrants. Thus, before the beginning of the electoral process, party elites find themselves involved in a complex game of entry coordination. This inter-elite electoral coordination (COX, 1997COX, Gary (1997), Making votes count: strategic coordination in the World's electoral systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 360 pp..) becomes even more complicated when there are multiple simultaneous elections for different offices, many of which are held under different electoral principles (majoritarian or proportional representation, one or two rounds, etc), as is the case in Brazil.

As a result, in Brazilian general elections, parties must decide, in every state, if they will enter each race or withdraw from it—this applies to elections for governor, federal and state representatives, and senator. These decisions about entry, however, are not dichotomous since parties have the possibility of forming electoral alliances. If a party joins an alliance for an office whose election is regulated by the majoritarian principle, it may not have its own candidate but still participate in the election by supporting the candidate(s) of other parties. For PR elections, all members of an alliance provide candidates for the joint list. Therefore, in this scenario, electoral coordination gives rise to a multi-level game between parties that hinges on decisions over where and for which offices each will offer candidates. Figure 01 shows the possible forms of entry for Brazilian parties.

Graph 1
Decision trees for electoral entries and withdrawals

Since the removal of the “authoritarian rubble” in the 1986 election, legislation has allowed for the formation of electoral alliances, re-instating the practice of the Third Republic (1945-1964). One point that is often overlooked about alliance formation, however, is that under current legislation4 4 Electoral alliances were regulated by Article 140 of the Electoral Code of 1950. This article said nothing about the relationship between electoral alliances formed to contest elections for different offices. alliances for majoritarian and proportional elections are no longer independent from one another. Article 06 of Law 7493, which regulated the 1986 election, allowed “political parties to establish alliances to register candidates for majoritarian elections, proportional elections, or both”, but paragraph 12 of this article established that it would be “forbidden for political parties to establish different alliances for majoritarian elections and proportional elections”. The intention of this rule was clear: alliances at these two electoral levels should maintain a certain consistency. However, the rule was strategically interpreted as: whoever forms an alliance to contest elections for the state government should also make alliances to dispute proportional elections — that is, elections for the HR or state-level Legislative Assemblies. As important, if not more so, was the logical complement to this: whoever did not form an alliance for governor would not form an alliance for proportional elections. By linking the two entry decisions to one another, the rule discouraged solo entries (single-party candidacies) in gubernatorial elections.

As always, the application of the rule was much more complicated than expected. The law contained some ambiguities and loopholes that led to some legal squabblings over its meaning and concrete application. The law, for example, does not seem to take into account the existence of two simultaneous majoritarian elections - one for governor and another for senator. In the 1990 and 1994 elections, which were regulated by specific legislation and regulations5 5 In this case, Law 7664/1988 (Article 08) and Resolutions/TSE 16347/90 and 16557/90 are relevant, as is Law 8713/1993 (Article 06). , new loopholes and ambiguities led to slightly different applications of the rule across different states, but the rule that alliances had to be identical (or that a party in alliance for a gubernatorial election had to run alone for Senate and proportional elections) was generally in effect. In practice, the alliance formed for the election of the state government subordinated the others, establishing the reference point around which other alliances had to maintain consistency.

With the enactment of Law N° 9504/97, the general law of elections, a legal framework was established, and the subject became regulated by its Article 06, according to which: “Political parties are, within the same electoral restrictions, allowed to establish alliances for majoritarian elections, proportional elections, or both, making it possible, in this last case, to form more than one alliance for proportional elections among the parties that make up the alliance for the majoritarian election”.

We argue that the interpretation of this principle that has prevailed in practice is that the majoritarian alliance should contain the proportional one. In other words, suppose that there are N parties p1 …pN in the country and that, in a given state, p1 runs a candidate for governor while p2 and p3 opt not to, forming an alliance for governor G = {p1,p2,p3}. In this same state, for any alliance D for the HR that contains any one of these parties, it should be true that D Ç G. As such, the possible combinations of alliances for the HR would be: D′ = {p1}, D" = {p2}, D′" = {p3}; or D′ = {p1,p2},D" = {p3}; or D′ = {p1,p3},D″ = {p2}; or D′ = {p1}, D″ = {p2,p3}; or D = {p1,p2,p3}. What this means is that, on the one hand, an alliance to contest a proportional election must be formed between parties that are not competing in majoritarian elections (not even as members of different alliances). On the other hand, it also means that parties who do not form an alliance for the gubernatorial election cannot be in the same alliances for proportional elections.

The consequence of this directive is evident: it increases the overall cost of running for governor. A party that is not sure of its electoral viability for governor receives an obvious incentive from the electoral legislation to withdraw from the gubernatorial race and to seek shelter in an alliance that would help it in the proportional contests. For a party with this profile, the withdrawal of its own candidate for the gubernatorial race appears prudent not only in order to avoid wasting resources with a long-shot candidacy, but also to avoid the even greater waste of not being able to count on allies who could transfer votes in the election for the HR. Consequently, as opposed to the traditional Duvergerian framework in which parties only consider the consequences of their decision for one race, in the Brazilian case, they make a joint decision, that is, they consider the effects for majoritarian and proportional elections together. This reinforces Duverger's idea (1954) of a prudent withdrawal effect on the majoritarian election, while decreasing the likelihood of a coattail effect over the proportional.

However, none of this would, by itself, prevent parties with a real chance of victory in the gubernatorial election from simply waiting passively for the prudent withdrawal of those candidates that did not have a real chance, as is the case in a more traditional Duvergerian scenario. If they were to do so, they would not need to pay the cost of incorporating the withdrawers into their alliances in the HR. The detail that transforms this process into an active negotiation about withdrawing candidates for governor is the link, created by the electoral legislation, between the number of seats that parties hold in the HR and the distribution of the fixed HGPE time allocated for all elections. Any candidate who wants to increase her exposure on radio and TV will have to obtain this time from an ally. From Law 7493, which regulated the 1986 election, to the General Law of Elections (Law N° 9504/97), an alliance is entitled to the sum of the fractions of the HGPE controlled by its members6 6 Resolution 16402 from 1990 explained in Article 27, line VI that ‘the time to be distributed to the electoral alliance will correspond to the sum of individual times of the parties that constitute it’. In the relevant legislation, the references are always to parties or electoral alliances, which means that they treated the same in legal terms. . Thus, to buid an alliance amounts to obtain additional, scarce and valuable resources to run a guvernatorial campaign.

