Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Growth regimes in central and peripheral countries: an econometric analysis, 1980-2018

Regimes de crescimento nos países centrais e periféricos: uma análise econométrica, 1980-2018

ABSTRACT

We explore structural differences in growth patterns and income distribution between central and peripheral countries. We provide dimensions that account for the structural limitations that dependent positions have in the peripheries and semi-peripheries. We conducted an analysis through different estimates of panel data models for 35 central and peripheral countries for the period 1980-2018. In particular, in addition to making the usual estimates of the components of aggregate demand, we include three variables that we consider representative of the dynamics that capital accumulation takes in the periphery: participation in global value chains, levels of foreignization of economies and labor productivity differentials.

KEYWORDS:
Growth regimes; income distribution; dependency; panel models

RESUMO

Exploramos diferenças estruturais nos padrões de crescimento e distribuição de renda entre países centrais e periféricos. Fornecemos dimensões que dão conta das limitações estruturais que as posições dependentes têm nas periferias e semiperiferias. Realizamos uma análise por meio de diferentes estimativas de modelos de dados em painel para 35 países centrais e periféricos para o período 1980-2018. Em particular, além de fazer as estimativas usuais dos componentes da demanda agregada, incluímos três variáveis que consideramos representativas da dinâmica que a acumulação de capital assume na periferia: a participação nas cadeias globais de valor, os níveis de estrangeirização das economias e a produtividade do trabalho diferenciais.

PALAVRAS-CHAVE:
Regimes de crescimento; distribuição de renda; dependência; modelos de painel

1. INTRODUCTION

The debate on the relationship between growth regimes and distribution patterns is already part of a long tradition in heterodox economic thought. In central countries, the development of different heterodox schools has provided compelling explanations about the ways in which capital accumulation has developed within the framework of the Keynesian-Fordist regimes after the Second War.

As from the crisis of the post-war regimes, the field of studies on growth and income distribution has developed multiple interpretations on how the Fordist-Keynesian dynamic had collapsed. At that point, there had already been several interpretations on profit squeeze (Skott, 1989Skott, P. (1989). Effective demand, class struggle and cyclical growth, International Economic Review, 231-247; Thompson, 2018Thompson, S. (2018). Profit squeeze in the Duménil and Lévy model, Review of Radical Political Economics , vol. 50, no. 2, 297-316), productivity stagnation, wage over-indexation (Bowles and Boyer, 1990), dynamics of over-production/over-capital accumulation, among others (Marglin and Schor, 1991Marglin, S. A. and Schor, J. B. (1991). The golden age of capitalism: reinterpreting the postwar experience, Oxford University Press). Then, with the emergence of the neoliberal turn as a regressive form of resolution to the crisis of the seventies, the questions about growth-distribution models began to revolve around effects of productive dislocation, the flexibilization of labor market and financialization of national economies. The implications of trade and financial openness (Blecker, 2002Blecker, R. (2002). Distribution, demand and growth in neo-Kaleckian macro-models, Chapters, Advance Access published 2002, 2016Blecker, R. A. (2016). Wage-led versus profit-led demand regimes: the long and the short of it, Review of Keynesian Economics, vol. 4, no. 4, 373-390; Hein, 2014Hein, E. (2014). Distribution and growth after Keynes: A Post-Keynesian guide, Edward Elgar Publishing), the effects of household debt and of the financialization of productive and non-productive enterprises on growth patterns have been studied in detail in recent years (Hein, 2012Hein, E. (2012). Finance-dominated capitalism, re-distribution, household debt and financial fragility in a Kaleckian distribution and growth model, PSL Quarterly Review, vol. 65, no. 260, 11-51; Onaran, 2011Onaran, Ö. (2011). Globalisation, macroeconomic performance and distribution, A Modern Guide to Keynesian Macroeconomics and Economic Policies, 240; Stockhammer and Wildauer, 2016Stockhammer, E. and Wildauer, R. (2016). Debt-driven growth? Wealth, distribution and demand in OECD countries, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 40, no. 6, 1609-1634).

Although several works have analyzed theoretical and empirical links between growth and distribution, the studies referring to the peripheral countries have had limited development1 1 Some exceptions to highlight are Onaran et al. (2011) and Onaran and Galanis (2014). However, none of these works take into consideration the structural characteristics of peripheral countries, which we consider relevant in this article. (see, for example, Bizberg, 2018Bizberg, I. (2018) Varieties of capitalism, growth and redistribution in Asia and Latin America, Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, vol. 38, no. 2, 261-279). Peripheral countries have structural features that constraint their processes of social and economic reproduction, their short-term cyclical dynamics and, naturally, their links between long-term economic growth and income distribution (Diamand, 1972Diamand, M. (1972). La estructura productiva desequilibrada argentina y el tipo de cambio, Desarrollo económico, vol. 12, no. 45, 25-47; Prebisch, 1986Prebisch, R. (1986). El desarrollo económico de la América Latina y algunos de sus principales problemas, Desarrollo económico, 479-502). Nevertheless, the specific characteristics of these countries and their structural differences with capitalist centers have not attracted researchers in the field of growth and distribution.

In this article we examine the case of peripheral countries. Have they suffered the same consequences as central countries in terms of the relationship between growth and income distribution? And if there were any differences, which explanatory factors account for such differences? Throughout this article, we intend to study the dimensions inherent to the dependency that peripheral economies have on global capital and how they operate to produce differential results in the relationship between growth and income distribution. Taking into account debates on growth regimes at the national level and the implications of the globalization of trade and finance on wage-led and profit-led models, we provide a series of dimensions to account for the structural limitations that the dependent positions have on the peripheries and semi-peripheries. The dependent position of Latin American countries in the world economy causes limitations on growth regimes at the national level, which are manifested in the instability of these regimes and in the constant tendency towards the prevalence of profit-led models.

In order to conduct the study, we analyze different estimations derived from panel data models for 35 central and peripheral countries within the period 1980-2018. We carried out the usual estimations of the components of aggregate demand and of the most relevant variables that account for the financialization process. In addition, we included three variables we consider to be representative of the dependent dynamic that capital accumulation acquires on the periphery: Participation in Global Value Chains, levels of foreignization2 2 This concept refers to the increasing weight of international capital in domestic economies. This Spanish concept does not possess an exact translation in English. of the economies and labor productivity differentials.

The article is structured as follows. In the second section, here is a deep analysis of the dimensions that account for the unequal position of periphery economies and the possible empirical approaches to this position. In the third section, there is presentation of the variables used for the classification of countries into central and peripheral and we construct an indicator of degree of dependency. In the fourth section, the main results of the estimations and central insights we have obtained on their basis are presented. Finally, in the fifth section we present some final thoughts and some unresolved points which will be addressed in future works.

2. UNEQUAL POSITIONS IN THE GLOBAL ORDER AND STRUCTURAL CONDITIONS OF THE PERIPHERY

Capitalist world as an un-equalizing system has gone through diverse stages which have been conditioned by the actions of different hegemonic centers that were able to direct the global economic order (Wallerstein, 1974Wallerstein, I. (1974). The rise and future demise of the world capitalist system: Concepts for comparative analysis, Comparative studies in society and history, vol. 16, no. 4, 387-415). From this perspective, the general orientation of the accumulation processes at the global level was centered in the Dutch century - linked to commerce -, the English century - related to the development of industrial capitalism -, the American century - after the Second World War - and, probably, the re-emergence of Asia as a new hegemonic center (Arrighi, 1994Arrighi, G. (1994). The long twentieth century: Money, power, and the origins of our times, verso.).

Going in depth into this interpretation helps us highlight an evident element to think about the modes of development at the national level and, particularly, their founding growth regimes. According to these perspectives, it becomes evident that the southern countries of the world - except for few exceptions - have remained in subordinated positions in the global order and have had less possibilities of national autonomous development (Amin, 1988Amin, S. (1988) . L’Accumulation à l’échelle mondiale: préface à la nouvelle édition.).

