Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Does Corporate Governance Influence the Efficiency of Brazilian Companies?* * Article presented at the IBGC (Special Academic Forum), São Paulo, Brazil, 2013.

Abstracts

Conflicts of interest between managers and owners is an oft-studied issue in academia, first documented by Berle and Means in 1932, which exposes the classic conflict of interest between agent and principal discussed in agency theory. The premise of corporate governance is that people in corporations do not necessarily act in funders' best interest. Based on this assumption, this study investigates the influence of aspects of corporate governance on the efficiency of publicly traded Brazilian companies. The study combines static optimization techniques through data envelopment analysis (DEA) to identify the efficiency of publicly traded companies, using panel data to identify the influence of corporate governance on company efficiency. The data were manually collected from 20-F reports from the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) for Brazilian companies that had American depositary receipts (ADRs) because the database is not entirely available in Brazil. Many of the hypotheses were confirmed, thereby showing the particular conditions of corporate finance in Brazil with respect to corporate governance. The immaturity of the Brazilian capital market is perceived in various analyses, emphasizing that the history of the Brazilian corporate system is one of the limiting factors of the efficiency of companies. The conditions that prevail are the following: (i) high ownership-management overlap; (ii) boards with low effectiveness; (iii) in family groups, the poor definitions of the roles of stockholders, boards and management; (iv) the lack of clarity related to the cost-benefit relationship for good governance; (v) inefficiency of the boards of directors and (vi) evidence of conflicts of interests, diminished by explicit and implicit incentives.

Efficiency; Corporate governance; Agency theory


O conflito de interesses entre executivos e proprietários é uma questão amplamente difundida na academia, já documentada em 1932 por Berle e Means, trazendo à tona o clássico conflito de interesses entre agente e principal discutido pela Teoria da Agência. A premissa por trás da governança corporativa é que as pessoas que estão dentro das corporações não necessariamente agem visando o melhor para os provedores de fundos. Partindo deste pressuposto, o trabalho em questão visa verificar a influência dos aspectos de governança corporativa na eficiência das empresas de capital aberto brasileiras. O estudo une técnicas de otimização estática através de Análise Envoltória de Dados (DEA) para identificar a eficiência das empresas de capital aberto, com Dados em Painel para identificar a influência da governança corporativa na eficiência das empresas. Os dados foram coletados manualmente dos relatórios 20-F da Security Exchange Commission (SEC) das empresas brasileiras que possuem American Depositary Receipts (ADRs), já que a base de dados não está disponível, no Brasil, de uma forma completa. Grande parte das hipóteses foi confirmada, evidenciando as condições particulares das finanças corporativas no Brasil no que tange a Governança Corporativa. A incipiência do mercado de capitais brasileiro é percebida em várias análises, ressaltando que o histórico do sistema corporativo brasileiro é um dos limitantes da eficiência das empresas. As condições que prevalecem são: (i) alta sobreposição propriedade-direção; (ii) conselhos de administração de baixa efetividade; (iii) em grupos familiares, os papéis dos acionistas, dos conselhos e da direção não são bem definidos; (iv) existe pouca clareza quanto à relação benefício-custo da boa governança; (v) baixa eficácia dos conselhos de administração; e (vi) indícios de conflitos de interesses, relativizados por incentivos explícitos e implícitos.

Eficiência; Governança corporativa; Teoria da agência


1 Introduction

Conflicts of interest between managers and owners is an oft-studied issue in academia, first documented in 1932 by Berle and Means, exposing the classic conflict of interest between agent and principal discussed by agency theory. The premise behind corporate governance is that people in corporations do not necessarily act in funders' best interest.

Executives may act in several ways that are inconsistent with the interests of shareholders. Tirole (2006)Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton: Princeton University Press. divides these behaviors into four categories, which belong to the problem generally termed "moral hazard": (i) insufficient commitment; (ii) extravagant investments; (iii) entrenchment strategies, or maintaining one's position in the company by engaging in actions that may harm shareholders; and (iv) self-dealing, or increasing private benefits for executives and consuming "perks" that burden the company and do not benefit the shareholder. However, the issue of moral hazard is only a small portion of executives' questionable behavior. Tirole (2006)Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton: Princeton University Press. argues that the primary issue involved in this conflict of interest is institutional responsibility related to corporate governance, finances and administrative incentive contracts.

Consistent with that assumption, this study aims to investigate the influence of aspects of corporate governance (particularly with respect to executive compensation) on the efficiency of Brazilian publicly traded companies.

This issue can be considered innovative because it uses data on corporate governance (executive compensation) to verify the impact of the variables set forth above on the efficiency of Brazilian companies; the data were collected manually from 20-F reports of the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) because the entire database is not available in Brazil. Companies that have American depositary receipts (ADRs) are required to provide that data to the SEC, enabling the collection of information. This study seeks to add corporate governance to the literature on production efficiency in the context of institutional differences in the Brazilian environment to complement previous studies that only consider outputs as measures of efficiency.

Among those studies are the works of Belkaoui e Pavlik (1992)Belkaoui, A., & Pavlik, E. (1992 August). The effects of ownership structure and diversification strategy on performance. Managerial and Decision Economics, 13(4),343-352. and Hitt e Ireland (1986)Hitt, M. A., & Ireland, R. D. (1986). Relationships among corporate level distinctive competencies, diversification strategy, corporate structure and performance. Journal of Management Studies, 23(4),401-416., who used the logarithm of revenue or market capitalization as a dependent variable to measure company performance. Frydman, Gray, Hessel, e Rapaczynski (1999)Frydman, R., Gray, C., Hessel, M., & Rapaczynski, A. (1999 November). When does privatization work? The impact of private ownership on corporate performance in the transition economies. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4),1153-1191. considered profitability as a measure of efficiency. Megginson, Nash, e Randenborgh (1994)Megginson, W. L., Nash, R. C., & Randenborgh, M. V. (1994 June). The financial and operating performance of newly privatized firms: an international empirical analysis. The, Journal of Finance 49(2),403-452. indicated efficiency by taking the company's revenue divided by the number of employees. However, these authors did not considerthat an organization's strategic focus is its operational function, i.e., the process of transforming inputs into outputs (Sheu & Yang, 2005Sheu, H. J., & Yang, C. Y. (2005 July/August). Insider ownership and firm performance in Taiwan's electronics industry: a technical efficiency perspective., Managerial and Decision Economics 26(5),307-318. .

Research on the technical efficiency of companies through data envelopment analysis (DEA) enables access to the problem of corporate governance in a transition scenario. If there is a significant positive relationship between corporate governance practices and technical efficiency, companies should have incentives to develop their governance. For Zheka (2005)Zheka, V. (2005).Corporate governance, ownership structure and corporate efficiency: the case of Ukraine., Managerial and Decision Economics 26(7),451-460., technical efficiency is a useful proxy because it is a single aggregate measure of using input factors to produce desired outputs relative to efficiency. This analysis enables an examination of the root of the corporate governance problem and, specifically, of the inefficient use of resources.

The use of technical efficiency to measure company performance, according to Destefanis e Sena (2007)Destefanis, S., & Sena, V. (2007). Patterns of corporate governance and technical efficiency in italian manufacturing., Managerial and Decision Economics 28(1),27-40., can be justified in many ways: (i) technical efficiency is a good indicator of performance in underdeveloped capital markets because it diminishes the importance of measures based on share price, which may not fully reflect information in the marketplace; (ii) where there is separation between capital and control, managers' inappropriate behavior generates a reduction in technical efficiency, which is captured in the analysis; and (iii) in the economics literature, several authors have demonstrated the existence of a substantial relationship between ownership structure and efficiency (Jensen & Meckling, 1976Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure., Journal of Financial Economics 3(4),305-360.; Belkaoui & Pavlik, 1992Belkaoui, A., & Pavlik, E. (1992 August). The effects of ownership structure and diversification strategy on performance. Managerial and Decision Economics, 13(4),343-352.).

2 Aspects of corporate governance

Assuming that corporate governance is the way that corporate shareholders ensure returns on their investments, thus resolving the conflict of interest between agent and principal, Tirole (2006)Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton: Princeton University Press. suggests two measures discussed below: (i) incentives for executives and (ii) monitoring.

2.1 Incentives for Executives.

Because the scope of questionable performance by executives is large, implicit and explicit, incentives can, in practice, generate value creation for the company (Tirole, 2006Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.). The following are the types of incentives available.

2.1.1 Explicit incentives.

A typical executive receives three types of compensation: salary, bonuses and stock-based incentives. Bonuses and stock-based compensation are the two most important components of incentives because they cause performance-based variations in salary. Baker, Jensen, e Murphy (1988)Baker, G. P., Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1988 July). Compensation and incentives: practice vs. theory., Journal of Finance 43(3),593-616. indicate that the lack of performance compensation systems offers few incentives for executives to structure and strengthen contracts that maximize corporate value. According to Jensen e Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264., executive compensation can positively impact shareholder wellbeing and the company's performance. Kaplan (1994a)Kaplan, S. N. (1994b). Top executives, turnover and firm performance in Germany. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(1),142-159. finds a positive relationship between executive compensation and corporate financial performance in Japan. However, according to Bertrand e Mullainathan (2001)Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2001 August). Are CEOs rewarded for luck? The ones without principals are. Quarterly Journal of Economics,116(3),901-932., executive compensation is often the result of luck. Under these assumptions, the following hypothesis is created:

Hypothesis 1: It is expected that a higher level of total compensation for executives causes them to have greater incentives to seek efficiency, and therefore, there should be a positive relationship between these two variables.