Since the redemocratization, the HGPE has been distributed in accordance with the performance of parties in legislative elections. More specifically, the electoral laws that governed the 1986 (Law 7508/1986) and 1990 (Resolution 16402/1990) elections established that, for any office being contested, 1/3 of the HGPE was to be distributed equally between all parties, approximately 41.67% of the HGPE in accordance with the size of the parties in the National Congress (Upper and Lower Houses), and the remaining 1/4 of the HGPE in accordance with the size of the parties in the Legislative Assemblies in the respective states7 7 In 1986, the exception was the Federal District (Article 1°, line II, paragraph and Law n° 7508 from 1986) and in 1990 the exceptions were the Federal District, Amapá and Roraima (Article 27°, line II, paragraph e and Resolution 16402 from 1990): in all these cases, 2/3 of the HGPE was distributed in accordance with the size of the representation of the parties in the National Congress and 1/3 was distributed equally to all parties with the right to receive the HGPE. The parties with the right to receive HGPE time were those who presented candidates for at least 1/3 of the seats up for election in the House of Representatives and State Assemblies (Article 1°, line VIII of Law 7508 from 1986 and Article 27°, line V from Resolution 16402 from 1990). . Starting with the law that governed the 1994 election (Law 8713/1993), the Senate and the State Assemblies ceased to enter the calculations: for all offices being disputed, 50% of the HGPE was to be distributed equally between all the parties and 50% in accordance with the proportion of the seats occupied by each party in the HR. Since the establishment of the general law of elections (Law 9504/1997), this percentage has been changed to 1/3 distributed uniformly and 2/3 divided proportionally in accordance with the size of the parties in the HR.

Since 1986, therefore, the relative value of the seats in the HR, measured in terms of the fraction of the HGPE that they guarantee, has only increased. It should be noted though, that fractions of the HGPE are calculated by taking the national distribution of seats as a baseline. As a result, even if a party does not have a representative elected in a given state, it will have a fraction of the HGPE time to negotiate in that state. Hence, for a party without a real chance of victory in a gubernatorial election, the incentives to negotiate its withdrawal and enter the HR race in all states also increases, since the latter also guarantees larger fractions of the HGPE in all disputes in the next electoral cycle (BRAGA, 2006BRAGA, Maria do Socorro (2006), Dinâmica de coordenação eleitoral em regime presidencialista e federativo: determinantes e consequencias das coligações partidarias no Brasil. In: Reforma política: lições da historia recente. Edited by SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon and RENNÓ, Lucio R.. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Getúlio Vargas. pp.228-248.; MELO ans SAEZ, 2007MELO, Carlos Ranulfo and SAEZ, Manuel Alcantara (eds) (2007), A democracia brasileira: balanço e perspectivas para o Século 21. Belo Horizonte: Editora UFMG. 488 pp..; SPECK and CAMPOS, 2014SPECK, Bruno Wilhelm and CAMPOS, Mauro Macedo (2014), Incentivos para a fragmentação e a nacionalização do sistema partidario a partir do horario eleitoral gratuito no Brasil. Teoria & Pesquisa. Vol. 23, № 02, pp. 12-40.). The result of this is that, as Melo (2010MELO, Carlos Ranulfo Felix de (2010), Eleições presidenciais jogos aninhados e sistema partidário no Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política. Vol. 04, pp. 13-42., p. 19) suggests, each party can choose which races to prioritize.

The specialized literature has overlooked the fact that, from the point of view of its effects on party fragmentation, alliances have radically different effects on the two different types of electoral contest. In majoritarian elections, parties in an alliance present just one candidate and, therefore, an alliance acts to concentrate (and not distribute) votes. In proportional elections at state level, an increase in the number of alliances also reduces the number of lists, but not the number of parties that have their own candidates and, consequently, that may win seats. As Vasselai (2015)VASSELAI, Fabricio (2015), Nationalization and localism in electoral systems and party systems. Doctoral thesis. Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Ciencias Humanas. Universidade de São Paulo. shows, since the composition of the HR is the result of the aggregation of each state's electoral results, the increasing number of party entries across states further intensifies the fragmentation of the House's party system.

Figure 02 presents data relating to the entry strategies of Brazilian parties for post-democratization general elections for governor and for the HR. More specifically, this figure shows the percentage of times that each of the possible strategic decisions was taken by the parties able to compete each year. For a given office in a given year y, the total number of decisions made in Brazil (which is the denominator used to calculate the percentages that make up the y-axis of the graph) corresponds to the product Ny * Sy, where Ny is the number of parties legally allowed to field candidates in year y, and Sy is the number of states that exist in year y. It is worth noting that both the number of parties and the number of states vary over this period.

Graph 2
Cumulative histogram: decisions relative to electoral ‘entries’ for Governor and House of Representatives

The most important point shown by this graph is the fall in the number of complete withdrawals and the simultaneous growth of entries as members of an alliance. This movement is pronounced in the first elections we analyzed, stabilizes in the next elections, and gains momentum again in the last two elections when entering into alliances became the norm. Complete withdrawals are extremely rare. In the case of majoritarian elections, however, the percentage of candidacies remains stable. The norm is to enter into an alliance in both majoritarian and proportional elections.

To get a better idea of what these numbers represent, let us consider gubernatorial elections. In 2014, 34 parties were allowed to run candidates. Given that there are 27 concomitant elections, if all parties ran their own candidates in all states, we would have a total of 918 candidates for governor. If we add together the three types of entry, we get very close to this: 844, or almost 92% of parties participating in the gubernatorial elections in some form. However, if we consider the number of candidates for governor who effectively ran, this number falls to 166, with 93 supported by an alliance and 73 running alone. As such, the number of entries as a member of an alliance was 678. The fact of the matter is that a large number of candidates did not have their own candidate for governor in any of the 27 electoral districts.

For both positions, the scenario develops in a practically identical way. Complete withdrawals were common in the first elections, but as more have been held, a gradual development can be observed towards the current situation. In recent elections, almost no party stays out of the race. This growth in participation clearly stems from the dominance of the strategy of entering the race as a member of an alliance.

To better disaggregate this information, the graphs in Figure 03 detail the entry strategies of each party in gubernatorial elections over time8 8 In Figure 03, to make it easier to visualize the party names on the x-axis, we opted to leave out parties that did not field candidates in any state (the PHS, PPB, PRTB, PSDC, PSL, PTC and PTdoB in 1994). . At the beginning of this period, the vast majority of the parties did not even participate in gubernatorial elections, withdrawing completely from the race in pure Duvergerian fashion. Over time, however, this strategy became rarer: in general, the parties that abstained from having their own candidacies for governor began to negotiate their entry into the alliance of one of the strong candidates. As can be seen, this did not change the fact that few parties were capable of leading gubernatorial alliances in a large number of states.

Graph 3
Cumulative histograms: no. of states where parties entered into elections for governor (by type of electoral entry)

In fact, there have been few parties capable of running a significant number of candidates for governor in more than one election; basically, DEM, PDT, PMDB, PP, PSB, PSDB, PT and PTB9 9 For all the parties, we have used their current names. . Besides, this is clearly a heterogeneous group. If we consider only those capable of heading large alliances, the PMDB, PT, and PSDB stick out from the rest, as they are the only parties consistently leading large alliances in different states during the entire period and, as we will show, a large alliance is a pre-condition for electoral succcess.