In particular, the subordinated insertion of Latin American economies in the dynamic of the capitalist centers of the world have been one of the most interesting problems for regional social sciences (Rosenmann, 2008Rosenmann, M. R. (2008). Pensar América Latina: el desarrollo de la sociología latinoamericana, Clacso). Since the 1950s, within the framework of development theory, structuralist approaches started to multiply in an attempt to question the pillars of the modernization theory developed by (Rostow, 1960Rostow, W. W. (1960). The stages of growth: A non-communist manifesto, Cambridge University Press) in the United States. According to the modernization approach, all peripheral countries - except for the communist ones - should go through a series of stages in their socioeconomic development. This would lead them to reach the social welfare levels inherent to the capitalist centers of the world. Unlike the modernization perspective, the structuralist approach of the Economic Commission for Latin America (ECLA) introduced differentiating elements between “developed” and “developing” countries, which would be then used in a more radical sense by the dependence theory (Pinto, 1973Pinto, A. (1973). Heterogeneidad estructural y modelo de desarrollo reciente de la América Latina, CEPAL).

By 1960, with the aim of solving what was interpreted as the problems of structuralist analysis by ECLA, the dependence theory emerged From the point of view of dependency theoreticians, the insertion of the Latin American economies in the global cycle of capital has been subordinated, until the first half of the 20th century, to the role of producing goods for consumption by the wage earners of the central countries (Marini, 1972Marini, R. M. (1972). Dialéctica de la dependencia: la economía exportadora, Sociedad y desarrollo, vol. 1, 35-52). From this perspective, since their initial years, peripheral countries have been part of the global capital accumulation, giving rise to certain economic and social structures historically dependent and unequal (Cueva, 1998Cueva, A. (1998). El desarrollo del capitalismo en América Latina: ensayo de interpretación histórica, Siglo XXI). The peripheral industrialization process that followed in Latin America and most of the countries of the Global South - characterized by the special features of the post-war period and coordinated afterwards with the globalization and transnationalization of capital - modified in an outstanding manner the role of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in these regions. Consequently, it caused the configuration of new productive models which were not able to break the dependent and unequal character of the global dynamic (Marini, 2007Marini, R. M. (2007). Proceso y tendencias de la globalización capitalista y otros textos (Antología), Prometeo Libros Editorial).

After the post-war period, and mainly since the 1960s and 1970s, the internationalization of capital was considered to be another consolidation element in the dependency of peripheral regions. Transnational enterprises - mainly from Europe and the U.S. - started to operate in Latin American, Asian and African countries as a mechanism of value transfer to the central countries (Cardoso and Faletto, 1979Cardoso, F. H. and Faletto, E. (1979). Dependency and development in Latin America (Dependencia y desarrollo en América Latina, engl.), Univ of California Press).

Dependency theoreticians have provided elements to account for the historical characteristics of peripheral capitalism. This approach brought to light that, in southern economies, the cycle of capital accumulation has been overdetermined by the participation of foreign capital in the cycle of local capital and by the way in which the local economy has been connected with it in the world economy (Marini, 2007Marini, R. M. (2007). Proceso y tendencias de la globalización capitalista y otros textos (Antología), Prometeo Libros Editorial). In the first place, direct or indirect investments of foreign capital act as one of the most important elements in gross capital formation in the peripheries, a factor that is not determinant in the center. Likewise, within the framework of late industrialization processes, Latin American countries tend to advance in the production of consumer goods, lacking a dynamic sector of capital goods, which involves a strong import dependency at this stage of the cycle (Pinto, 1973Pinto, A. (1973). Heterogeneidad estructural y modelo de desarrollo reciente de la América Latina, CEPAL). These characteristics, then, have an impact on the productive dynamics of southern countries: productivity differentials between foreign and local enterprises involve the displacement of small and medium-sized enterprises, which cause an accelerated concentration. As its counterpart, functional income inequality is increased by less competitive capitals as a way to “compensate” for low productivity levels. Finally, the form of production in the periphery determines a dual final demand pattern, luxury goods and necessary goods, in which popular consumption is a secondary element for the realization of value, since the export of goods and services represents a central component to boost growth, which tends to strengthen the profit-led dynamics of peripheral economies.

These elements considered by the dependency theory became more evident after the “neoliberal turn” of the sixties (Harvey, 2007Harvey, D. (2007). Breve historia del neoliberalismo, Ediciones Akal). In peripheral economies, the new strategy of the internationalization of capital adopted the form of growing foreignization, by breaking the import substitution process (Frieden, 2007Frieden, J. A. (2007). Global capitalism: Its fall and rise in the twentieth century, WW Norton & Company). From our perspective, the structural conditions imposed during the neoliberal phase of capitalism produced at least three concrete results that strengthened the dependency dynamics of peripheral countries. First, the transnationalization of capital involved a constant process of concentration and centralization of most of the productive, financial and commercial activities (Gaggero et al., 2014Gaggero, A., Schorr, M., and Wainer, A. (2014). Restricción eterna: el poder económico durante el kirchnerismo, Futuro Anterior; Yang, 2016Yang, C. (2016). Relocating labour-intensive manufacturing firms from China to Southeast Asia: a preliminary investigation, Bandung, vol. 3, no. 1, 1-13). This process produced an increasing division between labor productivity of big and small and medium-size enterprises (López and Barrera Insua, 2019López, E. and Barrera Insua, F. (2019). The Specific Conditions of the Valorization of Capital in a Dependent Nation: The Case of Argentina (2002-2014), Review of Radical Political Economics, vol. 51, no. 1, 75-94); and, consequently, there was a relative growth in the profits of big enterprises (López and Barrera Insua, 2018Lopez, E. and Barrera Insua, F. (2018). The deep inheritance of dependency. Extraordinary profits and capitalist competition in Argentina (2002-2015), América Latina Hoy-Revista de Ciencias Sociales, vol. 80, 119-141). Second, within sectoral analysis, it can be observed that transnational and concentrated capitals are oriented towards those activities that have extraordinary profitability conditions in the Global South: this is, agricultural production, extractive activities and manufacturing sectors that produce wage-goods (particularly, agro-food) (López and Barrera Insua, 2018Lopez, E. and Barrera Insua, F. (2018). The deep inheritance of dependency. Extraordinary profits and capitalist competition in Argentina (2002-2015), América Latina Hoy-Revista de Ciencias Sociales, vol. 80, 119-141). These are the activities that have high productivity and can be inserted into the world in a competitive way (Diamand, 1972Diamand, M. (1972). La estructura productiva desequilibrada argentina y el tipo de cambio, Desarrollo económico, vol. 12, no. 45, 25-47). Considering Global Value Chains (GVC), this has a main implication, since it allows us to formulate the hypothesis - that we will later confirm - that southern countries are at the end of such chains: they are either at the end of primary production (upstream) or they are assemblers and exporters with high proportions of foreign components (downstream) (Milberg and Winkler, 2013Milberg, W. & Winkler, D. (2013). Outsourcing Economics. Global Value Chains in Capitalist Development, Cambridge University Press.). Thus, a perspective such as the one developed by Fernández and Trevignani, (2015Fernández, V. R. and Trevignani, M. F. (2015). Cadeias Globais de Valor e Desenvolvimento: Perspectivas Críticas do Sul Global, Dados, vol. 58, no. 2, 499-536) facilitates thinking about a hierarchic coordination between - mainly business - actors of the center and the periphery.

For these reasons, in contrast with the usual classification of countries based on income levels, we consider it preferable to make a classification between central and peripheral countries, since it can account for those unequal positions in the world system. This point will be developed in the next section.