Another aspect of the design of incentive compensation is the (non)linearity of compensation as a function of performance. Shares or "options" (i.e., the right to buy shares at a "strike price" until a specified date) can be offered to executives. Taking into account the percentage of shares owned by company officers and directors, Ghosh (2007)Ghosh, S. (2007). Bank Monitoring, managerial ownership and Tobin's Q: an empirical analysis for India., Managerial and Decision Economics 28(2),129-143. identifies a positive relationship between this variable and company performance, but this relationship is not necessarily monotonic. Babenko (2009)Babenko, I. (2009 February). Share repurchases and pay-performance sensitivity of employee compensation contracts., Journal of Finance 64(1),117-151. shows that share buyback is positively related to executive compensation because executives are forced to assume more risk in companies that repurchase shares, forcing them to exercise their options and receive higher compensation. In contrast, Bergstresser e Philippon (2006)Bergstresser, D., & Philippon, T. (2006 June). CEO incentives and earnings management. Journal of Financial Economics, 80(3),511-529. show that the use of accounting manipulations is more pronounced in companies where the total potential compensation of the Chief Executive Officer (CEO) is more related to the value of shares and options. Thus, during years with greater manipulation, CEOs usually exert a greater number of options and sell large quantities of shares, which shows that incentives based on shares and options are not always the best choice for executive compensation. In the same context, Bennett (2010) finds that when a majority of a company's shares are owned by outside shareholders, that company performs better in the announcement to buy and sell sharesthan companies with primarily inside shareholders.

Slovin and Sushka (1993)Slovin, M. B., & Sushka, M. E. (1993 September). Ownership concentration, corporatecontrol activity, and firm value: evidence from the death of inside blockholders., Journal of Finance 48(4),1293-1321., Ghosh and Ruland (1998)Ghosh, A., & Ruland, W. (1998 April). Managerial ownership, the method of paymentfor acquisitions, and executive job retention., Journal of Finance 53(2),785-798., Hall and Liebman (1998)Hall, B. J., & Liebman, J. B. (1998 August). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats?, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3),653-691. and Fahlenbrach and Stulz (2009)Fahlenbrach, R., & Stulz, R. M. (2009). Managerial ownership dynamics and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3),342-361. find a strong positive relationship between performance and executive compensation that primarily consists of shares and options, but as stated by Dickins and Houmes (2009)Dickins, D., & Houmes, R. (2009). Revisiting the relationship between insider ownership and performance. Journal of Business & Economic Studies, 15(2),32-43., this positive relationship diminishes greatly in markets that are experiencing crises. Florackis, Kostakis, and Ozkan (2009)Florackis, C., Kostakis, A., & Ozkan, A. (2009 December). Managerial ownership and performance. Journal of Business Research, 62(12),1350-1357. arrive at the same result using a semiparametric approach. Along the same lines, Bulan, Sanyal, and Yan (2010)Bulan, L., Sanyal, P., & Yan, Z. (2010 July/August). A few bad apples: an analysis of CEO performance pay and firm productivity. Journal of Economics and Business, 62(4),273-306. find a non monotonic positive relationship between productive efficiency and executive share ownership, and Guedri and Hollandts (2008)Guedri, Z., & Hollandts, X. (2008 September). Beyond dichotomy: the curvilinear impact ofemployee ownership on firm performance. Journal of Corporate Governance, 16(5),460-474. identify this relationship in French companies as having the form of an inverted "U". In accordance with these assumptions, the following hypotheses are formulated:

Hypothesis 2: The fact that executives own company shares creates incentives for them to seek efficiency, so this relationship should be positive.

Hypothesis 3: The fact that executives own company options creates incentives for them to seek efficiency, so this relationship should be positive.

2.1.2 Implicit incentives.

Naturally, executives are concerned with keeping their jobs. Unsatisfactory performance causes directors to remove executives from their posts. Directors may voluntarily fire executives or can implicitly or explicitly pressurethemto quit if shareholders observe that the company's stock price or profit is lower than expected (Tirole, 2006Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.). In this context, Boyer and Ortiz-Molina (2008)Boyer, M. M., & Ortiz-Molina, H (2008 May). Career concerns of top executives, managerial ownership and CEO succession. Corporate Governance: An International Review,16(3),178-193. argue that career preoccupation causes executives to make riskier decisions.

Some studies, such as those by Weisbach (1988)Weisbach, M. S. (1988). Outside directors and CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics, 20(1),431-460. and Jensen and Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264., have documented an inverse relationship between company performance and the likelihood of executive turnover (i.e., a change in the identity of the CEO in a given period). These results suggest that executives are more likely to leave a company after years of bad performance than after years of good performance, and therefore, they are disciplined by the threat of termination. However, for Chen, Goldstein, and Jiang (2008)Chen, Q., Goldstein, I., & Jiang, W. (2008 December). Directors' ownership in the U.S. mutual fund industry., Journal of Finance 63(6),2629-2677., turnover is a good proxy for determining whether directors effectively monitor the executives.

Other studies, such as those by Jensen and Warner (1988)Jensen, M. C., & Warner, J. B. (1988). The distribution of power among corporate managers, shareholders and directors., Journal of Financial 'Economics 20(1),3-24. and Gilson (1989)Gilson, S. C. (1989 December). Management turnover and financial distress., Journal of Financial Economics 25(2),211-262., find an inverse relationship between turnover and performance. Gilson (1989)Gilson, S. C. (1989 December). Management turnover and financial distress., Journal of Financial Economics 25(2),211-262. shows that 52% of companies surveyed turnover executives when they are in financial difficulty or bankruptcy. Executives who have resigned from their companies typically are not hired by another listed company during the three subsequent years. This phenomenon is also observed by Kaplan (1994b)Kaplan, S. N. (1994b). Top executives, turnover and firm performance in Germany. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(1),142-159. for German companies. According to these assumptions, the following hypotheses are formulated:

Hypothesis 4: Executive turnover is negatively related to company efficiency because it may indicate financial difficulties arising out of mismanagement.

Hypothesis 4A: Executive turnover is positively related to company efficiency because it indicates an improvement in performance requirements.

Jensen e Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264. suggest that the risk of CEOs being fired by the board decreases with time. The authors argue that the risk of dismissal is more pronounced for younger CEOs because, over time, they will form their power bases. Based on this assumption, the following hypothesis is formulated:

Hypothesis 5: The executive's age is negatively related to efficiency because, in general, older CEOs have established their power bases and make less risky decisions.

The power granted to company executives can elucidate important aspects of executive compensation that have long been a puzzle for researchers working on models of optimal contracts, primarily with regard to the separation of ownership and control. Jensen (1993)Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems., Journal of Finance 48(3),831-880. and Bebchuk and Fried (2003)Bebchuk, L. A., & Fried, J. M. (2003). Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3),71-92. explain that the influence of executives on their own pay, hiring, and firing, among others factors, can generate substantial costs for share holders that can distort incentives and hurt corporate performance. Goyal and Park (2002)Goyal, V. K., & Park, C. W. (2002). Board leadership structure and CEO turnover., Journal of Corporate Finance 8(1),49-66. argue that the sensitivity of CEO turnover to company performance is significantly lower when the CEO also serves on the board of directors. This result demonstrates that an executive's dual status as a board member hinders dismissal due to weak performance. Thus, the following hypothesis is formulated:

Hypothesis 6: The fact that the executive serves on the board, especially when the CEO isthe chairman of the board, may impair corporate efficiency, and thus, there is a negative relationship between the variables.

The optimal contract hypothesis predicts that monitoring by the directors is less necessary when there are other control mechanisms that are effective in reducing the agency problem. Chen et al. (2008)Chen, Q., Goldstein, I., & Jiang, W. (2008 December). Directors' ownership in the U.S. mutual fund industry., Journal of Finance 63(6),2629-2677. state that two measures capture the power of incentives for executives: tenure, which is measured by the number of years that the executive has held office, and the size of the executive group. The optimal contract hypothesis predicts a negative relationship of tenure and number of chief executives with efficiency. The idea behind this statement is that executives who are in power for longer have fewer worries about the job market, and thus,the demand for monitoring is relatively high for executives who have served for a longer period.

The existence of a large number of executives also generates more monitoring because the greater the number of executives, the greater the oversight by the directors. Goyal e Park (2002)Goyal, V. K., & Park, C. W. (2002). Board leadership structure and CEO turnover., Journal of Corporate Finance 8(1),49-66. find a negative effect of tenure on the company because a long tenure may represent that the CEO has established a power base. In this context, the following hypotheses are formulated:

Hypothesis 7: Executive tenure is negatively related to corporate efficiency because it can worsen the agency problem.