The presence of the DEM, PDT, PP and PTB in the gubernatorial races, traditional parties that were considered big in the past, is clearly dwindling. As they have done in presidential elections, these parties have also been gradually abstaining from participating in the struggle to elect a governor, opting instead, in most districts, to seek shelter in alliances led by the PT, PMDB, or PSDB. At the same time, since at least 2002, the PSB has emerged as something of a fourth power, fielding candidates for governor on a more consistent basis.

Other parties, such as, for example, the PCdoB, PPS, PR and the PV, rarely run candidates for governor. Therefore, they generally do not even try their luck or test their strength in this arena10 10 Of the small parties, only the parties from the left, especially PSOL, have shown themselves to have a strategy of entry in executive elections. To a large extent, PSOL and the other small parties from the left are reproducing the long-term strategy of the PT in its first years of existence: not forming electoral alliances, or only doing so among themselves, with their eye on future elections, accumulating strength for larger breakthroughs. The results of this strategy up to now, however, have been meager. . With the decrease in gubernatorial candidacies from mediumsized traditional parties, it is not surprising that fewer and fewer parties are fielding candidates, meaning the increase in parties’ electoral participation in gubernatorial elections is accompanied by a net reduction in the number of candidacies.

On the other hand, Brazilian parties are broadening their participation in elections for the HR, spreading out across the territory, as Figure 04 shows11 11 In Figure 04, to make it easier to visualize the party names on the x-axis, we opted to leave out parties that did not field candidates in any state (the PHS, PPB, PRTB, PSDC, PSL, PTC and PTdoB in 1994). . At the beginning of the period, few parties had a presence in a significant number of states, and it was not uncommon for the bigger ones to run with their own lists. Small parties concentrated their entry efforts on specific districts where, for whatever reason, they had some comparative advantage (a historical link with a given state, prominent regional leadership, dominance of specific mayoralties, etc). The offerings of candidates, as the next graph shows, became nationalized; in other words, practically all parties have at least one candidate in every state today. ‘Entering’ is now the norm. Almost no one stays out of elections, but trying one's luck alone, without joining an alliance, is a strategy that few use. The exceptions confirm the rule: only the small ideological parties on the left insist on running alone.

Graph 4
Cumulative histograms: no. of states where parties entered elections for the House of Repr. (by type of electoral entry)

To the extent that a given party has candidates across the 27 electoral constituencies (26 states and 1 federal district), each one of them opens up the possibility that the party will benefit from the transfer of votes that occurs within their alliance. Small parties, therefore, have an incentive to spread out across the country and to try their luck in all districts. As Vasselai (2015)VASSELAI, Fabricio (2015), Nationalization and localism in electoral systems and party systems. Doctoral thesis. Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Ciencias Humanas. Universidade de São Paulo. shows, the larger the number of candidates presented by a given party, and the more these candidates are distributed across a large number of districts, the better the party's chances of winning a seat.

The list of parties that has presented candidates for HR in almost all states over the entire period is similar to that of those that have dominated the offerings for governor, featuring the PMDB, PSDB, and PT, in addition to the secondary tier of parties at the gubernatorial level, such as the DEM, PDT, PSB and PTB. The most visible trend, however, is the dramatic decline of solo lists, that is, the fact that fewer and fewer parties run candidates for the HR without being in alliances. The expansion of electoral alliances as a dominant strategy led to the multiplication of candidacies. By 2002, the vast majority of parties already effectively ran for a seat in practically every state.

As a result, given that electoral alliances have been reducing the number of candidates for governor (or maintaining them at a low level) at the same time that they have been increasing the number of candidates for the HR (both intra- and inter-state), it is not surprising that, from the point of view of electoral results, gubernatorial results are becoming more concentrated while HR results are fragmenting. To measure the concentration or fragmentation of an electoral race, we use the classic index proposed by Laakso and Taagepera (1979)LAAKSO, Marku and TAAGEPERA, Rein (1979), Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe. Comparative Political Studies. Vol. 12, № 01, pp. 03-27., of the effective number of electoral parties, which measures how many parties concentrate the votes in a given election. One can calculate this measure for each district (that is, for each state in Brazil) or as a national aggregate (by using the aggregate number of votes for each party in all states). Figure 05 displays both pieces of information: the distribution of the effective number of intra-state (through a boxplot for each year) and national (a value per year and the trend line between these values) electoral parties for gubernatorial and HR elections over time.

Graph 5
Effective number of electoral parties in elections for Governor and House of Representatives, in states (boxplots) and nationally (red line)

In the gubernatorial races, the effective number of viable candidates—those that actually compete for the preferences of the voters—has fluctuated between two and three. This confirms the suspicion of Melo (2010)MELO, Carlos Ranulfo Felix de (2010), Eleições presidenciais jogos aninhados e sistema partidário no Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política. Vol. 04, pp. 13-42., for whom candidacies for governor had “the tendency to form two big blocks around which local political elites distribute themselves” (MELO, 2010MELO, Carlos Ranulfo Felix de (2010), Eleições presidenciais jogos aninhados e sistema partidário no Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política. Vol. 04, pp. 13-42., p. 10). The most common, let's say, is two and a half candidates: two stronger candidates supported by big alliances and either a third force or a myriad of configurations of smaller alliances. In other words, just like “presidentiable” parties are rare exceptions in Brazil (in the sense that SAMUELS and SHUGART, 2010SAMUELS, David. J. and SHUGART, Matthew Soberg (2010), Presidents, parties and prime ministers. How separation of power affects party organization and behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 310 pp.. seem to consider the rule), there are few parties that are “governorable”. This scenario contradicts what, for Spoon and West (2015)SPOON, Jae-Jae, and WEST, Karleen Jones (2015), Alone or together? How institutions affect party entry in presidential elections in Europe and South America. Party Politics. Vol. 21, № 03, pp. 393-403., should be expected in two-round executive elections. For them, just like for Duverger (1954)DUVERGER, Maurice (1954), Political parties: their organization and activity in the modern state. London: Methuen. 439 pp.. in his original propositions, there is an incentive for parties to try their luck in the first round, leaving electoral coordination for the second round and thus increasing the number of candidates. This is not what has been happening in gubernatorial elections in Brazil. In fact, the coordination has been happening at the start, that is to say, the reduction to around two effective candidates has been happening in the first round. The reason for this is that parties that could only “try their luck” in the first round could not enter alliances with larger parties for proportional elections—this is a risk that is too high to take for those who know in advance that they have little chance of winning an executive office.