3. STRUCTURAL WEIGHT OF DEPENDENT CONDITIONS

We have selected three key variables which we consider to be indicators of the dominant/subordinate positions of the different countries: a) foreignization of economies; b) an indicator of the position in Global Value Chains (GVC); c) Relative Unit Labor Costs (RULC). These indicators respond to the characterization of the situation of dependency in which the countries of the global south find themselves.

First, we have included the levels of foreignization of economies by calculating the quotient between the Stock of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and the Total Capital Stock. As López and Barrera Insua (2018Lopez, E. and Barrera Insua, F. (2018). The deep inheritance of dependency. Extraordinary profits and capitalist competition in Argentina (2002-2015), América Latina Hoy-Revista de Ciencias Sociales, vol. 80, 119-141) pointed out, it can be expected that the levels of foreignization and its qualitative effects are more significant in the peripheries than in the center as we will show later on. The levels of foreignization are similar between countries although the qualitative differences are important. We will mention two dimensions: a) while companies that operate in the center have their activity oriented to value realization in the internal markets, the strategy of transnational companies in the peripheral economies is value realization on export markets; b) as a result of the productive delocalization process, companies from the center control productive processes in different parts of the world.

Second, we included the relation between the domestic value added in agricultural and manufacturing exports as an indicator of the position in the Global Value Chains (GVCs). This indicator enables us to account for the role that dependent economies have in the global dynamic of accumulation. In particular, peripheral economies tend to be at the end of these positions: either as exporters of primary goods or as assemblers of final goods led by the centers.

Thus, considering this variable, we find significant explanations about the role of the productive specialization that a great part of the countries of the Global South have in the current process of economic globalization. In any case, Latin American countries own a share of agricultural goods above the average compared to central countries (see Figure 1)3 3 Naturally, by comparing the peripheries, we find that in the countries of Asia the contribution of manufacturing exports in value added is predominant as opposed to Latin American countries. In any case, the key point here is that while most of the central countries have balanced export contributions to the value of both branches, the peripheral and semi-peripheral countries have an imbalance due to the international division of labor that has not been substantially modified, with the exception of China. .

Figure 1
Relationship between domestic value added in exports of agricultural goods and domestic value added in manufacturing exports, 2018, in percentages

Third, we included the Relative Unit Labor Costs (RULC), calculated as the relation between average wage and average labor productivity of each country with respect to such relation for the United States. We expect that those countries with high levels of ULC (near to or higher than the U.S.) are central while those countries with lower levels of ULC are among the peripheral countries.

We consider the export strategy to be different between the centers and the peripheries. While in the center the exporting companies seek to increase productivity and technology to achieve higher levels of competition, in the periphery the search for low wage costs to obtain greater international competitiveness continues to be the guideline. This leads peripheral and semi-peripheral countries to be at the end of value chains, while central countries are located in intermediate positions.

3.1 Synthetic Indicator of Dependency

Since we stood out these three variables for the classification of our data panel, we have to consider the possibility that some of the countries of the Global South do not present the expected results in some of these indicators. This should be particularly expected for the BRICS (China, India, Brazil, Russia and South Africa) and, maybe, for some economies of Southeast Asia. The development of their productive forces enables their conception more as semi-peripheral than as merely peripheral (Yoo, 1998), even if they are subordinated in the global order. However, we considered them within the non-central countries because, as we will see in the results of our estimations, they present differential dynamics regarding the growth and distribution processes of the centers, and they produce results qualitatively similar to the peripheral countries regarding the main variables of interest.

In order to achieve an integral perspective of the dependency process based on the mentioned variables, we constructed a Synthetic Indicator of Dependency (SID). This indicator includes the foreignization of the economy (EX) related to the degree of financialization (FG), the participation of primary goods exports in the value added and the relative unit labor costs (productivity-adjusted labor costs). All these variables are weighted by the participation of domestic GDP in the world GDP. Formally,

S I D i = φ i E X F G i + φ i E X P O i + φ i R U L C i - 1 (1)

The results for the different countries of the panel are summarized in the following map:

Figure 2
Synthetic dependency indicator for the different countries, 2018

Figure 2 shows that Latin America, Asia and Africa present a higher degree of dependency than countries such as the U.S., Canada and Western Europe.

4. AN EMPIRICAL APPROACH TO GROWTH MODELS AT A NATIONAL SCALE FOR CENTERS AND PERIPHERIES

The point of reference for the empirical analysis is the Bhaduri and Marglin (1990Bhaduri, A. and Marglin, S. (1990.) Unemployment and the real wage: the economic basis for contesting political ideologies, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 14, no. 4, 375-393) growth model to which we incorporate the effects of foreignization, relative unit labor costs and the position in GVCon the different components of the aggregate demand. We use a panel approach, as many similar studies do. For instance, Hartwig (2014Hartwig, J. (2014). Testing the Bhaduri-Marglin model with OECD panel data, International Review of Applied Economics, vol. 28, no. 4, 419-435) used a panel of 31 OECD countries for the period 1970-2011 and found a wage led demand regime. Kiefer and Rada (2015Kiefer, D. and Rada, C. 2015. Profit maximising goes global: the race to the bottom, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 39, no. 5, 1333-1350.) estimate demand and distribution equations for a panel of OECD countries together with control variables that affect income distribution concluding that demand is led by profits. Stockhammer and Wildauer (2016Stockhammer, E. and Wildauer, R. (2016). Debt-driven growth? Wealth, distribution and demand in OECD countries, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 40, no. 6, 1609-1634) incorporate private debt and stock prices in a Badhuri-Marglin model by means of an econometric analysis based on a sample of 18 OECD economies for the period 1980-2013. They find evidence in favor of a wage-led demand regime. Finally, de Oliveira and Souza (2021De Oliveira G and Sousa E (2021) Wage-led and profit-led growth regimes: a panel data approach, Review of Keynesian Economics vol. 9 Issue 3, p394-412.) estimate a panel-data model of the capital stock and the rate of capacity utilization for 61 countries over the period 1995-2014. They found wage-led growth regimes for developed countries, while most developing countries exhibited a profit-led growth regime. In Latin American countries, the causality channel is mainly related to the international trade channel, while in other developing countries it is related to domestic investment function.

Most of these studies have been carried out for central economies, giving little consideration to the structural characteristics of peripheral economies. As we have seen in the previous section, we believe it is essential to take these dimensions into account.

4.1 Data and Estimation Strategy

Our dataset covers 35 central and peripheral economies for the period 1980-2018.

We classified countries into three different groups (center, periphery and semi-periphery) based on the SID described in the previous section. First, countries with an SID below the median were considered part of the center. Then, the periphery was formed by those countries with an SID above the median of the remaining subgroup and the semi-periphery by those with an SID below the median value4 4 The countries included in the empirical study are: Central: Australia, Austria, Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, England, United States. Semi-periphery: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, India, Malaysia, Mexico, South Korea, South Africa, Thailand. Periphery: Bolivia, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Honduras, Nicaragua, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, Venezuela. .

Variable’s definitions, data sources and unit of measurement for each one is provided in Table 1.

Table 1
Source and variables

As for the static panel estimators, the FD is preferable to the estimator that arises from the within groups transformation of panel data, because although both estimators allow for country fixed effects and are consistent when T grows relative to N (Rangel Jiménez, 2012), the FD estimator is more efficient in the context of non-stationary data.