Hypothesis 8: The number of executives is negatively related to the company's efficiency because the demand for monitoring is greater, thereby increasing the costs.

2.2 Monitoring.

Companies are monitored by various external agents, including board members, auditors, major shareholders, creditors, investment banks, and rating agencies. First, the board members monitor the company's management on behalf of shareholders (Tirole, 2006Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.). Studies such as Gilson (1990)Gilson, S. C. (1990 October). Bankruptcy, boards, banks and blockholders: evidence on changes in corporate ownership and control when firms default., Journal of Financial Economics 27(2),355-388. have shown the importance of measuring the impact of the composition of the board of directors on company performance: the proportion of independent directors is the most important question to evaluate, which demonstrates the positive relationship between these variables.

Faleye, Hoitash, e Hoitash (2011)Faleye, O., Hoitash, R., & Hoitash, U. (2011). The costs of intense board monitoring., Journal of Financial Economics 101(1),160-181. claim that directors may be either affiliated with the company or independent and that the latter group has no significant relationship with the company. Due to this objectivity, independent directors are seen as valuable monitors, and their involvement with the board is usually related to improvement in the company's accounting system and greater shareholder protection. Brick and Chidambaran (2010)Brick, I. E., & Chidambaran, N. K. (2010 September). Board meetings, committee structure, and firm value. Journal of Corporate Finance, 16(4),533-553. find a positive relationship between the number of independent directors and company performance after increased external pressure from the stock exchanges to seat independent directors. Beasley (1996)Beasley, M. S. (1996 October). An empirical analysis of the relation between the board of director composition and financial statement fraud. Accounting Review, 71(4),443-465. shows that the percentage of independent board members is lower in companies that have had fraud scandals.

However, Adams and Ferreira (2007)Adams, R. B., & Ferreira, D. (2007 February). A theory of friendly boards. Journal of Finance, 62(1),217-250. present a model in which independent directors can suffer severe consequences because administrators are less inclined to share information with directors as the intensity of monitoring increases. With less information, the board cannot monitor effectively. In his most recent study, Adams (2009)Adams, R. B. (2009). Asking directors about their dual roles. Working Paper, University of Queensland. suggests that directors who primarily monitor executives are less affected than directors who only direct, suggesting that monitoring alone is not sufficient for good governance. In the same vein, Cohen, Frazzini, and Malloy (2012)Cohen, L., Frazzini, A., & Malloy, C. (2012 June). Hiring cheerleaders: board appointments of "independent" directors. Management Science, 58(6),1039-1058. show that companies tend to appoint independent directors that have a more optimistic view of the company and who are less efficient monitors. Those authors also identify that the more optimistic the independent directors, themore poorly managed the companies and the larger the subsequent increases in executive compensation. According to these assumptions, the following hypotheses have been formulated:

Hypothesis 9: An increase in the proportion of independent directors is positively related to efficiency because independent directors have fewer vices related to the company, which could increase effective monitoring.

Hypothesis 9A: An increase in the proportion of independent directors is negatively associated with efficiency because companies tend to appoint directors who are more optimistic and less efficient monitors.

Franks and Myer (2001)Franks, J., & Mayer, C. (2001). Ownership e control in German corporations. The, Review of Financial Studies 14(4),943-977. find a positive relationship between loss of revenue and director turnover due to lack of continuity in decision-making, thereby showing an inverse relationship between these two variables. In the same context, Gilson (1990)Gilson, S. C. (1990 October). Bankruptcy, boards, banks and blockholders: evidence on changes in corporate ownership and control when firms default., Journal of Financial Economics 27(2),355-388. states that on average, only 46% of directors remain with a company after financial difficulties or possible bankruptcy. This negative relationship is also identified by Yermack (1996)Yermack, D. (1996). Higher market valuation of companies with a small board of directors., Journal of Financial Economics 40(2),185-211.. The result suggests that financial difficulties generate significant changes to board structure and decision-making related to the allocation of corporate resources.

Arthaud-Day, Certo, Dalton, and Dalton (2006)Arthaud-Day, M. L., Certo, S. T., Dalton, C. M., & Dalton, D. R. (2006). A changing of the guard: executive and director turnover following corporate financial restatements. Academy of Management Journal, 49(6),1119-1136. demonstrate that changes in the board of directors occur more frequently when a company is restructuring. In the same vein, Agrawal, Jaffe, e Karpoff (1999)Agrawal, A.,Jaffe, J. F., & Karpoff, J. M. (1999). Management turnover and governance changes following the revelation of fraud. Journal of Law and Economics, 42(1),309-342. show that fraud scandals can create incentives to change the board of directors to increase company performance through increased monitoring and the presence of directors with better reputations. These factors show that turnover can be positively connected to efficiency. Based on these assumptions, the following hypotheses are formulated:

Hypothesis 10: Turnover of the chairman of the board is positively related to efficiency because it may represent an increase in monitoring by hiring directors with better reputations, especially if the company had experienced a fraud scandal.

Hypothesis 10A: Turnover of the chairman of the board is negatively correlated with efficiency because it creates problems related to the continuity of decision-making, which has an impact on company revenues.

Jensen (1993)Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems., Journal of Finance 48(3),831-880. and Nanka-Bruce (2009)Nanka-Bruce, D. (2009 October). The impact of large shareholdings and board structure on efficiency. Working-Paper, Universidade Autônoma de Barcelona. claim that having a small board can help increase company performance. When a board has more than seven or eight people, it is less able to function effectively in terms of monitoring, and it becomes easier for the CEO to maintain control. Consequently, board size is negatively related to company efficiency. Yermack (1996)Yermack, D. (1996). Higher market valuation of companies with a small board of directors., Journal of Financial Economics 40(2),185-211. also finds that companies with smaller boards have better financial indices and better financial incentives for executives. In that context, the following hypothesis is formulated:

Hypothesis 11: Board size negatively influences a company's efficiency because it is less able to function effectively.

Chen et al. (2008)Chen, Q., Goldstein, I., & Jiang, W. (2008 December). Directors' ownership in the U.S. mutual fund industry., Journal of Finance 63(6),2629-2677. argue that directors with greater longevity in office generally have greater financial resources, prompting them to invest more in company ownership and creating a positive relationship among ownership, age, tenure and,consequently, efficiency.

In the same context, but using different arguments, Adams (2009)Adams, R. B. (2009). Asking directors about their dual roles. Working Paper, University of Queensland. and Faleye et al. (2011)Faleye, O., Hoitash, R., & Hoitash, U. (2011). The costs of intense board monitoring., Journal of Financial Economics 101(1),160-181. find that the longer a director serves, the greater his or her decision-making performance. The authors argue that knowledge and professional experience make directors more likely to choose the correct strategic alternative. Additionally, because they have longer periods of service, these directors also generate greater confidence on the part of CEOsby being less critical and more understanding when evaluating potential strategic options. Consistent with this fact, the following hypotheses are formulated:

Hypothesis 12: Director tenure is positively related to efficiency because longer-serving directors are more prepared to make strategic decisions.

Hypothesis 13: Director age is positively related to efficiency because older directors have more experience and influence, thus facilitating interaction with the CEO.

3 Methodological Aspects

To analyze the influence of aspects of governance on the efficiency of publicly traded Brazilian companies, we conducted exploratory and descriptive research based on quantitative methods. The steps used to conduct the study are described below:

Data collection: secondary data extracted from specific databases in Brazil were used to conduct this study. The basic data relating to ownership structure balance sheet and income statement, among others were taken from Economática. Data on the number of employees were taken from companies' websites, Portal Exame and the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). Finally, we used data collected manually from the 20-F SEC reports to analyze aspects of corporate governance (this idea is from Funchal and Terra, 2006Funchal, J. A., & Terra, P. R. S. (2006). Remuneração de executivos, desempenho econômico e governança corporativa: um estudo empírico em empresas latino-americanas. Anais do Encontro Associação Nacional de Pesquisa e Pós-graduação em Administração, Salvador, BA, Brasil, 30.).

Scope and sample: this work covers publicly traded companies listed on the SEC with stock traded at the Stock Exchange of São Paulo (Bolsa de Valores de São Paulo Bovespa) (ADRs). Data collection was performed in two steps. To analyze the relative efficiency of companies, data were obtained for an average of 515 companies with shares traded at Bovespa during 1999-2009 (11 years), totaling 5,665 company-years (data on all the companies traded in this period were used). Because DEA does not accept missing data, the company-years that did not have all available data were removed, resulting in 4,046 company-years. This sample was divided by year (11 years) and by sector (13 sectors), generating 143 different analyses. This measure was taken because,given that the DEA is a calculation of relative efficiency (efficient relative to other companies that are in the sample), companies could not be compared to themselves in previous years or to companies belonging to different sectors in which the measures, standards, and conventions are very different. To identify the 13 sectors mentioned, the same criteria as those of the Economática database (which classifies 21 different sectors) were used, and some of these were rearranged by a homogeneity criterion because they had few companies, thus precluding analysis.