As opposed to what happens in presidential elections, however, there is no clear crystallization of the main contenders; that is, we do not observe the same two or three parties dominating the gubernatorial elections over time and space. If we look at any given state, the identity of the main competitors does not usually remain the same between one election and the next. However, the possible variations and alternatives are limited. The range of parties that actually run for governor “with a chance of winning” (that is, parties that lead large alliances) is limited in most contests to the three mentioned previously: the PMDB, PT, and PSDB, along with, every once in a while, a fourth force. Occasionally, parties can win individual elections in a state, but without this representing their consolidation in the longterm. In other words, it is possible to relativize Melo's (2010) thesis that the repetition of gubernatorial elections was not capable of establishing a pattern of interaction and a specific structure for gubernatorial elections.

While gubernatorial elections have a small effective number of competitors, elections for the HR are becoming more and more fragmented, both within the states and at the aggregated national level. In other words, the strategy of having candidacies for the HR in almost all states has been reaping dividends for small parties, which always “hang on” to alliances in the hope that they will be able to benefit from the within alliance transference of votes to gain a seat. Naturally, with more alliances and more members within each of them, this increases the probability that more alliances, in each state, will pass the electoral quotient and the parties that belong to them will end up winning at least one seat.

The fact that party concentration in gubernatorial elections and party fragmentation in HR elections happen simultaneously, however, is not enough evidence to claim that they are related. To verify this relationship, it is necessary to pin point the link between the two processes, that is, it is necessary to show that the parties that lead gubernatorial alliances are exactly the same parties that also are harmed by these alliances in elections for the HR. Likewise, it is necessary to show that the parties that withdraw candidates from gubernatorial elections are those who win seats for the Lower House because of their participation in alliances. In the next section, we show that this, in fact, does indeed occur. To the best of our knowledge, this link has not been demonstrated in the extant literature.

The link between alliances for governor and for the House of Representatives and its effects

Investigating whether a given party won or lost seats because they had established an electoral alliance for the HR means speculating upon a counterfactual scenario: what would the electoral performance of this party have been if it had not entered into an alliance? The response to this question will never be definitive since the “ceteris paribus” condition would not hold. One can, however, simulate what the distribution of seats would have been in the absence of electoral alliances12 12 We know of course that political actors would have adapted to this new rule, ruling out the possibility of precisely estimating of the counterfactual scenario based on observed results. The behavior would change, as would the results. The simulation serves, however, as an approximation of the gains and losses in each year that resulted from the existence of alliances in elections for the House of Representatives. .

Using the electoral outcomes for individual candidates and party lists for the Lower House elections, we therefore re-calculated the party quotients in each state and the distribution of seats without considering electoral alliances (following the details of specific legislation for each year). Using this simulated result, it is possible to know how many seats each party loses and/or wins in each state thanks to its participation in a given alliance. As emphasized earlier, we want to identify how many HR seats are transferred from the ‘head’ of each gubernatorial alliance to the other members.

Thus, instead of the typical distinction between big and small parties, our calculations take into account the type of entry for the gubernatorial election (whether “head” or “member” of an alliance). Figure 06 shows the number of seats transferred in accordance with participation in the gubernatorial election.

Graph 6
Number of seats redistributed if electoral alliances for the House of Representatives were not allowed, in accordance with type of entry for governor

The result of this exercise leaves little doubt: in general, leading gubernatorial alliances has led parties to lose seats in the HR. Likewise, not running one's own candidate for governor has a positive effect, producing a net gain in seats. The result is also supported by the fact that solo candidacies and full withdrawals from gubernatorial elections have no effect on the distribution of seats in the HR. This result makes sense: if we expect participation in alliances for governor to alter the performance of parties in elections for the HR (even if the effect depends on the role of each party within the alliance), it is significant that the graph shows that non-participation in a gubernatorial alliance does not affect the distribution of seats in the HR.

The effect of gubernatorial alliances on the distribution of seats in the HR has been becoming more accentuated over time. In the 1986 election, being the head or a member of a gubernatorial alliance had no discernible effect on parties’ access to the HR. From 1990 on, however, this situation changes. The effect grows gradually, reaching significant levels in the 2006 election. In 2010 and 2014, the negative effect on the number of seats in the HR for the parties leading alliances is remarkable, bringing with it the opposite effect: a positive balance for members of alliances.

The specialized literature notes that alliances for the HR offer the expedient that small parties use to circumvent the electoral threshold implied in Brazilian electoral legislation (see, among others, DANTAS and PRAÇA, 2010DANTAS, Humberto and PRAÇA, Sérgio (2010), Pequenos partidos no Brasil: uma analise do posicionamento ideológico com base nas coligações municipais de 2000 a 2008. In: Coligações partidárias na nova democracia brasileira: perfis e tendâncias. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana; DANTAS, Humberto, and MIGUEL, Luis Felipe. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. UNESP. pp. 99-133., 2010; MACHADO, 2005MACHADO, Aline (2005), A lógica das coligações no Brasil. In: Partidos e coligações eleitorais no Brasil. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana and SCHMITT, Rogério. São Paulo, Rio de Janeiro: Editora Fundação Konrad Adenauer and UNESP. pp. 43-83.; NASCIMENTO et al., 2016NASCIMENTO, Willber; SILVA JR., José Alexandre da; PARANHOS, Ranulfo; SILVA, Denisson and FIGUEIREDO F○, Dalson Britto (2016), Does size matter? Electoral performance of small parties in Brazil. Brazilian Political Science Review. Vol. 10, № 02, pp. 01-26.; RODRIGUES, 1995RODRIGUES, Leôncio Martins (1995), Eleições, fragmentação partidaria e governabilidade. Novos Estudos CEBRAP. Vol. 41, № 01, pp. 78-90.). However, alliances in proportional elections, in and of themselves, do not have an unambiguous and stable effect on fragmentation in the HR. Without paying attention to the morphology, size, and internal composition of alliances, it is not possible to assess their effects. Furthermore, the contribution of alliances to the fragmentation of the HR grew insofar as alliances began to contain more and more parties. Calvo, Guarnieri and Limongi (2015)CALVO, Ernesto; GUARNIERI, Fernando, and LIMONGI, Fernando (2015), Why coalitions? Party system fragmentation, small party bias, and preferential vote in Brazil. Electoral Studies. Vol. 39, pp. 219-229., for instance, have shown that the direction of this transfer depends on the concentration-distribution of votes within the parties that make up the alliance and that this—because the small parties have more concentrated voting patterns—is why the small parties end up being the direct beneficiaries of alliances.