Regarding dynamic panel data estimators, to address possible autocorrelation problems present in these specifications, we apply the Anderson and Hsiao (1982Anderson, T. W. and Hsiao, C. (1982). Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data, Journal of econometrics, vol. 18, no. 1, 47-82) (A&H) estimator, as well as restricted versions of the Arellano and Bond (1991Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations, The review of economic studies, vol. 58, no. 2, 277-297) one-step estimator. Concerning the difference estimators of Arellano and Bond (1991Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations, The review of economic studies, vol. 58, no. 2, 277-297) and system GMM of Blundell and Bond (1998), the set of tools needed to address the correlation of the lagged dependent variable with the error term exhibits a quadratic increase in T and, therefore, these methods become infeasible when T grows relative to N (Nickell, 1981). This is the case of dataset used in this article. Given these characteristics of the data set, the one-step estimator of Arellano and Bond (1991Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations, The review of economic studies, vol. 58, no. 2, 277-297) will be more efficient and produce less bias than the system GMM estimator. Finally, as Baltagi (2013) has presented, the non-stationarity of the data set is also a reason not to use the system GMM estimator, since it requires mean-stationary series in levels, which is not met in the worked data set.

We started the empirical contrast with an analysis of the stationarity properties of the series. For that purpose, we applied three panel data unit root tests: Im et al. (2003Im, K. S., Pesaran, M. H., and Shin, Y. (2003). Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels, Journal of econometrics , vol. 115, no. 1, 53-74), Fisher-ADF (Choi, 2001Choi, I. (2001). Unit root tests for panel data, Journal of international money and Finance, vol. 20, no. 2, 249-272) and Fisher-Phillips and Perron (Choi, 2001Choi, I. (2001). Unit root tests for panel data, Journal of international money and Finance, vol. 20, no. 2, 249-272). Results indicate that most of the series follow stationary stochastic processes I(0) in first difference; i.e., they are integrated of order one I(1) in levels (see Appendix Appendix Table 2 Results for consumption function Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnCt-1 0.761*** 0.743*** 0.777*** 0.716*** 0.790*** 0.656*** (0.059) (0.055) (0.060) (0.083) (0.054) (0.088) lnY 0.731*** 0.581*** 0.501*** 0.721*** 0.541*** 0.556** 0.844*** 0.601*** 0.599*** (0.016) (0.068) (0.059) (0.028) (0.063) (0.110) (0.019) (0.064) (0.098) lnWS 0.116** 0.132** 0.098* 0.171*** 0.193** 0.126* 0.086** 0.080** 0.076** (0.014) (0.042) (0.041) (0.032) (0.061) (0.063) (0.012) (0.037) (0.051) lnGF -0.017*** -0.036*** -0.015* -0.007** -0.021*** -0.016* -0.025*** -0.039** -0.053 (0.004) (0.007) (0.009) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) (0.036) lnDH 0.095** 0.017** 0.012 0.126*** 0.096** 0.091* 0.036 0.028 0.012 (0.091) (0.126) (0.031) (0.091) (0.032) (0.063) (0.096) (0.098) (0.089) lnEX 0.018** 0.014** 0.013* 0.009** 0.007** 0.016** -0.015** -0.011* -0.090 (0.008) (0.012) (0.016) (0.003) (0.004) (0.015) (0.006) (0.009) (0.072) Observations 1,360 1,360 1,360 741 741 741 619 619 619 R-squared 0.899 0.796 0.778 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.106 0.103 0.098 0.091 0.096 0.090 Hansen p-value 0.133 0.121 0.109 0.106 0.101 0.097 AR (2) p-value 0.496 0.493 0.401 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 3 Results for investment function Investment Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnIt-1 0.866*** 0.892*** 0.829*** 0.876*** 0.889*** 0.791* (0.023) (0.057) (0.036) (0.059) (0.062) (0.101) lnY 1.991*** 1.969*** 2.041*** 1.872*** 1.998*** 2.020*** 1.983*** 2.057*** 2.051** (0.176) (0.192) (0.116) (0.118) (0.148) (0.214) (0.101) (0.173) (0.142) lnWS -0.135*** -0.126** -0.150** -0.048** -0.073*** -0.041* -0.188*** -0.189** -0.192** (0.064) (0.032) (0.059) (0.016) (0.023) (0.015) (0.073) (0.041) (0.043) r -0.185** -0.123** -0.112* -0.308*** -0.213** -0.206* -0.086** -0.081* 0.077 (0.051) (0.059) (0.063) (0.098) (0.086) (0.079) (0.046) (0.039) (0.041) lnGF -0.216** -0.150** -0.132* -0.153*** -0.131*** -0.128 -0.231*** -0.193* -0.281* (0.051) (0.029) (0.026) (0.089) (0.016) (0.061) (0.071) (0.066) (0.142) lnEX -0.026** -0.013** -0.012* -0.006* -0.002 0.057 -0.133*** -0.101** 0.178* (0.016) (0.011) (0.012) (0.003) (0.004) (0.068) (0.013) (0.013) (0.136) Observations 1,301 1,301 1,301 703 703 703 598 598 598 R-squared 0.894 0.691 0.663 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.331 0.279 0.297 0.209 0.203 0.111 Hansen p-value 0.312 0.261 0.241 0.201 0.211 0.119 AR (2) p-value 0.626 0.412 0.351 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 4 Results for exports function Exports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnXt-1 0.929*** 0.916*** 0.842*** 0.831*** 0.928*** 0.890** (0.132) (0.101) (0.106) (0.116) (0.099) (0.114) lnY* 1.531*** 1.691*** 1.706*** 1.791*** 2.091*** 1.854** 1.571*** 2.003*** 1.321** (0.119) (0.142) (0.151) (0.115) (0.203) (0.239) (0.126) (0.187) (0.198) lnWS -0.058** -0.079*** -0.099 -0.033* -0.051* -0.076 -0.081** -0.092** -0.109 (0.019) (0.042) (0.051) (0.017) (0.029) (0.061) (0.041) (0.053) (0.106) lnRER -0.088** -0.121** -0.139** -0.131*** -0.199*** -0.131 -0.049** -0.029** -0.012 (0.026) (0.069) (0.096) (0.052) (0.066) (0.105) (0.028) (0.016) (0.011) lnGF -0.041** -0.052** 0.058* -0.016** -0.026** -0.015 -0.036** -0.038** -0.097 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) (0.011) (0.017) (0.013) (0.021) (0.016) (0.068) lnEX 0.029* -0.053 -0.028 0.009 0.006 -0.016 0.097** 0.099** 0.083 (0.018) (0.019) (0.016) (0.005) (0.005) (0.013) (0.039) (0.055) (0.067) lnRULC -0.098** -0.064* -0.100 -0.044* -0.036 -0.038 -0.088** 0.067** 0.059** (0.043) (0.033) (0.081) (0.036) (0.031) (0.027) (0.044) (0.026) (0.042) lnEXPO 0.285*** 0.193*** 0.096 0.186*** 0.171*** 0.169 0.316*** 0.221*** 0.249* (0.127) (0.109) (0.091) (0.117) (0.107) (0.128) (0.291) (0.106) (0.196) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.786 0.771 0.693 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.291 0.219 0.171 0.148 0.098 0.089 Hansen p-value 0.319 0.299 0.197 0.192 0.108 0.107 AR (2) p-value 0.172 0.140 0.136 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 5 Results for imports function Imports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnMt-1 0.696*** 0.687*** 0.519*** 0.521** 0.526*** 0.618** (0.129) (0.188) (0.138) (0.191) (0.103) (0.189) lnY 1.421*** 1.462*** 1.398** 1.283*** 1.276*** 1.142** 1.531*** 1.479*** 1.387** (0.123) (0.129) (0.201) (0.074) (0.101) (0.266) (0.144) (0.101) (0.222) lnWS 0.066** 0.083* 0.081 0.033** 0.049* 0.043 0.097** 0.099** 