The sectors were thus arranged as follows: (1) finance and securities (35 companies per year on average); (2) construction (22 companies per year on average); (3) steel, metallurgy, and mining of metal products (39 companies per year on average); (4) provision of services (30 companies per year on average); (5) food and beverage (24 companies per year on average); (6) manufacture of vehicles, machinery, parts, and electronics (38 companies per year on average); (7) telecommunications (26 companies per year on average); (8) textiles (29 companies per year on average); (9) chemicals, oil, and gas (24 companies per year on average); (10) cellulose, agriculture, fishing, and mining of non-metallic products (22 companies per year on average); (11) trade (16 companies per year on average); (12) management of companies and enterprises (22 companies per year on average); and (13) electric power (38 companies per year on average).

Much data relating to corporate governance is not supplied by Brazilian companies, particularly for such a long time series, because it is not included in the Bovespa or other known databases in Brazil. Therefore, the data were manually collected and analyzed from the 20-F reports of Brazilian companies that had ADRs, which contained a relatively complete set of information for these companies. However, the sample had to be reduced because few Brazilian companies have ADRs. The first sample was used to calculate efficiency using DEA, and the second was reduced to the number of companies that had data on corporate governance. When the two databases were combined, only 396 company-years remained to be analyzed, that is, an average of 40 companies (not all companies had data for all 11 years).

Software: the programs used were (i) DEA-Solver-Pro® to calculate DEA and (ii) Stata SE® to calculate linear regressions.

1. Calculation of Companies' Relative Efficiency: The first step consisted of calculating the relative efficiency of publicly traded Brazilian companies through DEA. The use of these variables was inspired by the model from Nanka-Bruce (2009)Nanka-Bruce, D. (2009 October). The impact of large shareholdings and board structure on efficiency. Working-Paper, Universidade Autônoma de Barcelona. and were arranged as follows: (i) three types of input variables the cash value of tangible and intangible assets; the cash value of material costs and operating expenses; and a log of the number of employees, and (ii) two types of output variables the cash value of revenues and Tobin's q, a performance measure based on market value. Tobin's q is calculated based on Chung and Pruitt (1994)Chung, K. H., & Pruitt, S. W. (1994). A simple approximation of Tobin's Q. Financial Management, 23(3),70-74., who consider it to be the ratio between the market and book values of the company's total assets, i.e., q=(MVE+PS+D)/TA, where MVE is the product of the company's stock price and the number of common stock shares in circulation, PS is the liquidating value of outstanding preferred stock, D is total debt, and TA is the total assets of the company. Total debt is calculated as follows: D = CL - CA + S + LTD, where CL is current liabilities, CA is current assets, Sis Stock, and LTD is Long Term Debt. The data used to compose this variable were taken from Economática. Two methods were used for DEA: (i) variable returns to scale (BCC); and (ii) total efficiency (GRS). The model used is additive because it simultaneously maximizes outputs and minimizes inputs, and it is the most recommended model for analyses involving costs and financial results (Cooper, Seiford, & Zhu, 2004Cooper, W.W., Seiford, L. M., & Zhu, J. (2004). Handbook on data envelopment analysis. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.). To calculate DEA, several steps were necessary. First, the variables were winsorized, i.e., a new variable identical to the previous variable was generated, except for the lower extreme values​​, which were replaced by the next smallest value, and the higher values, which were replaced by the previous value. This was done to reduce the influence of outliers on the analysis. It was decided to use 5% in winsorization. Second, the correlation test was applied to assess whether the variables were highly correlated. If so, an analysis was conducted to identify the less-significant variable so it could be removed from the model. Third, the variables were separated by year and by sector, generating 143 analyses (11 years and 13 different sectors). The index generated constitutes the relative efficiency of companies and is used as the dependent variable in the regression.

2. Analysis of the influence of corporate governance on efficiency: To assess the influence of ownership structure on company efficiency, we used the unbalanced panel data model that employs the generalized method of moments (GMM), which is a tool that considers a given sample of individuals over time and allows multiple observations of each individual in the sample. In this case, the dynamic model (which considers the lagged dependent variable as explanatory) and differences (GMM-Sys) were applied. The instruments used were the lagged variables, as proposed by Almeida, Campello, and Galvão (2010)Almeida, H., Campello, M., & Galvão, A. F. (2010 September). Measurement errors in investment equations. Review of Financial Studies, 23(9),3279-3328.. To conduct the analysis, the following tests were applied: (i) the correlation test, which checks whether the variables are highly related and, if so, assesses which variable is least significant so it can be removed from the model; (ii) the Arellano and Bond (1991)Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991 April). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2),277-297. test, which tests the existence of serial correlation; (iii) the test of over-identification by Hansen J (1982)Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50(4),1029-1054.; and (iv) Chi-square (X2). As in the DEA, the variables are winsorized at 5%. Formula 1 shows the dependent variable and the independent variables of the model.

where E represents the efficiency of companies, α is the intercept, (, ( and ( are the coefficients of the variables, Zit are the variables related to ownership structure, Witare the variables related to corporate governance, Cit represent the control variables, EFind represents fixed industry effects, EFtemp represents temporal fixed effects, and εit is the error term. The variables relating to ownership structure are as follows: (i) ownership structure of the principal share holder PSV; (ii) ownership structure of the three principal share holders TSV; and (iii) ownership structure of the top five shareholders FSV. The ownership structures of the top-three and top-five shareholders were considered because, according to Laeven e Levine (2008)Laeven, L., & Levine, R. (2008). Complex ownership structures and corporate valuations., Review of Financial Studies 21(2),579-604., one-third of European companies have multiple large shareholders with market value that differs from companies that have a dispersion or concentration of shares. This shows the need to examine not only the largest shareholder but also the remaining majority shareholders. For simplicity, only regressions with PSV and FSV are shown in the tables. The governance variables, defined in the literature review and hypothesis formulation, are as follows: (i) number of directors; (ii) tenure of directors; (iii) age of directors; (iv) number of independent directors; (v) number of executives on the board; (vi) dummy if the CEO is also chairman of the board; (vii) dummy for director turnover; (viii) number of chief executives; (ix) age of executives; (x) tenure of executives; (xi) dummy for executive turnover; (xii) equity ownership of executives in the company; (xiii) options for executives; and (xiv) executive compensation. The variables "options for executives" and "executive compensation" are adjusted for inflation using the General Price Index Internal Availability (Índice Geral de Preços-Disponibilidade Interna - IGP-DI). These variables are defined in Appendix A. With respect to the control variables, the following measures were included in the equation: (i) size total assets; (ii) leverage current and long-term liabilities on stockholders' equity; (iii) industry fixed effects; and (iv) temporal fixed effects.

Because the dependent variable in the model is limited to a number from zero to 100, there is a possibility of problems with truncated variables. For this reason, the algorithm from Simar and Wilson (2007)Simar, L., & Wilson, P. W. (2007). Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-parametric models of production processes. J Econometrics, 136(1),31-64. was applied in two stages to improve the statistical inference of the measures of technical efficiency. Examples from Souza, Souza, and Staub (2009)Souza, M. O., Souza, G. S., & Staub, R. B. (2009 maio/agosto). Influência das variáveis contextuais em medidas não-paramétricas de eficiência: uma aplicação com métodos de reamostragem. Pesquisa Operacional, 29(2),289-302. were also used as parameters to analyze the model.

4 Analysis of Results

This subsection aims to identify how agent-principal conflicts affect efficiency and whether incentives have a positive effect on the performance of Brazilian corporations. Using the descriptive statistics presented in Table 1, we found that on average, companies have nine to ten directors, each of whom spend approximately three years on the board. On average, the directors are 54 years old. The companies have six or seven principal executives, who are 50 years old on average and spend approximately three and one-half years in office. Executives' equity interest is very low, an average of just under 0.02%. Total compensation, deflated to the year 1999, is approximately R$ 7.3 million, representing R$1.09 million per year for each executive, with options that average R$9.09 million. With respect to performance, companies have 61.45% total efficiency on average; when considering only variable returns to scale, this average increases to 86.70%.

Table 1
Descriptive statistics

Tables 2 and 3 show the analyses for the influence of the board of directors on efficiency using the BCC method and the influence of executive compensation on efficiency using the GRS method. The other tables were omitted because they showed similar results. All the variables addressed in the review were tested separately and in combination, and the ownership structure variable was included in the last regression. At the bottom of the tables, the Hansen J (1982)Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50(4),1029-1054. over-identification test is shown, showing that in all analyses, the null hypothesis is not rejected and indicating that the instruments are apparently uncorrelated with the error term of the regression.

Table 2
Analysis of the Board of Directors' influence on efficiency using the BCC method
Table 3
Analysis of the influence of executive compensation on efficiency using the GRS method

In the chi-squared test (X2), the null hypothesis is rejected, indicating that the observed frequencies are not different from the expected frequencies, i.e., there is an association between groups of variables in the models presented. Finally, in the Arellano and Bond (1991)Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991 April). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2),277-297. test (AR(1) and AR(2)), the null hypothesis is rejected in most of the regressions with respect to the lack of serial correlation in the first-order residuals, and the hypothesis is not rejected for the second order. Therefore, for these, the model shows serial correlation of first order, an important assumption for the validity of instruments based on the lag of regressors, as in the case of GMM-Sys used in the analysis. For the sake of synthesis, some regressions that showed similar results were omitted.