As can be seen in Figure 07, the specific contribution of proportional alliances to fragmentation takes shape and starts to become visible in the 1994 elections. In the 2002 elections, the process gained new momentum, and in 2010 and 2014, it became blatant. Without electoral alliances for the HR, party fragmentation would have remained practically constant from 1990 until 2014—and stood still between 1994 and 201013 13 One should note that parties can also be induced to form electoral alliances as a response to the strategies of their opponents: if their opponents form alliances, it might be understood as necessary to pursue the same strategy. .

Graph 7
House of Representatives: actual party fragmentation versus party fragmentation simulated with electoral alliances not allowed

It remains to be seen, however, what the incentives or gains are for the parties that lead the gubernatorial alliances. As we pointed out initially, this crucial question was raised for the first time by Lavareda (1991)LAVAREDA, Antonio (1991), A democracia nas urnas: o processo eleitoral brasileiro. Rio de Janeiro: IUPERJ/Rio Fundo Editora. 187 pp.., who believed the big parties gave up seats in the HR in exchange for strengthening their candidacies for governor. However, the meaning of “strengthening” here can have different levels. A candidate for governor may have ambitions to build a big alliance for various reasons. As many authors suggest (see BRAGA, 2006BRAGA, Maria do Socorro (2006), Dinâmica de coordenação eleitoral em regime presidencialista e federativo: determinantes e consequencias das coligações partidarias no Brasil. In: Reforma política: lições da historia recente. Edited by SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon and RENNÓ, Lucio R.. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Getúlio Vargas. pp.228-248.; MELO and SAEZ, 2007MELO, Carlos Ranulfo and SAEZ, Manuel Alcantara (eds) (2007), A democracia brasileira: balanço e perspectivas para o Século 21. Belo Horizonte: Editora UFMG. 488 pp..; SAMUELS, 2003SAMUELS, David J. (2003), Ambition, federalism, and legislative politics in Brazil. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 248 pp..), she may be interested in convincing other parties to campaign for her, she may want to attract the support of mayors and political leaders from other parties, or she may simply wish to guarantee the withdrawn of opponents that could split the votes. Lastly, she may be interested in increasing her access to public resources such as electoral advertising.

As we have discussed before, we believe that alliances for executive elections look to maximize the HGPE time available to the “head” of the alliance. However, although this is understood as essential for campaigning and winning elections, little is known about the real effect of the HGPE on candidates’ actual chances in elections for different offices. The empirical literature on the topic is scarce, given that data about the distribution of HGPE time for several election years are difficult to compile and organize (see SCHMITT et al., 1999SCHMITT, Rogério, CARNEIRO, Leandro P. and KUSCHNIR, Karina. (1999), Estratégia de Campanha no Horario Gratuito de Propaganda Eleitoral em Eleições Proporcionais. Dados. Vol. 42, № 02, pp. 277-301.; SPECK and CERVI, 2016SPECK, Bruno Wilhelm, and CERVI, Emerson Urizzi (2016), Money, time and electoral memory: the mechanisms that define the vote in mayoral elections in 2012. Dados. Vol. 59, № 01, pp. 53-90.; SPECK and CAMPOS, 2014SPECK, Bruno Wilhelm and CAMPOS, Mauro Macedo (2014), Incentivos para a fragmentação e a nacionalização do sistema partidario a partir do horario eleitoral gratuito no Brasil. Teoria & Pesquisa. Vol. 23, № 02, pp. 12-40.). To assess the correlation between HGPE time and electoral performance, we use our new database to estimate the distribution of HGPE time for all gubernatorial candidates in all states since 1986, adjusted for the specific legislation surrounding each election14 14 In the case of the 1986 elections, considering that Law 7508/1986 did not mention the exact date on which legislative representations would be counted, we opted to use the date in which the electoral law was promulgated. As a result, we used attendance records in the Official Journals and the Report of the Presidency of the Senate in 1986 to identify manually the representation of the different parties in the House of Representatives and the Senate on July 04, 1986. In the case of the 1990 elections, Resolution 16402/1990 identifies in Article 27°, paragraph 1°, that the the division of HGPE time was based on representation on April 03, 1990. As such, we manually identified representation within the House of Representatives and Senate through the Official Journals on the closest possible dates. As we mentioned before, these two elections distributed % of the HGPE in accordance with the representation of the parties in the State Assemblies. Since it is difficult to obtain information about the effective representation of each Assembly on a specific data, we used the number of city councilmen elected in the elections that immediately preceded these dates as a proxy. In both these years, we also took into account the different rules about the distribution of the HGPE in the Federal District in 1986, and in the Federal District, Amapa, and Roraima in 1990 that were mentioned above. We also took into account the fact that, in both these elections, only the parties that fielded candidates for 1/3 of the slots in the House of Representatives and the Assemblies participated in the proportional distribution of votes. In the case of the subsequent elections, the rules were much simpler. Law 8713/1993, which regulated the 1994 election, determined that, for the Division of HGPE time, the representation of parties in the House of Representatives would be based on data regarding the promulgation of the law. We therefore used the Database of Party Migrations from NECI-USP to identify party representation on September 30,1993. In the case of the 1998, 2002, and 2006 elections, the general law of elections, Law 9504/1997, determined that they would consider the representation inaugurated in the House of Representatives based upon the election immediately prior. Again, we used the Database of Party Migrations from NECI-USP to obtain this information. Finally, after the alteration introduced by Law N° 11300/2006, for the 2010 and 2014 elections, the distribution of HGPE time was based on representation the elections immediately prior—and we therefore reconstructed this representation using the results contained in our own database. .

In Figure 08, we present two series of graphs. One shows the relationship between the size of gubernatorial alliances and the electoral performance of the candidacies. The other shows the correlation between the HGPE time added by members of an alliance (that is, not taking into consideration the HGPE time of the party that led the alliance)15 15 By leaving out the HGPE time of the party that led the alliance, we can assess the relevance of alliance formation members. Otherwise, one would never know whether the correlation showed in the figure is dominated simply by the HGPE of the candidate's party. and the candidate's electoral performance.

Graph 8
Votes obtained in the 1st round and size of electoral alliance for governor and Votes obtained in the 1st round and HGPE in elections for governor, 1986-2014

As expected, we can see that larger alliances are frequently related to higher levels of votes while solo candidacies and alliances with few members tend to be associated with weak electoral performance. For gubernatorial candidates, broadening the alliances seems to be a good bet. Analogously, one can see a very similar result when we consider the HGPE time that each gubernatorial candidate adds by joining an alliance—that is, the fraction of the HGPE gained through the inclusion of an alliance member. While there is variation around a non-parametric lowess-smoothed line, the trend is clear: larger quantities of HGPE time added to a candidacy tend to be correlated with better electoral performance. As would be expected, this result, while evident for all years of the graph, is particularly marked after 1990. After all, from 1994 onwards, the allocation of HGPE time stopped considering party representation in the Senate and State Assemblies, which strengthened the mechanism that we describe: the negotiation of withdrawals of gubernatorial candidacies with the consequent increase in HGPE time for gubernatorial candidates in exchange for transfers of votes for HR elections.