0.112* (0.045) (0.041) (0.059) (0.017) (0.027) (0.019) (0.031) (0.091) (0.109) lnRER 0.078*** 0.069** 0.083 0.091** 0.077** -0.070* 0.040*** 0.038* 0.051 (0.033) (0.066) (0.071) (0.032) (0.069) (0.063) (0.029) (0.028) (0.042) lnGF 0.139*** 0.083** 0.089 0.031** 0.017** 0.020 0.159*** 0.133* 0.126** (0.063) (0.051) (0.079) (0.012) (0.015) (0.019) (0.099) (0.118) (0.101) lnEX 0.215** 0.206** 0.212** 0.116* 0.103** 0.103 0.329** 0.317*** 0.323** (0.101) (0.104) (0.101) (0.071) (0.096) (0.077) (0.097) (0.081) (0.116) lnRULC 0.091* 0.076* 0.071 0.039* 0.051 0.069 0.088* 0.081* 0.096 (0.081) (0.043) (0.069) (0.031) (0.043) (0.067) (0.077) (0.069) (0.091) lnEXPO 0.326*** 0.314*** 0.269** 0.139*** 0.121** 0.136** 0.346*** 0.363*** 0.301** (0.106) (0.103) (0.128) (0.118) (0.102) (0.117) (0.109) (0.191) (0.116) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.823 0.813 0.745 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.099 0.086 0.073 0.058 0.061 0.042 Hansen p-value 0.088 0.073 0.068 0.070 0.065 0.059 AR (2) p-value 0.149 0.139 0.121 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 6 Marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in wage share on excess final demand Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery C 0.106 0.158 0.104 0.054 I -0.049 -0.016 -0.071 -0.102 X+M -0.039 -0.020 -0.057 -0.076 Y 0.018 0.122 -0.024 -0.123 Financialization 274% 352% 107% 121% Foreignization 8% 9% 6% 2% RULC 13% 26% 8% 12% VAag/VAind 10% 5% 24% 4% Notes: The calculations of the effects on the final demand are based on the FD estimators, averages 1980-2018. The elasticities were transformed to marginal effects using the participation in the GDP as a weight. The average financialization of the semi-periphery excludes China. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 7 Growth contributions Change 2010-2018 Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery Aggregate 1 ΔC 26% 14% 30% 52% 2 ΔI 27% 13% 5% 35% Δ(X-M) -29% -51% -13% -7% 3 ΔY 26% 17% 29% 45% Consumption 4 ΔC-βYΔY 7% 1% 6% 14% 5 βwsΔWS -0.2% 0.2% -0.5% -0.1% 6 βEXΔEX 0.9% 0.1% -1.6% -0.6% 7 βFΔF 3.7% 3.1% -0.2% -0.9% Investment 8 ΔI-βYΔY-βrΔr -25% -20% -52% -54% 9 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 10 βEXΔEX -1.3% 0.0% -14.1% -5.4% 11 βGFΔGF -4.3% -3.6% -2.2% -8.6% Expo-Imp 12 βY*ΔY*-βYΔY 2.9% 6.4% 0.2% 1.4% 13 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 14 βDCΔDC -13% 0% -29% -11% 15 βGFΔGF -3.6% -1.1% -1.9% -7.2% GDP 16 βwsΔWS 0.2% 0.1% 1.5% 0.2% 17 βDCΔDC -13.6% 0.3% -44.9% -17.3% 18 βFΔF -4.2% -1.6% -4.4% -16.7% Notes: The coefficients correspond to FD estimator in tables (2) to (5). βFΔF = βGFΔGF+βDHΔDH y βDCΔDC = βEXΔEX+βRULCΔRULC+βEXPOΔEXPO. Table 8 Descriptive statistics Variable N Mean SD Min Max Unit Y 1365 1005.99 2142.31 4.69 17856.48 Billions (USD) C 1365 581.19 1359.78 2.39 12388.55 Billions (USD) I 1365 282.62 791.74 0.67 12388.55 Billions (USD) X 1365 213.69 346.55 0.46 2626.65 Billions (USD) M 1365 209.77 374.07 1.26 3203.78 Billions (USD) Y* 1365 35190.46 16933.20 17379.22 82709.21 Billions (USD) WS 1365 0.57 0.09 0.31 0.76 %GDP r 1301 0.27 3.42 -0.98 93.94 % DH 1360 91.76 63.34 10.51 347.48 %GDP RER 1361 101.50 78.94 12.41 512.90 2010=100 GF 1365 2.66 3.91 0.16 33.06 %GDP EX 1365 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.86 % capital stock EXPO 1321 0.11 0.09 0.01 0.39 Ratio RULC 1363 0.13 0.12 0.02 1.13 According to USA Table 9 Unit root test Variable Im, Pesaran and Shin1 Fisher ADF2 Fisher Phillips and Perron3 >I(d) no trend trend no trend trend no trend trend Y 1.0000 0.6693 1.0000 0.3585 1.0000 0.9584 I(1) WS 0.7885 0.5955 0.4857 0.4858 0.6258 0.6125 I(1) Y* 0.6325 1.0000 0.8965 1.0000 0.9325 1.0000 I(1) C 1.0000 0.2854 1.0000 0.2587 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) I 1.0000 0.8172 0.9999 0.1125 1.0000 0.8752 I(1) X 0.9991 0.9658 0.9999 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) M 1.0000 0.2158 1.0000 0.1115 1.0000 0.1984 I(1) RER 0.0000 0.0021 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0761 I(0) r 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) RULC 0.9586 0.9589 0.9586 0.9548 0.9518 0.9651 I(1) EX 0.4586 0.9436 0.8651 0.9961 0.6351 0.9993 I(1) EXPO 0.5358 0.6151 0.6583 0.9932 0.8591 1.0000 I(1) GF 0.1412 0.1506 0.2731 0.9542 0.1452 0.6702 I(1) DH 0.3521 0.1358 0.5326 0.4891 0.6531 0.8641 I(1) ΔY 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔWS 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔY* 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔI 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRER 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Δr 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRULC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEXPO 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔGF 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔDH 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Notes": he tests are performed on the logarithmic transformation of the variables, except in the case of the real interest rate. 1. H0: all panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary. The table shows the p-value of the W-t-bar statistic. 2. H0: the panels contain unit roots; H1: at least one panel is stationary. The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). 3. H0: ll panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary.The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). Estimates run using STATA 15. , Table 9). We carried out the static panel first difference (FD) estimator and in relation to dynamic panel specifications, we applied the difference GMM estimator as proposed by Arellano and Bond (1991Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations, The review of economic studies, vol. 58, no. 2, 277-297) and the Anderson and Hsiao (1982Anderson, T. W. and Hsiao, C. (1982). Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data, Journal of econometrics, vol. 18, no. 1, 47-82) estimator (AH) to address potential problems of autocorrelation in dynamic specifications and to check robustness. In these last cases, the set of lags used as instruments to handle the correlation of the lagged dependent variable and the error term has been limited (Roodman, 2009Roodman, D. (2009). A note on the theme of too many instruments, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and statistics, vol. 71, no. 1, 135-158). Specifically, he number of lags of the independent variable for instrumenting lnC it-1 , lnI it-1 , lnX it-1 , lnM it-1 was restricted to two5 5 One issue to take into account is that there may be common shocks across countries and differential impacts of these shocks that are not discriminated in this model from those shocks specific to the countries. However, we consider that, given that the estimators we use control for autoregression adequately, this does not represent major problems for the specification strategy of the model. .