In Regression 8 on Table 2, ownership structure negatively influences efficiency in a subsequent period, showing that a 1% change in the ownership structure of the principal shareholder adversely affects efficiency by 0.17% at a 10% significance level using the BCC method. In economic terms, for a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.09, the influence is 0.015%.

When the companies analyzed are considered separately, the number of directors (Regression 1) negatively influences efficiency, i.e.,a 1% change in the number of directors adversely affects efficiency by 0.14% at a 10% significance level using the BCC method, and in economic terms, a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.09 has an influence of 0.01%. This result is consistent with the studies of Jensen (1993)Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems., Journal of Finance 48(3),831-880. and Nanka-Bruce (2009)Nanka-Bruce, D. (2009 October). The impact of large shareholdings and board structure on efficiency. Working-Paper, Universidade Autônoma de Barcelona., which state that having a small board of directors can help to increase company performance, thus not rejecting Hypothesis 11. Combined analyses corroborate the assumptions of the model, although this variable is not significant in Regression 8. In terms of length of service, this variable negatively influences efficiency when considered separately (Regression 2), i.e., a 1% change in length of service adversely affects efficiency by 0.07% using the BCC method at a 10% significance level, and in economic terms, the influence of a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.04 is0.003%, thereby rejecting Hypothesis 12. In contrast, in the two combined analyses (Regression 8 in Table 2 and Regression9 in Table 3), this variable is positive and significant, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 12and corroborating Adams (2009)Adams, R. B. (2009). Asking directors about their dual roles. Working Paper, University of Queensland. and Faleye et al. (2011)Faleye, O., Hoitash, R., & Hoitash, U. (2011). The costs of intense board monitoring., Journal of Financial Economics 101(1),160-181..

The age of directors positively influences efficiency (Regression 3) i.e., a 1% increase in the age of the directors increases efficiency by 0.56% using the BCC method at a 10% significance level, where as in economic terms, the influence of a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.31 is 0.17%, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 13. This analysis is consistent with Adams (2009)Adams, R. B. (2009). Asking directors about their dual roles. Working Paper, University of Queensland., who argues that younger directors tend to have less influence on the board, interact less with CEOs and, consequently, hinder information exchange between the parties, thus affecting efficiency.

In separate analyses, the number of independent directors compared to the total number of directors (Regression 4) had a positive relationship with efficiency, i.e., a 1% increase in the proportion of independent directors on the board increases efficiency by 0.08% at a 5% significance level, and in economic terms, the influence of a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.03 is 0.002%, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 9. This result is consistent with studies from Faleye, Hoitash, and Hoitash (2011)Faleye, O., Hoitash, R., & Hoitash, U. (2011). The costs of intense board monitoring., Journal of Financial Economics 101(1),160-181., which state that independent directors are seen as valuable monitors and that their involvement with the board is normally related to improvements in a company's accounting system and increased shareholder protection. The combined analyses are consistent with this result, and in Regression 9 in Table 3, this variable has a significance level of 1%.

In line with this theory, when considering the number of executives on the board relative to the total number of directors, it is evident that this variable is negatively correlated with efficiency when considered separately (Regression 5). That is, a 1% increase in the proportion of the number of executives on the board decreases efficiency by 0.06% at a 10% significance level, and in economic terms, a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.03 has a 0.002% influence, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 6. This result is in line with Jensen (1993)Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems., Journal of Finance 48(3),831-880., Goyal and Park (2002)Goyal, V. K., & Park, C. W. (2002). Board leadership structure and CEO turnover., Journal of Corporate Finance 8(1),49-66. and Bebchuk and Fried (2003)Bebchuk, L. A., & Fried, J. M. (2003). Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3),71-92., who explain that executives' influence on their own compensation, hiring, firing, and other factors can generate substantial costs for shareholders that can distort incentives and damage corporate performance. This result corroborates the combined regression analysis of Regression 9 in Table 3, in which the result is negative at a 1% significance level.

Consistent with the previous results, the fact that the CEO is also chairman of the board of directors further negatively influences company efficiency when considered separately (Regression 6). That is, if the company chooses to seat the CEO as chairman of the board, efficiency decreases by 0.24% at a 10% significance level, and in economic terms, a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.16 has a 0.04% influence, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 6. This result is also corroborated by Regression 9 in Table 3, where this variable is negative at a 1% significance level.

Finally, in the case of chairman turnover, this variable positively influences efficiency, and in a separate analysis (Regression 7), the fact that there is a change in chairman from the previous year increases company efficiency by 0.22% at a 5% significance level. In economic terms, a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.10 has a 0.02% influence, which does not reject Hypothesis 10. This result was also found in the combined analysis, although it was not significant in Regression 8. This analysis is consistent with the studies of Agrawal et al. (1999)Agrawal, A.,Jaffe, J. F., & Karpoff, J. M. (1999). Management turnover and governance changes following the revelation of fraud. Journal of Law and Economics, 42(1),309-342., which show that fraud scandals can create incentives to change the board of directors for the purpose of increasing company performance through increased monitoring and hiring directors with better reputations.

When considering the data for the executives (Table 3), ownership structure negatively influences efficiency during a subsequent period, showing that a 1% change in the ownership structure of the top five shareholders negatively affects efficiency by 1.01% at a 1% significance level, and in economic terms, at a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.19, this influence is 0.19%.

When the companies analyzed are considered separately, the number of chief executives (Regression 1) negatively influences efficiency. That is, a 1% change in the number of chief executives negatively affects efficiency by 0.11% at a 10% significance level, and in economic terms, at a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.06, this influence is 0.007%, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 8. The combined analyses corroborate the separate analysis (Regressions 8 and 9 of Table 3). This result is in line with Chen, Goldstein, e Jiang (2008)Chen, Q., Goldstein, I., & Jiang, W. (2008 December). Directors' ownership in the U.S. mutual fund industry., Journal of Finance 63(6),2629-2677., who claim that a large number of executives generate a larger monitoring effort.

In considering the age of the executives, when taken separately, this variable positively influences efficiency (Regression 2). That is, a 1% change in the age of top executives positively affects efficiency by 0.88% at a 5% significance level, and in economic terms, at a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.42, this influence is 0.37%, thereby rejecting Hypothesis 5. This result agrees with Jensen e Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264..

With respect to the average number of years that chief executives are in office, when analyzed separately, this variable negatively influences efficiency (Regression 3). That is, a 1% change in the tenure of the top executives negatively affects efficiency by 0.05% using the BCC method at a level of 5%, and in economic terms, at a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.02, this influence is 0.001%, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 7. This result is consistent with the studies of Goyal e Park (2002)Goyal, V. K., & Park, C. W. (2002). Board leadership structure and CEO turnover., Journal of Corporate Finance 8(1),49-66., who find a negative effect of tenure on the company because a long tenure may mean that the CEO has established a power base. The combined analyses did not corroborate this result.

In considering a change in company presidency, when taken separately, this variable negatively influences efficiency (Regression 4). That is, turnover of the chief executive adversely affects efficiency by 0.19% at a 5% level of significance, whereas in economic terms, a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.09 has a 0.02% influence, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 4. This result is consistent with the studies of Jensen and Warner (1988)Jensen, M. C., & Warner, J. B. (1988). The distribution of power among corporate managers, shareholders and directors., Journal of Financial 'Economics 20(1),3-24., Gilson (1989)Gilson, S. C. (1989 December). Management turnover and financial distress., Journal of Financial Economics 25(2),211-262. and Kaplan (1994b)Kaplan, S. N. (1994b). Top executives, turnover and firm performance in Germany. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(1),142-159., who find that most companies turnover executives when they are in financial difficulty or bankruptcy. The combined analysis in Regression 9 corroborates the results.

Regressions 5, 6, and 7 refer to explicit incentives that may exist. Taking into consideration executives' equity interest (Regression 5), when taken separately, this variable positively influences efficiency. That is, a 1% increase in the equity interest of the major share holders positively affects efficiency by 2.53% at a 10% significance level, and in economic terms, at a one-standard-deviation difference of 1.42, this influence is 3.59%, thus supporting Hypothesis 2. This result is in line with Jensen and Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264., Ghosh (2007)Ghosh, S. (2007). Bank Monitoring, managerial ownership and Tobin's Q: an empirical analysis for India., Managerial and Decision Economics 28(2),129-143. and Fahlenbrach and Stulz (2009)Fahlenbrach, R., & Stulz, R. M. (2009). Managerial ownership dynamics and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3),342-361., among others, who show that if executives have partial ownership, they have incentives to reduce agency problems. However, these results are not corroborated by the combined analysis, where this variable is negative and significantly related with efficiency (Regressions 8 and 9).