Clearly, future investigation the relationship between the HGPE and electoral performance will require more sophisticated statistical tests. Identification strategies and causal inference methods are particularly needed for dealing with the problem of the direction of causality: do candidates with more HGPE time receive more votes, or do stronger candidates attract more allies, and therefore, end up having more HGPE time? Our new data, our analysis and the graphics above merely shed some light on this matter. Preliminary results from other studies, though, point in the same direction (SILVEIRA and MELLO, 2011SILVEIRA, Bernardo da and MELLO, João M. de (2011), Campaign advertising and election outcomes: quasi-natural experiment evidence from gubernatorial elections in Brazil. Review of Economic Studies. Vol. 78, № 02, pp. pp. 590-612.).

Conclusion

Electoral alliances are one of the most studied objects in Brazilian political science. Since the pioneering contribution of Soares (1964)SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon (1964), Alianças e coligações eleitorais: notas para uma teoria. Revista Brasileira de Estudos Políticos. № 17, pp. 95-124., the specialized literature on the topic has only grown. As is often the case, our work has benefited from the knowledge that has accumulated from this dense area of study. We follow diverse threads in the literature in formulating our proposal for an integrated understanding of alliances that are formed simultaneously in elections for governor and for seats in the House of Representatives.

Even if they do not need to be identical, the strategic decisions taken by the parties in these two races are interdependent, if for no other reason than that the legislation makes it so. Upon joining an alliance to contest a race for governor, parties limit their options for alliances in House of Representatives races. More specifically, if they want to join an alliance for the proportional elections, the party must be part of that alliance for the gubernatorial election. The result is a reduction in candidates running for governor.

Followingthe suggestion of Lavareda (1991)LAVAREDA, Antonio (1991), A democracia nas urnas: o processo eleitoral brasileiro. Rio de Janeiro: IUPERJ/Rio Fundo Editora. 187 pp.., we showthatthe strategy that guarantees electoral success in majoritarian elections has proportional alliances as a counterpoint. We offer much needed evidence that the “heads” of the alliances for majoritarian elections are the ones who receive resources from their allies (HGPE time) and who transfer seats to those same parties in legislative elections. As a result, instead of the usual typology (big parties/small parties), our analysis shows that the party system is organized around the roles of “head” and “members” of the gubernatorial alliance. As such, alliances contribute to the reduction of the number of entries in gubernatorial elections while simultaneously increasing the number of entries in proportional elections. The result is a process of specialization in which a few parties (the PMDB, PT, and PSDB, and to a lesser degree, the PSB or some other fourth party) contest majoritarian elections while the others dedicate themselves exclusively to contesting legislative seats.

Many questions remain unanswered, awaiting studies equipped with better strategies for identifying causal dynamics. It seems evident to us that competition for HGPE time is a central axis on which the Brazilian electoral party system rests and develops. Its specific weight in the agreements that lead to the formation of alliances requires specific and more in-depth studies. However, there is already evidence that politicians understand some of these aspects and have tried to alter them. Law 13165/2015 altered the criteria for the distribution of HGPE time in favor of larger parties so that in 2018, 10% of the time would already be reserved for equitable distribution while the 90% remaining would reflect the proportion of seats in the House of Representatives. Another innovation of the same law concerns the fraction of the HGPE that each alliance for majoritarian elections receives, given that what now determines this distribution is the time held by the six largest parties within each alliance.

In other words, the bargaining power of smaller parties was clearly reduced. It remains to be seen how much this will succeed in altering the logic of negotiations explained in this article. Suppose that there is a state in which there are three relevant candidates for governor in a given election, with each one at the head of an alliance of at least six parties. In this case, at least 18 parties would make effective contributions to the final calculation of the distribution of the HGPE time, a number that is not insignificant and that perhaps does not profoundly alter the logic upon which the current system operates.

In any case, the modification of the law proves the importance of the mechanisms that we identify in this article. It also shows that politicians noticed it before academics had explored its importance in full. If anything, we hope that this example will serve to encourage new studies on the topic.