4.2 Results

Consumption

The consumption function has been estimated in the following way:

ln C i t = α ln C i t - 1 + β 1 ln Y i t + β 2 ln W S i t + ω F i t + γ D C + μ i + v i t (2)

Where F and DC are two vectors of variables that incorporate the dimensions of financialization and dependent conditions, respectively, and i are country fixed effects and vit is the residual term. The results of the estimations under different specifications are summarized in Table 2 (see Appendix Appendix Table 2 Results for consumption function Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnCt-1 0.761*** 0.743*** 0.777*** 0.716*** 0.790*** 0.656*** (0.059) (0.055) (0.060) (0.083) (0.054) (0.088) lnY 0.731*** 0.581*** 0.501*** 0.721*** 0.541*** 0.556** 0.844*** 0.601*** 0.599*** (0.016) (0.068) (0.059) (0.028) (0.063) (0.110) (0.019) (0.064) (0.098) lnWS 0.116** 0.132** 0.098* 0.171*** 0.193** 0.126* 0.086** 0.080** 0.076** (0.014) (0.042) (0.041) (0.032) (0.061) (0.063) (0.012) (0.037) (0.051) lnGF -0.017*** -0.036*** -0.015* -0.007** -0.021*** -0.016* -0.025*** -0.039** -0.053 (0.004) (0.007) (0.009) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) (0.036) lnDH 0.095** 0.017** 0.012 0.126*** 0.096** 0.091* 0.036 0.028 0.012 (0.091) (0.126) (0.031) (0.091) (0.032) (0.063) (0.096) (0.098) (0.089) lnEX 0.018** 0.014** 0.013* 0.009** 0.007** 0.016** -0.015** -0.011* -0.090 (0.008) (0.012) (0.016) (0.003) (0.004) (0.015) (0.006) (0.009) (0.072) Observations 1,360 1,360 1,360 741 741 741 619 619 619 R-squared 0.899 0.796 0.778 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.106 0.103 0.098 0.091 0.096 0.090 Hansen p-value 0.133 0.121 0.109 0.106 0.101 0.097 AR (2) p-value 0.496 0.493 0.401 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 3 Results for investment function Investment Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnIt-1 0.866*** 0.892*** 0.829*** 0.876*** 0.889*** 0.791* (0.023) (0.057) (0.036) (0.059) (0.062) (0.101) lnY 1.991*** 1.969*** 2.041*** 1.872*** 1.998*** 2.020*** 1.983*** 2.057*** 2.051** (0.176) (0.192) (0.116) (0.118) (0.148) (0.214) (0.101) (0.173) (0.142) lnWS -0.135*** -0.126** -0.150** -0.048** -0.073*** -0.041* -0.188*** -0.189** -0.192** (0.064) (0.032) (0.059) (0.016) (0.023) (0.015) (0.073) (0.041) (0.043) r -0.185** -0.123** -0.112* -0.308*** -0.213** -0.206* -0.086** -0.081* 0.077 (0.051) (0.059) (0.063) (0.098) (0.086) (0.079) (0.046) (0.039) (0.041) lnGF -0.216** -0.150** -0.132* -0.153*** -0.131*** -0.128 -0.231*** -0.193* -0.281* (0.051) (0.029) (0.026) (0.089) (0.016) (0.061) (0.071) (0.066) (0.142) lnEX -0.026** -0.013** -0.012* -0.006* -0.002 0.057 -0.133*** -0.101** 0.178* (0.016) (0.011) (0.012) (0.003) (0.004) (0.068) (0.013) (0.013) (0.136) Observations 1,301 1,301 1,301 703 703 703 598 598 598 R-squared 0.894 0.691 0.663 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.331 0.279 0.297 0.209 0.203 0.111 Hansen p-value 0.312 0.261 0.241 0.201 0.211 0.119 AR (2) p-value 0.626 0.412 0.351 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 4 Results for exports function Exports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnXt-1 0.929*** 0.916*** 0.842*** 0.831*** 0.928*** 0.890** (0.132) (0.101) (0.106) (0.116) (0.099) (0.114) lnY* 1.531*** 1.691*** 1.706*** 1.791*** 2.091*** 1.854** 1.571*** 2.003*** 1.321** (0.119) (0.142) (0.151) (0.115) (0.203) (0.239) (0.126) (0.187) (0.198) lnWS -0.058** -0.079*** -0.099 -0.033* -0.051* -0.076 -0.081** -0.092** -0.109 (0.019) (0.042) (0.051) (0.017) (0.029) (0.061) (0.041) (0.053) (0.106) lnRER -0.088** -0.121** -0.139** -0.131*** -0.199*** -0.131 -0.049** -0.029** -0.012 (0.026) (0.069) (0.096) (0.052) (0.066) (0.105) (0.028) (0.016) (0.011) lnGF -0.041** -0.052** 0.058* -0.016** -0.026** -0.015 -0.036** -0.038** -0.097 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) (0.011) (0.017) (0.013) (0.021) (0.016) (0.068) lnEX 0.029* -0.053 -0.028 0.009 0.006 -0.016 0.097** 0.099** 0.083 (0.018) (0.019) (0.016) (0.005) (0.005) (0.013) (0.039) (0.055) (0.067) lnRULC -0.098** -0.064* -0.100 -0.044* -0.036 -0.038 -0.088** 0.067** 0.059** (0.043) (0.033) (0.081) (0.036) (0.031) (0.027) (0.044) (0.026) (0.042) lnEXPO 0.285*** 0.193*** 0.096 0.186*** 0.171*** 0.169 0.316*** 0.221*** 0.249* (0.127) (0.109) (0.091) (0.117) (0.107) (0.128) (0.291) (0.106) (0.196) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.786 0.771 0.693 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.291 0.219 0.171 0.148 0.098 0.089 Hansen p-value 0.319 0.299 0.197 0.192 0.108 0.107 AR (2) p-value 0.172 0.140 0.136 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 5 Results for imports function Imports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnMt-1 0.696*** 0.687*** 0.519*** 0.521** 0.526*** 0.618** (0.129) (0.188) (0.138) (0.191) (0.103) (0.189) lnY 1.421*** 1.462*** 1.398** 1.283*** 1.276*** 1.142** 1.531*** 1.479*** 1.387** (0.123) (0.129) (0.201) (0.074) (0.101) (0.266) (0.144) (0.101) (0.222) lnWS 0.066** 0.083* 0.081 0.033** 0.049* 0.043 0.097** 0.099** 0.112* (0.045) (0.041) (0.059) (0.017) (0.027) (0.019) (0.031) (0.091) (0.109) lnRER 0.078*** 0.069** 0.083 0.091** 0.077** -0.070* 0.040*** 0.038* 0.051 (0.033) (0.066) (0.071) (0.032) (0.069) (0.063) (0.029) (0.028) (0.042) lnGF 0.139*** 0.083** 0.089 0.031** 0.017** 0.020 0.159*** 0.133* 0.126** (0.063) (0.051) (0.079) (0.012) (0.015) (0.019) (0.099) (0.118) (0.101) lnEX 0.215** 0.206** 0.212** 0.116* 0.103** 0.103 0.329** 0.317*** 0.323** (0.101) (0.104) (0.101) (0.071) (0.096) (0.077) (0.097) (0.081) (0.116) lnRULC 0.091* 0.076* 0.071 0.039* 0.051 0.069 0.088* 0.081* 0.096 (0.081) (0.043) (0.069) (0.031) (0.043) (0.067) (0.077) (0.069) (0.091) lnEXPO 0.326*** 0.314*** 0.269** 0.139*** 0.121** 0.136** 0.346*** 0.363*** 0.301** (0.106) (0.103) (0.128) (0.118) (0.102) (0.117) (0.109) (0.191) (0.116) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.823 0.813 0.745 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.099 0.086 0.073 0.058 0.061 0.042 Hansen p-value 0.088 0.073 0.068 0.070 0.065 0.059 AR (2) p-value 0.149 0.139 0.121 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 6 Marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in wage share on excess final demand Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery C 0.106 0.158 0.104 0.054 I -0.049 -0.016 -0.071 -0.102 X+M -0.039 -0.020 -0.057 -0.076 Y 0.018 0.122 -0.024 -0.123 Financialization 274% 352% 107% 121% Foreignization 8% 9% 6% 2% RULC 13% 26% 8% 12% VAag/VAind 10% 5% 24% 4% Notes: The calculations of the effects on the final demand are based on the FD estimators, averages 1980-2018. The elasticities were transformed to marginal effects using the participation in the GDP as a weight. The average financialization of the semi-periphery excludes China. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 7 Growth contributions Change 2010-2018 Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery Aggregate 1 ΔC 26% 14% 30% 52% 2 ΔI 27% 13% 5% 35% Δ(X-M) -29% -51% -13% -7% 3 ΔY 26% 17% 29% 45% Consumption 4 ΔC-βYΔY 7% 1% 6% 14% 5 βwsΔWS -0.2% 0.2% -0.5% -0.1% 6 βEXΔEX 0.9% 0.1% -1.6% -0.6% 7 βFΔF 3.7% 3.1% -0.2% -0.9% Investment 8 ΔI-βYΔY-βrΔr -25% -20% -52% -54% 9 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 10 βEXΔEX -1.3% 0.0% -14.1% -5.4% 11 βGFΔGF -4.3% -3.6% -2.2% -8.6% Expo-Imp 12 βY*ΔY*-βYΔY 2.9% 6.4% 0.2% 1.4% 13 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 14 βDCΔDC -13% 0% -29% -11% 15 βGFΔGF -3.6% -1.1% -1.9% -7.2% GDP 16 βwsΔWS 0.2% 0.1% 1.5% 0.2% 17 βDCΔDC -13.6% 0.3% -44.9% -17.3% 18 βFΔF -4.2% -1.6% -4.4% -16.7% Notes: The coefficients correspond to FD estimator in tables (2) to (5). βFΔF = βGFΔGF+βDHΔDH y βDCΔDC = βEXΔEX+βRULCΔRULC+βEXPOΔEXPO. Table 8 Descriptive statistics Variable N Mean SD Min Max Unit Y 1365 1005.99 2142.31 4.69 17856.48 Billions (USD) C 1365 581.19 1359.78 2.39 12388.55 Billions (USD) I 1365 282.62 791.74 0.67 12388.55 Billions (USD) X 1365 213.69 346.55 0.46 2626.65 Billions (USD) M 1365 209.77 374.07 1.26 3203.78 Billions (USD) Y* 1365 35190.46 16933.20 17379.22 82709.21 Billions (USD) WS 1365 0.57 0.09 0.31 0.76 %GDP r 1301 0.27 3.42 -0.98 93.94 % DH 1360 91.76 63.34 10.51 347.48 %GDP RER 1361 101.50 78.94 12.41 512.90 2010=100 GF 1365 2.66 3.91 0.16 33.06 %GDP EX 1365 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.86 % capital stock EXPO 1321 0.11 0.09 0.01 0.39 Ratio RULC 1363 0.13 0.12 0.02 1.13 According to USA Table 9 Unit root test Variable Im, Pesaran and Shin1 Fisher ADF2 Fisher Phillips and Perron3 >I(d) no trend trend no trend trend no trend trend Y 1.0000 0.6693 1.0000 0.3585 1.0000 0.9584 I(1) WS 0.7885 0.5955 0.4857 0.4858 0.6258 0.6125 I(1) Y* 0.6325 1.0000 0.8965 1.0000 0.9325 1.0000 I(1) C 1.0000 0.2854 1.0000 0.2587 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) I 1.0000 0.8172 0.9999 0.1125 1.0000 0.8752 I(1) X 0.9991 0.9658 0.9999 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) M 1.0000 0.2158 1.0000 0.1115 1.0000 0.1984 I(1) RER 0.0000 0.0021 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0761 I(0) r 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) RULC 0.9586 0.9589 0.9586 0.9548 0.9518 0.9651 I(1) EX 0.4586 0.9436 0.8651 0.9961 0.6351 0.9993 I(1) EXPO 0.5358 0.6151 0.6583 0.9932 0.8591 1.0000 I(1) GF 0.1412 0.1506 0.2731 0.9542 0.1452 0.6702 I(1) DH 0.3521 0.1358 0.5326 0.4891 0.6531 0.8641 I(1) ΔY 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔWS 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔY* 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔI 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRER 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Δr 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRULC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEXPO 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔGF 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔDH 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Notes": he tests are performed on the logarithmic transformation of the variables, except in the case of the real interest rate. 1. H0: all panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary. The table shows the p-value of the W-t-bar statistic. 2. H0: the panels contain unit roots; H1: at least one panel is stationary. The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). 3. H0: ll panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary.The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). Estimates run using STATA 15. ). As we mentioned, the number of instruments in the dynamic specifications is restricted to two lags.