"Options" (namely, the right to buy shares at a "strike price") may be offered to the executives until a specified date. The choice of options as an incentive for CEOs, when analyzed separately, positively influences efficiency. That is, a 1% increase in the choice of options positively affects efficiency by 0.03% at a 10% significance level, and in economic terms, at a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.02, this influence is 0.0006%, thus not rejecting Hypothesis 3. The combined analysis in Regression 9 corroborates the separate analysis. This result is in line with Slovin and Sushka (1993)Slovin, M. B., & Sushka, M. E. (1993 September). Ownership concentration, corporatecontrol activity, and firm value: evidence from the death of inside blockholders., Journal of Finance 48(4),1293-1321., Ghosh and Ruland (1998)Ghosh, A., & Ruland, W. (1998 April). Managerial ownership, the method of paymentfor acquisitions, and executive job retention., Journal of Finance 53(2),785-798., Hall and Liebman (1998)Hall, B. J., & Liebman, J. B. (1998 August). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats?, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3),653-691. and Fahlenbrach and Stulz (2009)Fahlenbrach, R., & Stulz, R. M. (2009). Managerial ownership dynamics and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3),342-361., who identify options as incentives for executives to pursue higher company performance.

Finally, for executive compensation in Regression 7, a 1% increase in this variable positively affects efficiency by 0.07% at a 5% significance level using the GRS method, and in economic terms, at a one-standard-deviation difference of 0.03, this influence is 0.002%. These results are in agreement with the combined analysis in Regression 9, there by corroborating Hypothesis 1. This relationship is consistent with the studies of Jensen and Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264. and Kaplan (1994a)Kaplan, S. N. (1994b). Top executives, turnover and firm performance in Germany. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(1),142-159., who shows that executive compensation may positively impact both shareholder wellbeing and company performance because it generates incentives for executives to resolve agency problems. The negative sign and significance of this variable in Regression 8 indicates the possibility that this result may be ambiguous, as described by Baker et al. (1988)Baker, G. P., Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1988 July). Compensation and incentives: practice vs. theory., Journal of Finance 43(3),593-616., who show that if compensation is not performance-related, there are few incentives for executives to structure and strengthen contracts to maximize corporate value.

In terms of control variables, those relating to size, represented by total assets, showed a positive relationship with efficiency and were only significant in Regressions 1, 2, 3, 4, 5 and 8 of Table 2 and in Regressions 1, 2 and 8 of Table 3. The variable referring to leverage was negatively related to efficiency in virtually all analyses but was only significant in Regression 5 of Table 2 and in Regressions 2, 7 and 8 of Table 3 because, according to Boubakri and Cosset (1998)Boubakri, N., & Cosset, J. C. (1998 June). The financial and operating performance of newly privatized firms: evidence from developing countries. Journal of Finance, 53(3),1081-1110., there is a tendency for leverage to decrease as efficiency increases because an increase in debt can hinder the efficient allocation of resources. Finally, temporal and industry dummy variables were used in all regressions. The lagged dependent variable was positive and significant in most analyses, showing that in those regressions, company efficiency during one period influences efficiency during a later period.

The Simar e Wilson (2007)Simar, L., & Wilson, P. W. (2007). Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-parametric models of production processes. J Econometrics, 136(1),31-64. algorithm was also applied at two stages to correct for bias in truncated variables, as explained in the methodology. In Table 4, the primary results are summarized. For the sake of synthesis, only variables related to corporate governance were made explicit. The first analysis shown was calculated by maximum likelihood using the truncated normal regression without considering the 100% efficient observations (TR - E), whereas the second was calculated using truncated regression but using 2,000 bootstrap replications

Table 4
Algorithm from Simar and Wilson (2007) to correct bias in truncated variables

Finally, correction bias was performed, and the relative bias between the two regressions shown was calculated. In almost all analyses, the bias was greater than 1%. However, the results were qualitatively similar to those found in previous regressions, even though some were not statistically significant, as in the case of the variables "board size", "number of independent directors", "chief executive on the board" (but the variable "number of executives on the board" was significantly negative), "director turnover", "number of top executives", and "equity interest of executives." The only variable that showed different results was "age of chief executive", which showed a significant negative relationship, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 5 and corroborating Jensen e Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264..

5 Conclusions and Contributions of the Study

Because the possibility of questionable performance by executives is large, in practice, implicit and explicit incentives can generate value creation for the company. For this reason, it is important to analyze the influence of these incentives on efficiency. With respect to executive compensation, this variable was positive when analyzed separately, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 1. This relationship is consistent with the studies of Jensen e Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264. e Kaplan (1994a)Kaplan, S. N. (1994b). Top executives, turnover and firm performance in Germany. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(1),142-159., who show that executive compensation can positively impact shareholder wellbeing and company performance of the company because it provides the executive with incentives to resolve the agency problem.

Taking into consideration executives' equity interest, this variable positively influences efficiency when considered separately, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 2. This result is in line with Jensen and Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264., Ghosh (2007)Ghosh, S. (2007). Bank Monitoring, managerial ownership and Tobin's Q: an empirical analysis for India., Managerial and Decision Economics 28(2),129-143. and Fahlenbrach and Stulz (2009)Fahlenbrach, R., & Stulz, R. M. (2009). Managerial ownership dynamics and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3),342-361., among others, who find a strong positive relationship between performance and executive compensation, resulting primarily from shares owned by CEOs that create incentives to reduce agency problems because executives with part ownership will be more likely to generate profit for the company. The choice of options as an incentive for CEOs was also significant, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 3 and corroborating studies of Slovin and Sushka (1993)Slovin, M. B., & Sushka, M. E. (1993 September). Ownership concentration, corporatecontrol activity, and firm value: evidence from the death of inside blockholders., Journal of Finance 48(4),1293-1321., Ghosh and Ruland (1998)Ghosh, A., & Ruland, W. (1998 April). Managerial ownership, the method of paymentfor acquisitions, and executive job retention., Journal of Finance 53(2),785-798., Hall and Liebman (1998)Hall, B. J., & Liebman, J. B. (1998 August). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats?, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3),653-691. and Fahlenbrach and Stulz (2009)Fahlenbrach, R., & Stulz, R. M. (2009). Managerial ownership dynamics and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3),342-361., which identified that options are incentives for the executive to seek higher company performance.

Considering implicit incentives, a change in company presidency negatively influences efficiency, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 4 but rejecting Hypothesis 4A. This result is consistent with the studies of Jensen and Warner (1988)Jensen, M. C., & Warner, J. B. (1988). The distribution of power among corporate managers, shareholders and directors., Journal of Financial 'Economics 20(1),3-24., Gilson (1989)Gilson, S. C. (1989 December). Management turnover and financial distress., Journal of Financial Economics 25(2),211-262. and Kaplan (1994b)Kaplan, S. N. (1994b). Top executives, turnover and firm performance in Germany. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(1),142-159., who find that most companies turnover executives when they are in financial difficulties or bankruptcy. In contrast, the age of executives positively influences efficiency, rejecting Hypothesis 5. This result agrees with studies of Jensen and Murphy (1990)Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264. suggesting that the risk of dismissal is more pronounced for younger CEOs. The longer an executive is at a company, the greater the possibility of creating ties, becoming entrenched in the job, and earning incentives. In the analysis using the algorithm from Simar and Wilson (2007)Simar, L., & Wilson, P. W. (2007). Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-parametric models of production processes. J Econometrics, 136(1),31-64., this variable was negative and significant, corroborating those authors.

In line with this theory, the number of executives on the board relative to total number of directors is negatively correlated with efficiency, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 6. This result is in line with Jensen (1993)Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems., Journal of Finance 48(3),831-880., Goyal and Park (2002)Goyal, V. K., & Park, C. W. (2002). Board leadership structure and CEO turnover., Journal of Corporate Finance 8(1),49-66. and Bebchuk and Fried (2003)Bebchuk, L. A., & Fried, J. M. (2003). Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3),71-92., who explain that executives' influence on their own pay, hiring, and firing, among others, can generate substantial costs for shareholders that can distort incentives and hurt corporate performance. Confirming previous results, a CEO simultaneously serving as chairman of the board of directors further negatively influences company efficiency.

In the companies analyzed, the average number of years of CEO tenure negatively impacts efficiency, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 7. This result is consistent with studies by Goyal and Park (2002)Goyal, V. K., & Park, C. W. (2002). Board leadership structure and CEO turnover., Journal of Corporate Finance 8(1),49-66., which show a negative effect of tenure because a long tenure may mean that the CEO has established a power base. The combined analyses do not corroborate this result. The number of top executives negatively affects efficiency, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 8. This result is in line with Chen et al. (2008)Chen, Q., Goldstein, I., & Jiang, W. (2008 December). Directors' ownership in the U.S. mutual fund industry., Journal of Finance 63(6),2629-2677., who claim that a large number of executives also generates a greater monitoring effort because the greater the number of executives, the greater the oversight by directors.

Analyzing the issues related to monitoring, the number of independent directors compared to the total number of directors had a positive relationship with efficiency, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 9 but rejecting Hypothesis 9A. This result is consistent with Faleye et al. (2011)Faleye, O., Hoitash, R., & Hoitash, U. (2011). The costs of intense board monitoring., Journal of Financial Economics 101(1),160-181., who state that independent directors are seen as valuable monitors and that their involvement with the board is usually related to improvements in the company's accounting system and greater shareholder protection.