  • For data replication, see https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/WZWU2D
  • 1
    We translate "coligações” as electoral alliances instead of the coalitions. We do so to stress that these are alliances formed for electoral purposes and that they do not have any "necessary” consequences for government in the legislative arena. It is important to stress that these are formal alliances that have to be confirmed by party conventions.
  • 2
  • 3
    To simulate precisely the number of legislators that would be elected by each party in the House of Representatives if there were no alliances, it is necessary to know not only the number of votes for each candidate, but also the number of votes that each party received solely for the party itself. In 1986 and 1990, the official electoral results in some states (including records from the results of vote counts) do not differentiate between votes for specific parties in the case of alliances. In these few cases, we imputed the number of votes for each party in the electoral alliance based on the percentage of votes for individual candidates within each party.
  • 4
    Electoral alliances were regulated by Article 140 of the Electoral Code of 1950. This article said nothing about the relationship between electoral alliances formed to contest elections for different offices.
  • 5
    In this case, Law 7664/1988 (Article 08) and Resolutions/TSE 16347/90 and 16557/90 are relevant, as is Law 8713/1993 (Article 06).
  • 6
    Resolution 16402 from 1990 explained in Article 27, line VI that ‘the time to be distributed to the electoral alliance will correspond to the sum of individual times of the parties that constitute it’. In the relevant legislation, the references are always to parties or electoral alliances, which means that they treated the same in legal terms.
  • 7
    In 1986, the exception was the Federal District (Article 1°, line II, paragraph and Law n° 7508 from 1986) and in 1990 the exceptions were the Federal District, Amapá and Roraima (Article 27°, line II, paragraph e and Resolution 16402 from 1990): in all these cases, 2/3 of the HGPE was distributed in accordance with the size of the representation of the parties in the National Congress and 1/3 was distributed equally to all parties with the right to receive the HGPE. The parties with the right to receive HGPE time were those who presented candidates for at least 1/3 of the seats up for election in the House of Representatives and State Assemblies (Article 1°, line VIII of Law 7508 from 1986 and Article 27°, line V from Resolution 16402 from 1990).
  • 8
    In Figure 03, to make it easier to visualize the party names on the x-axis, we opted to leave out parties that did not field candidates in any state (the PHS, PPB, PRTB, PSDC, PSL, PTC and PTdoB in 1994).
  • 9
    For all the parties, we have used their current names.
  • 10
    Of the small parties, only the parties from the left, especially PSOL, have shown themselves to have a strategy of entry in executive elections. To a large extent, PSOL and the other small parties from the left are reproducing the long-term strategy of the PT in its first years of existence: not forming electoral alliances, or only doing so among themselves, with their eye on future elections, accumulating strength for larger breakthroughs. The results of this strategy up to now, however, have been meager.
  • 11
    In Figure 04, to make it easier to visualize the party names on the x-axis, we opted to leave out parties that did not field candidates in any state (the PHS, PPB, PRTB, PSDC, PSL, PTC and PTdoB in 1994).
  • 12
    We know of course that political actors would have adapted to this new rule, ruling out the possibility of precisely estimating of the counterfactual scenario based on observed results. The behavior would change, as would the results. The simulation serves, however, as an approximation of the gains and losses in each year that resulted from the existence of alliances in elections for the House of Representatives.
  • 13
    One should note that parties can also be induced to form electoral alliances as a response to the strategies of their opponents: if their opponents form alliances, it might be understood as necessary to pursue the same strategy.
  • 14
    In the case of the 1986 elections, considering that Law 7508/1986 did not mention the exact date on which legislative representations would be counted, we opted to use the date in which the electoral law was promulgated. As a result, we used attendance records in the Official Journals and the Report of the Presidency of the Senate in 1986 to identify manually the representation of the different parties in the House of Representatives and the Senate on July 04, 1986. In the case of the 1990 elections, Resolution 16402/1990 identifies in Article 27°, paragraph 1°, that the the division of HGPE time was based on representation on April 03, 1990. As such, we manually identified representation within the House of Representatives and Senate through the Official Journals on the closest possible dates. As we mentioned before, these two elections distributed % of the HGPE in accordance with the representation of the parties in the State Assemblies. Since it is difficult to obtain information about the effective representation of each Assembly on a specific data, we used the number of city councilmen elected in the elections that immediately preceded these dates as a proxy. In both these years, we also took into account the different rules about the distribution of the HGPE in the Federal District in 1986, and in the Federal District, Amapa, and Roraima in 1990 that were mentioned above. We also took into account the fact that, in both these elections, only the parties that fielded candidates for 1/3 of the slots in the House of Representatives and the Assemblies participated in the proportional distribution of votes. In the case of the subsequent elections, the rules were much simpler. Law 8713/1993, which regulated the 1994 election, determined that, for the Division of HGPE time, the representation of parties in the House of Representatives would be based on data regarding the promulgation of the law. We therefore used the Database of Party Migrations from NECI-USP to identify party representation on September 30,1993. In the case of the 1998, 2002, and 2006 elections, the general law of elections, Law 9504/1997, determined that they would consider the representation inaugurated in the House of Representatives based upon the election immediately prior. Again, we used the Database of Party Migrations from NECI-USP to obtain this information. Finally, after the alteration introduced by Law N° 11300/2006, for the 2010 and 2014 elections, the distribution of HGPE time was based on representation the elections immediately prior—and we therefore reconstructed this representation using the results contained in our own database.
  • 15
    By leaving out the HGPE time of the party that led the alliance, we can assess the relevance of alliance formation members. Otherwise, one would never know whether the correlation showed in the figure is dominated simply by the HGPE of the candidate's party.
  • Revised by Matthew Richmond