The over-identification tests for both estimators GMM and A&H indicate that the model is correctly identified, since it is not possible to reject the null hypothesis of validity of the instruments at 5% significance. However, this result is rather weak, especially in the case of separate samples, where it is possible to reject the null hypothesis at 10% significance.

The main findings are summarized as follows: on the one hand, wage share is statistically significant and positive in all specifications. The size of the effect is larger, on average, for central countries than for those peripheral and semi-peripheral countries and these results are robust in all estimations; second, financialization, measured as the sum of foreign assets and liabilities in relation to GDP, is significant and negative, being the size of the effect larger for peripheral countries in absolute terms. This result is also robust in the different estimated specifications.

The significance of wage share, as well as its sign, are maintained when removing the dependency variables, and the results are in line with what is found in the empirical literature analyzing demand-led growth. However, differences in the magnitude of the coefficients are observed, especially for the group of peripheral and semi-peripheral countries. In particular, we note that the effect of wage share on consumption is smaller when variables related to the dependent condition of the countries are not controlled for than in the case where they are not incorporated.

Regarding household debt and the non-financial business sector, the obtained results account for its relevance only in central countries, where it has a positive and statistically significant effect (similar to Stockhammer and Wildauer, 2016Stockhammer, E. and Wildauer, R. (2016). Debt-driven growth? Wealth, distribution and demand in OECD countries, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 40, no. 6, 1609-1634). Finally, as regards the foreignization variable, the result is significant for most of the estimators and they present inverse signs for the center and the peripheries.

Investment

The investment function has been estimated in the following way:

ln I i t = α ln I i t - 1 + β 1 ln Y i t + β 2 r i t + β 3 ln W S i t + ω F i t + γ D C + ν i + ν i t (3)

where υ i are country fixed effects and it is the residual term. The results of the estimations under different specifications are summarized in Table 3. Again, the number of instruments in the dynamic specifications is restricted to two lags.

According to the results of the over-identification tests, the instruments are valid for both dynamic estimators in the different specifications (it is not possible to reject the null hypothesis at 10% significance).

The results reported in Table 3 indicate the following. The national income has a positive and significant effect on investment, with an elasticity close to one, which is a robust result in the different estimated models. Regarding wage share, results show a negative and significant sign for the whole panel, in line with the prediction made by a good part of the economic literature. These results hold for the case of the central countries as well as for the peripheral and semi-peripheral countries. Here, the size of absolute effect is substantially higher. The real interest rate is relevant and affects investment negatively in all specifications. However, the size of the effect is larger for central countries. The sign and significance of the coefficients are maintained when not controlling for the variables related to the dependency status of the countries. However, as in the case of consumption, the magnitude of the coefficients is modified, reducing the differences found for the subsamples of central and peripheral countries.

Financial globalization affects gross fixed capital formation negatively. This result persists across the different specifications both in central and peripheral countries, being the size of the effect slightly larger for the latter. Finally, the foreignization of the economy is negative and statistically significant for the whole panel. This result does not persist in the case of central countries since the coefficient for this variable is not significant.

External Sector

For the external sector, we estimated export and import functions separately, as it is shown in equations (4) and (5).

ln X i t = α ln X i t - 1 + β 1 + ln Y i t * + β 2 ln E R i t + β 3 ln W S i t + ω F i t + γ D C + ρ i + ε i t (4)

ln M i t = α ln M i t - 1 + β 1 + ln Y i t * + β 2 ln E R i t + β 3 ln W S i t + ω F i t + γ D C + τ i + ε i t (5)

Where ρ i and τ i are country fixed effects and εit and υit are residual terms, in export and import functions, respectively.