In the case of chairman turnover, this variable positively influences efficiency in virtually all the results, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 10 and rejecting Hypothesis 10A. This result is consistent with Agrawal et al. (1999)Agrawal, A.,Jaffe, J. F., & Karpoff, J. M. (1999). Management turnover and governance changes following the revelation of fraud. Journal of Law and Economics, 42(1),309-342., who show that fraud scandals can create incentives to change the board of directors for the purpose of increasing company performance through increased monitoring and hiring of directors with better reputations.

In the companies analyzed, the number of directors negatively influences efficiency, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 11. This result is consistent with Jensen (1993)Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems., Journal of Finance 48(3),831-880. and Nanka-Bruce (2009)Nanka-Bruce, D. (2009 October). The impact of large shareholdings and board structure on efficiency. Working-Paper, Universidade Autônoma de Barcelona., who state that having a small board of directors can help increase company performance. In terms of length of service, when taken separately, this variable negatively affects efficiency, but in the combined analysis, the influence is positive, partially rejecting Hypothesis 12. The results of the combined analysis corroborate the argument of Faleye et al. (2011)Faleye, O., Hoitash, R., & Hoitash, U. (2011). The costs of intense board monitoring., Journal of Financial Economics 101(1),160-181., who state that knowledge and professional experience make directors betterable to make the most correct strategic choice out of a set of possibilities because they have more years of service and because they generate greater confidence on the part of CEOs. Finally, in linewith the previous analysis, the age of the directors also positively influences efficiency, thereby not rejecting Hypothesis 13. This analysis is consistent with the study by Adams (2009)Adams, R. B. (2009). Asking directors about their dual roles. Working Paper, University of Queensland., who argues that younger directors tend to have less influence on the board, interact less with CEOs and, consequently, hinder information exchange between the parties, thus affecting efficiency.

Many of the hypotheses were confirmed, thus showing the particular conditions of corporate finance in Brazil with respect to corporate governance. The immaturity of the Brazilian capital market, identified by Aldrighi and Mazzer (2007)Aldrighi, D. M., & Mazzer, R. (2007 abril/junho). Evidências sobre as estruturas de propriedade de capital e de voto das empresas de capital aberto no Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Economia, 61(2),129-152., is perceived in various analyses, highlighting that the history of the Brazilian corporate system is one of the factors limiting the efficiency of companies. The prevailing conditions are as follows: (i) high ownership-management overlap; (ii) boards with low effectiveness; (iii) in family groups, the poor definitions of the roles of stockholders, boards and management; (iv) the lack of clarity about the cost-benefit relationship of good governance; (v) inefficiency of the boards of directors and (vi) evidence of conflicts of interest, diminished by explicit and implicit incentives. In the same context, Ferreira (2012)Ferreira, R. do N. (2012). Governança corporativa e desempenho: uma análise emempresas brasileiras de capital aberto. Tese de doutorado, Universidade Federal de Lavras, Lavras, Minas Gerais, Brasil. , by testing whether companies listed on the corporate governance segment are more efficient than companies listed on the traditional market, finds no evidence to corroborate that statement. Macedo and Corrar (2012)Macedo, M. A. D. S., & Corrar, L. J. (2012 janeiro/abril). Análise comparativa do desempenho contábil-financeiro de empresas com boas práticas de governança corporativa no Brasil. Revista Contabilidade e Controladoria - RC & C, 4(1),42-61. find superior performance for companies in the electricity distribution sector in Brazil only in 2005 and do not find superior performance for companies with better corporate governance practices in subsequent years.

Studies in other countries have also analyzed the influence of corporate governance on technical efficiency but have found a positive relationship between these variables. Luo and Yao (2010)Luo, D., & Yao, S. (2010).World financial crisis and the rise of Chinese commercial banks: an efficiency analysis using DEA. Applied Financial Economics, 20(19),1515-1530. have found that Chinese banks, seeking to increase governance and efficiency levels, significantly increased their efficiency even after a crisis due to diversification of ownership structure. Zheka (2005)Zheka, V. (2005).Corporate governance, ownership structure and corporate efficiency: the case of Ukraine., Managerial and Decision Economics 26(7),451-460. and Zelenyuk and Zheka (2006)Zelenyuk, V., & Zheka, V. (2006). Corporate governance and firm's efficiency: the case of a transitional country, Ukraine. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 25(1-2),143-157. also have found a positive impact of the quality of corporate governance on the efficiency of Ukrainian companies. Delmas and Tokat (2005)Delmas, M., & Tokat, Y. (2005). Deregulation, governance structures, and efficiency: the US electric utility sector. Strategic Management Journal, 26(5),441-460. have found that the market deregulation process has a negative effect on theproduction efficiency of U.S. electric companies but that some types of governance structures can adapt to the uncertainty of regulation by using different mechanisms. To investigate the strengths and weaknesses of the German corporate governance system, in which banks and insurance companies predominate as major shareholders and labor unions have board representation, Frick e Lehmann (2005)Frick, B., & Lehmann, E. (2005). Corporate governance in Germany: ownership, codetermination and firm performance in a stakeholder economy. In H. Gospel & A. Pendleton. Corporate governance and labour management: an international comparison. (pp. 122-147). Oxford: Oxford University Press. have identified that this system can benefit governance processes and increase company performance. Along the same lines, Lehmann, Warning, and Weigand (2004)Lehmann, E. R. I. K. ,Warning, S., & Weigand, J. (2004).Governance structures, multidimensional efficiency and firm profitability. Journal of Management and Governance, 8(3),279-304. have found that the performance of German companies makes a significant contribution to explaining differences in profitability among companies. Seeking to analyze the relationship between corporate governance and efficiency in Italian manufacturing companies, Destefanis and Sena (2007)Destefanis, S., & Sena, V. (2007). Patterns of corporate governance and technical efficiency in italian manufacturing., Managerial and Decision Economics 28(1),27-40. have identified a positive impact on the ownership structure of the largest shareholders.

This study has some limitations: (i) the DEA works with a measure of relative efficiency, which may distort the analysis, but the issue of truncated variables was resolved by bias correction using the algorithm proposed by Simar and Wilson (2007)Simar, L., & Wilson, P. W. (2007). Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-parametric models of production processes. J Econometrics, 136(1),31-64., whose results are qualitatively similar; (ii) the relationship among the variables in the model can be endogenous; (iii) the sample obtained for calculating the aspects of governance is very small; and (iv) some results presented in Regressions 8 of Tables 2 and 3 were not in line with the other results due to possible endogeneity of the governance variables, which may generate distortions in the study.

APPENDIX

APPENDIX A
FORMULAS USED IN THE STUDY
  • *
    Article presented at the IBGC (Special Academic Forum), São Paulo, Brazil, 2013.