References

  • ABRUCIO, Fernando Luiz (1998), Os barões da federação: os governadores e a redemocra-tização brasileira. São Paulo: Hucitec/USP. 253 pp..
  • BORGES, André, and LLOYD, Ryan (2016), Presidential coattails and electoral coordination in multilevel elections: comparative lessons from Brazil. Electoral Studies. Vol. 43, pp.104-114.
  • BRAGA, Maria do Socorro (2006), Dinâmica de coordenação eleitoral em regime presidencialista e federativo: determinantes e consequencias das coligações partidarias no Brasil. In: Reforma política: lições da historia recente. Edited by SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon and RENNÓ, Lucio R.. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Getúlio Vargas. pp.228-248.
  • BRAGA, Maria do Socorro and ROMA, Celso (2002), Sistema partidário, eleições e a questão federativa no Brasil (1986-2000). In: Partidos no cone sul: novos ângulos de pesquisa. Edited by PINTO, Céli Regina and SANTOS, André Marenco dos. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad Andenauer Stiftung. Vol. 01, pp. 47-82.
  • CALVO, Ernesto; GUARNIERI, Fernando, and LIMONGI, Fernando (2015), Why coalitions? Party system fragmentation, small party bias, and preferential vote in Brazil. Electoral Studies. Vol. 39, pp. 219-229.
  • CARREIRÃO, Yan (2006), Ideologia e partidos políticos: um estudo sobre coligações em Santa Catarina. Opinião Pública. Vol. 12, № 01, pp. 136-163.
  • CARREIRÃO, Yan S. and NASCIMENTO, Fernanda Paula (2010), As coligações nas eleições para os cargos de governador, senador, deputado federal e deputado estadual no Brasil (1986/2006). Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política. № 04, pp. 75-104.
  • COX, Gary (1997), Making votes count: strategic coordination in the World's electoral systems. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 360 pp..
  • DALMORO, Jefferson and FLEISCHER, David (2005), Eleição proporcional: os efeitos das coligaçoes e o problema da proporcionalidade. In: Partidos e coligações eleitorais no Brasil. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana e SCHMITT, Rogério. Rio de Janeiro/SãoPaulo: Konrad-Adenauer Stiftung/Editora Unesp. pp. 85-113.
  • DANTAS, Humberto (2007), Coligações em eleiçoes majoritárias municipais: a lógica do alinhamento dos partidos políticos brasileiros nas disputas de 2000 e 2004. Doctoral thesis. Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Ciencias Humanas. Universidade de São Paulo.
  • DANTAS, Humberto and PRAÇA, Sérgio (2010), Pequenos partidos no Brasil: uma analise do posicionamento ideológico com base nas coligações municipais de 2000 a 2008. In: Coligações partidárias na nova democracia brasileira: perfis e tendâncias. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana; DANTAS, Humberto, and MIGUEL, Luis Felipe. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. UNESP. pp. 99-133.
  • DUVERGER, Maurice (1954), Political parties: their organization and activity in the modern state. London: Methuen. 439 pp..
  • KRAUSE, Silvana (2005), Uma análise comparativa das estratégias eleitorais nas eleições majoritárias (1994-1998-2002): coligaçoes eleitorais X nacionalização dos partidos e do sistema partidario brasileiro. In: Partidos e coligações eleitorais no Brasil. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana, and SCHMITT, Rogério. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. UNESP, pp. 115-142.
  • KRAUSE, Silvana and GODOI, Pedro (2010), Coligações eleitorais para os executivos estaduais (1986-2006): padrões e tendâncias. In: Coligações partidárias na nova democracia brasileira: perfis e tendencias. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana; DANTAS, Humberto, and MIGUEL, Luis Felipe. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. ENESP, pp. 41-99.
  • LAAKSO, Marku and TAAGEPERA, Rein (1979), Effective Number of Parties: A Measure with Application to West Europe. Comparative Political Studies. Vol. 12, № 01, pp. 03-27.
  • LAVAREDA, Antonio (1991), A democracia nas urnas: o processo eleitoral brasileiro. Rio de Janeiro: IUPERJ/Rio Fundo Editora. 187 pp..
  • LEONI, Eduardo (2011), Coligações e ideologia nas eleições para vereadores no Brasil: uma analise econométrica. In: O Congresso por ele mesmo: autopercepções da classe política brasileira. Edited by POWER, Thimoty. J. and ZUCCO JR., Cesar. Belo Horizonte: UFMG. pp. 42-73.
  • LIMA JR., Olavo Brasil de (1983) Os partidos políticos brasileiros: a experiencia federal e regional: 1945-1964. Rio de Janeiro: Graal. 157 pp..
  • MACHADO, Aline (2005), A lógica das coligações no Brasil. In: Partidos e coligações eleitorais no Brasil. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana and SCHMITT, Rogério. São Paulo, Rio de Janeiro: Editora Fundação Konrad Adenauer and UNESP. pp. 43-83.
  • MELO, Carlos Ranulfo Felix de (2010), Eleições presidenciais jogos aninhados e sistema partidário no Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política. Vol. 04, pp. 13-42.
  • MELO, Carlos Ranulfo and SAEZ, Manuel Alcantara (eds) (2007), A democracia brasileira: balanço e perspectivas para o Século 21. Belo Horizonte: Editora UFMG. 488 pp..
  • MIGNOZZETTI, Umberto Guarnier; GALDINO, Manoel, and BERNABEL, Rodolpho (2011), Um modelo para explicar as coligações eleitorais para a Câmara federal brasileira (1998-2006). Revista Política Hoje. Vol. 20, № 02, pp. 741-788.
  • MIRANDA, Geralda L. (2013), Coligações eleitorais: tendências e racionalidades nas eleições federais e majoritárias estaduais (1990-2010). Revista de Sociologia Política. Vol. 21, № 47, pp. 69-90.
  • NASCIMENTO, Willber; SILVA JR., José Alexandre da; PARANHOS, Ranulfo; SILVA, Denisson and FIGUEIREDO F, Dalson Britto (2016), Does size matter? Electoral performance of small parties in Brazil. Brazilian Political Science Review. Vol. 10, № 02, pp. 01-26.
  • NICOLAU, Jairo Marconi (1996), Multipartidarismo e democracia: um estudo sobre o sistema partidário brasileiro (1985-1994). Rio de Janeiro: FGV. 120 pp..
  • NOVAES, Carlos Alberto Marques (1994), Dinâmica institucional da representação: individualismo e partidos na câmara dos deputados. Novos Estudos. Vol. 38, pp. 99-147.
  • RODRIGUES, Leôncio Martins (1995), Eleições, fragmentação partidaria e governabilidade. Novos Estudos CEBRAP. Vol. 41, № 01, pp. 78-90.
  • SAMUELS, David J. (2005), The gubernatorial coattails effect: federalism and congressional elections in Brazil. The Journal of Politics. Vol. 62, № 01, pp. 240-253.
  • SAMUELS, David J. (2003), Ambition, federalism, and legislative politics in Brazil. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 248 pp..
  • SAMUELS, David. J. and SHUGART, Matthew Soberg (2010), Presidents, parties and prime ministers. How separation of power affects party organization and behavior. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 310 pp..
  • SANTOS, Wanderley Guilherme (1987), Crise e castigo: partidos e generais na política brasileira. São Paulo: Vértice. 208 pp..
  • SCHMITT, Rogério Augusto (2000), Partidos políticos no Brasil (1945-2000). Rio de Janeiro: J. Zahar. 96 pp..
  • SCHMITT, Rogério, CARNEIRO, Leandro P. and KUSCHNIR, Karina. (1999), Estratégia de Campanha no Horario Gratuito de Propaganda Eleitoral em Eleições Proporcionais. Dados. Vol. 42, № 02, pp. 277-301.
  • SHUGART, Mathew Soberg and CAREY, John M. (1992), Presidents and assemblies: constitutional design and electoral dynamics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 332 pp..
  • SILVEIRA, Bernardo da and MELLO, João M. de (2011), Campaign advertising and election outcomes: quasi-natural experiment evidence from gubernatorial elections in Brazil. Review of Economic Studies. Vol. 78, № 02, pp. pp. 590-612.
  • SOARES, Gláucio Ary Dillon (1964), Alianças e coligações eleitorais: notas para uma teoria. Revista Brasileira de Estudos Políticos. № 17, pp. 95-124.
  • SOARES, Marcia Miranda (2013), Influencia majoritária em eleições proporcionais: os efeitos presidenciais e governatoriais sobre as eleições para a câmara dos deputados brasileira (1994-2010). Dados. Vol. 56, № 02, pp.413-437.
  • SOUZA, Vivaldo de (2010), Reeleição de governadores e posicionamento ideológico das coligações eleitorais nas eleições de 1998, 2002 e 2006. In: Coligações partidárias na nova democracia brasileira: perfis e tendencias. Edited by KRAUSE, Silvana; DANTAS, Humberto, and MIGUEL, Luis Felipe. Rio de Janeiro: Konrad-Adenauer-Stiftung. São Paulo: Ed. ENESP. pp. 135-165.
  • SPECK, Bruno Wilhelm and CAMPOS, Mauro Macedo (2014), Incentivos para a fragmentação e a nacionalização do sistema partidario a partir do horario eleitoral gratuito no Brasil. Teoria & Pesquisa. Vol. 23, № 02, pp. 12-40.
  • SPECK, Bruno Wilhelm, and CERVI, Emerson Urizzi (2016), Money, time and electoral memory: the mechanisms that define the vote in mayoral elections in 2012. Dados. Vol. 59, № 01, pp. 53-90.
  • SPOON, Jae-Jae, and WEST, Karleen Jones (2015), Alone or together? How institutions affect party entry in presidential elections in Europe and South America. Party Politics. Vol. 21, № 03, pp. 393-403.
  • VASSELAI, Fabricio (2015), Nationalization and localism in electoral systems and party systems. Doctoral thesis. Faculdade de Filosofia, Letras e Ciencias Humanas. Universidade de São Paulo.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    29 Nov 2018
  • Date of issue
    2018

History

  • Received
    19 Aug 2017
  • Accepted
    08 Aug 2018
Associação Brasileira de Ciência Política Avenida Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 315, sala 2047, CEP 05508-900, Tel.: (55 11) 3091-3754 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: bpsr@brazilianpoliticalsciencareview.org