Referências

  • Adams, R. B. (2009). Asking directors about their dual roles Working Paper, University of Queensland.
  • Adams, R. B., & Ferreira, D. (2007 February). A theory of friendly boards. Journal of Finance, 62(1),217-250.
  • Agrawal, A.,Jaffe, J. F., & Karpoff, J. M. (1999). Management turnover and governance changes following the revelation of fraud. Journal of Law and Economics, 42(1),309-342.
  • Aldrighi, D. M., & Mazzer, R. (2007 abril/junho). Evidências sobre as estruturas de propriedade de capital e de voto das empresas de capital aberto no Brasil. Revista Brasileira de Economia, 61(2),129-152.
  • Almeida, H., Campello, M., & Galvão, A. F. (2010 September). Measurement errors in investment equations. Review of Financial Studies, 23(9),3279-3328.
  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991 April). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Review of Economic Studies, 58(2),277-297.
  • Arthaud-Day, M. L., Certo, S. T., Dalton, C. M., & Dalton, D. R. (2006). A changing of the guard: executive and director turnover following corporate financial restatements. Academy of Management Journal, 49(6),1119-1136.
  • Babenko, I. (2009 February). Share repurchases and pay-performance sensitivity of employee compensation contracts., Journal of Finance 64(1),117-151.
  • Baker, G. P., Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1988 July). Compensation and incentives: practice vs. theory., Journal of Finance 43(3),593-616.
  • Beasley, M. S. (1996 October). An empirical analysis of the relation between the board of director composition and financial statement fraud. Accounting Review, 71(4),443-465.
  • Bebchuk, L. A., & Fried, J. M. (2003). Executive compensation as an agency problem. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 17(3),71-92.
  • Belkaoui, A., & Pavlik, E. (1992 August). The effects of ownership structure and diversification strategy on performance. Managerial and Decision Economics, 13(4),343-352.
  • Bennett, M. J. (2010). Does ownership structure affect corporate performance? Evidence from the market for asset sales. The IUP Journal of Corporate Governance, 9(1-2),57-98.
  • Bergstresser, D., & Philippon, T. (2006 June). CEO incentives and earnings management. Journal of Financial Economics, 80(3),511-529.
  • Berle, A. , JR. , & Means, G. (1932). The modern corporation and private property Chicago: Commerce Clearing House.
  • Bertrand, M., & Mullainathan, S. (2001 August). Are CEOs rewarded for luck? The ones without principals are. Quarterly Journal of Economics,116(3),901-932.
  • Boubakri, N., & Cosset, J. C. (1998 June). The financial and operating performance of newly privatized firms: evidence from developing countries. Journal of Finance, 53(3),1081-1110.
  • Boyer, M. M., & Ortiz-Molina, H (2008 May). Career concerns of top executives, managerial ownership and CEO succession. Corporate Governance: An International Review,16(3),178-193.
  • Brick, I. E., & Chidambaran, N. K. (2010 September). Board meetings, committee structure, and firm value. Journal of Corporate Finance, 16(4),533-553.
  • Bulan, L., Sanyal, P., & Yan, Z. (2010 July/August). A few bad apples: an analysis of CEO performance pay and firm productivity. Journal of Economics and Business, 62(4),273-306.
  • Chen, Q., Goldstein, I., & Jiang, W. (2008 December). Directors' ownership in the U.S. mutual fund industry., Journal of Finance 63(6),2629-2677.
  • Chung, K. H., & Pruitt, S. W. (1994). A simple approximation of Tobin's Q. Financial Management, 23(3),70-74.
  • Cohen, L., Frazzini, A., & Malloy, C. (2012 June). Hiring cheerleaders: board appointments of "independent" directors. Management Science, 58(6),1039-1058.
  • Cooper, W.W., Seiford, L. M., & Zhu, J. (2004). Handbook on data envelopment analysis Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers.
  • Delmas, M., & Tokat, Y. (2005). Deregulation, governance structures, and efficiency: the US electric utility sector. Strategic Management Journal, 26(5),441-460.
  • Destefanis, S., & Sena, V. (2007). Patterns of corporate governance and technical efficiency in italian manufacturing., Managerial and Decision Economics 28(1),27-40.
  • Dickins, D., & Houmes, R. (2009). Revisiting the relationship between insider ownership and performance. Journal of Business & Economic Studies, 15(2),32-43.
  • Fahlenbrach, R., & Stulz, R. M. (2009). Managerial ownership dynamics and firm value. Journal of Financial Economics, 92(3),342-361.
  • Faleye, O., Hoitash, R., & Hoitash, U. (2011). The costs of intense board monitoring., Journal of Financial Economics 101(1),160-181.
  • Ferreira, R. do N. (2012). Governança corporativa e desempenho: uma análise emempresas brasileiras de capital aberto Tese de doutorado, Universidade Federal de Lavras, Lavras, Minas Gerais, Brasil.
  • Florackis, C., Kostakis, A., & Ozkan, A. (2009 December). Managerial ownership and performance. Journal of Business Research, 62(12),1350-1357.
  • Franks, J., & Mayer, C. (2001). Ownership e control in German corporations. The, Review of Financial Studies 14(4),943-977.
  • Frick, B., & Lehmann, E. (2005). Corporate governance in Germany: ownership, codetermination and firm performance in a stakeholder economy. In H. Gospel & A. Pendleton. Corporate governance and labour management: an international comparison (pp. 122-147). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Frydman, R., Gray, C., Hessel, M., & Rapaczynski, A. (1999 November). When does privatization work? The impact of private ownership on corporate performance in the transition economies. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(4),1153-1191.
  • Funchal, J. A., & Terra, P. R. S. (2006). Remuneração de executivos, desempenho econômico e governança corporativa: um estudo empírico em empresas latino-americanas. Anais do Encontro Associação Nacional de Pesquisa e Pós-graduação em Administração, Salvador, BA, Brasil, 30.
  • Ghosh, A., & Ruland, W. (1998 April). Managerial ownership, the method of paymentfor acquisitions, and executive job retention., Journal of Finance 53(2),785-798.
  • Ghosh, S. (2007). Bank Monitoring, managerial ownership and Tobin's Q: an empirical analysis for India., Managerial and Decision Economics 28(2),129-143.
  • Gilson, S. C. (1989 December). Management turnover and financial distress., Journal of Financial Economics 25(2),211-262.
  • Gilson, S. C. (1990 October). Bankruptcy, boards, banks and blockholders: evidence on changes in corporate ownership and control when firms default., Journal of Financial Economics 27(2),355-388.
  • Goyal, V. K., & Park, C. W. (2002). Board leadership structure and CEO turnover., Journal of Corporate Finance 8(1),49-66.
  • Guedri, Z., & Hollandts, X. (2008 September). Beyond dichotomy: the curvilinear impact ofemployee ownership on firm performance. Journal of Corporate Governance, 16(5),460-474.
  • Hall, B. J., & Liebman, J. B. (1998 August). Are CEOs really paid like bureaucrats?, Quarterly Journal of Economics 113(3),653-691.
  • Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50(4),1029-1054.
  • Hitt, M. A., & Ireland, R. D. (1986). Relationships among corporate level distinctive competencies, diversification strategy, corporate structure and performance. Journal of Management Studies, 23(4),401-416.
  • Hu, Y., & Izumida, S. (2008 July). Ownership concentration and corporate performance: a causal analysis with Japanese panel data. Corporate Governance, 16(4),342-358.
  • Jensen, M. C. (1993). The modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems., Journal of Finance 48(3),831-880.
  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure., Journal of Financial Economics 3(4),305-360.
  • Jensen, M. C., & Murphy, K. J. (1990 April). Performance pay and top-management incentives. The Journal of Political Economy, 98(2),225-264.
  • Jensen, M. C., & Warner, J. B. (1988). The distribution of power among corporate managers, shareholders and directors., Journal of Financial 'Economics 20(1),3-24.
  • Kaplan, S. N. (1994a). Top executive rewards and firm performance: a comparison of Japan and United States. Journal of Political Economy, 102(3),510-546.
  • Kaplan, S. N. (1994b). Top executives, turnover and firm performance in Germany. The Journal of Law, Economics & Organization, 10(1),142-159.
  • Laeven, L., & Levine, R. (2008). Complex ownership structures and corporate valuations., Review of Financial Studies 21(2),579-604.
  • Lehmann, E. R. I. K. ,Warning, S., & Weigand, J. (2004).Governance structures, multidimensional efficiency and firm profitability. Journal of Management and Governance, 8(3),279-304.
  • Luo, D., & Yao, S. (2010).World financial crisis and the rise of Chinese commercial banks: an efficiency analysis using DEA. Applied Financial Economics, 20(19),1515-1530.
  • Macedo, M. A. D. S., & Corrar, L. J. (2012 janeiro/abril). Análise comparativa do desempenho contábil-financeiro de empresas com boas práticas de governança corporativa no Brasil. Revista Contabilidade e Controladoria - RC & C, 4(1),42-61.
  • Megginson, W. L., Nash, R. C., & Randenborgh, M. V. (1994 June). The financial and operating performance of newly privatized firms: an international empirical analysis. The, Journal of Finance 49(2),403-452.
  • Nanka-Bruce, D. (2009 October). The impact of large shareholdings and board structure on efficiency Working-Paper, Universidade Autônoma de Barcelona.
  • Sargan, J. D. (1958 July). The estimation of economic relationships using instrumental variables., Econometrica 26(3),393-415.
  • Security Exchange Comission. SEC. (1999-2009). Recuperado em 13 dezembro, 2011 de http://www.sec.org
    » http://www.sec.org
  • Sheu, H. J., & Yang, C. Y. (2005 July/August). Insider ownership and firm performance in Taiwan's electronics industry: a technical efficiency perspective., Managerial and Decision Economics 26(5),307-318.
  • Simar, L., & Wilson, P. W. (2007). Estimation and inference in two-stage, semi-parametric models of production processes. J Econometrics, 136(1),31-64.
  • Slovin, M. B., & Sushka, M. E. (1993 September). Ownership concentration, corporatecontrol activity, and firm value: evidence from the death of inside blockholders., Journal of Finance 48(4),1293-1321.
  • Souza, M. O., Souza, G. S., & Staub, R. B. (2009 maio/agosto). Influência das variáveis contextuais em medidas não-paramétricas de eficiência: uma aplicação com métodos de reamostragem. Pesquisa Operacional, 29(2),289-302.
  • Tirole, J. (2006). The theory of corporate finance Princeton: Princeton University Press.
  • Weisbach, M. S. (1988). Outside directors and CEO turnover. Journal of Financial Economics, 20(1),431-460.
  • Yermack, D. (1996). Higher market valuation of companies with a small board of directors., Journal of Financial Economics 40(2),185-211.
  • Zelenyuk, V., & Zheka, V. (2006). Corporate governance and firm's efficiency: the case of a transitional country, Ukraine. Journal of Productivity Analysis, 25(1-2),143-157.
  • Zheka, V. (2005).Corporate governance, ownership structure and corporate efficiency: the case of Ukraine., Managerial and Decision Economics 26(7),451-460.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    May-Aug 2014

History

  • Received
    01 Mar 2013
  • Reviewed
    11 Mar 2013
  • Accepted
    08 Apr 2014
Universidade de São Paulo, Faculdade de Economia, Administração e Contabilidade, Departamento de Contabilidade e Atuária Av. Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 908 - prédio 3 - sala 118, 05508 - 010 São Paulo - SP - Brasil, Tel.: (55 11) 2648-6320, Tel.: (55 11) 2648-6321, Fax: (55 11) 3813-0120 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: recont@usp.br