In the dynamic specifications it is not possible to reject the null hypothesis of validity of the instruments in the over-identification tests. However, the result is weak for the group of peripheral and semi-peripheral countries, since it rejects 10% significance (see Table 4 in the Appendix Appendix Table 2 Results for consumption function Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnCt-1 0.761*** 0.743*** 0.777*** 0.716*** 0.790*** 0.656*** (0.059) (0.055) (0.060) (0.083) (0.054) (0.088) lnY 0.731*** 0.581*** 0.501*** 0.721*** 0.541*** 0.556** 0.844*** 0.601*** 0.599*** (0.016) (0.068) (0.059) (0.028) (0.063) (0.110) (0.019) (0.064) (0.098) lnWS 0.116** 0.132** 0.098* 0.171*** 0.193** 0.126* 0.086** 0.080** 0.076** (0.014) (0.042) (0.041) (0.032) (0.061) (0.063) (0.012) (0.037) (0.051) lnGF -0.017*** -0.036*** -0.015* -0.007** -0.021*** -0.016* -0.025*** -0.039** -0.053 (0.004) (0.007) (0.009) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) (0.036) lnDH 0.095** 0.017** 0.012 0.126*** 0.096** 0.091* 0.036 0.028 0.012 (0.091) (0.126) (0.031) (0.091) (0.032) (0.063) (0.096) (0.098) (0.089) lnEX 0.018** 0.014** 0.013* 0.009** 0.007** 0.016** -0.015** -0.011* -0.090 (0.008) (0.012) (0.016) (0.003) (0.004) (0.015) (0.006) (0.009) (0.072) Observations 1,360 1,360 1,360 741 741 741 619 619 619 R-squared 0.899 0.796 0.778 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.106 0.103 0.098 0.091 0.096 0.090 Hansen p-value 0.133 0.121 0.109 0.106 0.101 0.097 AR (2) p-value 0.496 0.493 0.401 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 3 Results for investment function Investment Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnIt-1 0.866*** 0.892*** 0.829*** 0.876*** 0.889*** 0.791* (0.023) (0.057) (0.036) (0.059) (0.062) (0.101) lnY 1.991*** 1.969*** 2.041*** 1.872*** 1.998*** 2.020*** 1.983*** 2.057*** 2.051** (0.176) (0.192) (0.116) (0.118) (0.148) (0.214) (0.101) (0.173) (0.142) lnWS -0.135*** -0.126** -0.150** -0.048** -0.073*** -0.041* -0.188*** -0.189** -0.192** (0.064) (0.032) (0.059) (0.016) (0.023) (0.015) (0.073) (0.041) (0.043) r -0.185** -0.123** -0.112* -0.308*** -0.213** -0.206* -0.086** -0.081* 0.077 (0.051) (0.059) (0.063) (0.098) (0.086) (0.079) (0.046) (0.039) (0.041) lnGF -0.216** -0.150** -0.132* -0.153*** -0.131*** -0.128 -0.231*** -0.193* -0.281* (0.051) (0.029) (0.026) (0.089) (0.016) (0.061) (0.071) (0.066) (0.142) lnEX -0.026** -0.013** -0.012* -0.006* -0.002 0.057 -0.133*** -0.101** 0.178* (0.016) (0.011) (0.012) (0.003) (0.004) (0.068) (0.013) (0.013) (0.136) Observations 1,301 1,301 1,301 703 703 703 598 598 598 R-squared 0.894 0.691 0.663 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.331 0.279 0.297 0.209 0.203 0.111 Hansen p-value 0.312 0.261 0.241 0.201 0.211 0.119 AR (2) p-value 0.626 0.412 0.351 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 4 Results for exports function Exports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnXt-1 0.929*** 0.916*** 0.842*** 0.831*** 0.928*** 0.890** (0.132) (0.101) (0.106) (0.116) (0.099) (0.114) lnY* 1.531*** 1.691*** 1.706*** 1.791*** 2.091*** 1.854** 1.571*** 2.003*** 1.321** (0.119) (0.142) (0.151) (0.115) (0.203) (0.239) (0.126) (0.187) (0.198) lnWS -0.058** -0.079*** -0.099 -0.033* -0.051* -0.076 -0.081** -0.092** -0.109 (0.019) (0.042) (0.051) (0.017) (0.029) (0.061) (0.041) (0.053) (0.106) lnRER -0.088** -0.121** -0.139** -0.131*** -0.199*** -0.131 -0.049** -0.029** -0.012 (0.026) (0.069) (0.096) (0.052) (0.066) (0.105) (0.028) (0.016) (0.011) lnGF -0.041** -0.052** 0.058* -0.016** -0.026** -0.015 -0.036** -0.038** -0.097 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) (0.011) (0.017) (0.013) (0.021) (0.016) (0.068) lnEX 0.029* -0.053 -0.028 0.009 0.006 -0.016 0.097** 0.099** 0.083 (0.018) (0.019) (0.016) (0.005) (0.005) (0.013) (0.039) (0.055) (0.067) lnRULC -0.098** -0.064* -0.100 -0.044* -0.036 -0.038 -0.088** 0.067** 0.059** (0.043) (0.033) (0.081) (0.036) (0.031) (0.027) (0.044) (0.026) (0.042) lnEXPO 0.285*** 0.193*** 0.096 0.186*** 0.171*** 0.169 0.316*** 0.221*** 0.249* (0.127) (0.109) (0.091) (0.117) (0.107) (0.128) (0.291) (0.106) (0.196) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.786 0.771 0.693 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.291 0.219 0.171 0.148 0.098 0.089 Hansen p-value 0.319 0.299 0.197 0.192 0.108 0.107 AR (2) p-value 0.172 0.140 0.136 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 5 Results for imports function Imports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnMt-1 0.696*** 0.687*** 0.519*** 0.521** 0.526*** 0.618** (0.129) (0.188) (0.138) (0.191) (0.103) (0.189) lnY 1.421*** 1.462*** 1.398** 1.283*** 1.276*** 1.142** 1.531*** 1.479*** 1.387** (0.123) (0.129) (0.201) (0.074) (0.101) (0.266) (0.144) (0.101) (0.222) lnWS 0.066** 0.083* 0.081 0.033** 0.049* 0.043 0.097** 0.099** 0.112* (0.045) (0.041) (0.059) (0.017) (0.027) (0.019) (0.031) (0.091) (0.109) lnRER 0.078*** 0.069** 0.083 0.091** 0.077** -0.070* 0.040*** 0.038* 0.051 (0.033) (0.066) (0.071) (0.032) (0.069) (0.063) (0.029) (0.028) (0.042) lnGF 0.139*** 0.083** 0.089 0.031** 0.017** 0.020 0.159*** 0.133* 0.126** (0.063) (0.051) (0.079) (0.012) (0.015) (0.019) (0.099) (0.118) (0.101) lnEX 0.215** 0.206** 0.212** 0.116* 0.103** 0.103 0.329** 0.317*** 0.323** (0.101) (0.104) (0.101) (0.071) (0.096) (0.077) (0.097) (0.081) (0.116) lnRULC 0.091* 0.076* 0.071 0.039* 0.051 0.069 0.088* 0.081* 0.096 (0.081) (0.043) (0.069) (0.031) (0.043) (0.067) (0.077) (0.069) (0.091) lnEXPO 0.326*** 0.314*** 0.269** 0.139*** 0.121** 0.136** 0.346*** 0.363*** 0.301** (0.106) (0.103) (0.128) (0.118) (0.102) (0.117) (0.109) (0.191) (0.116) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.823 0.813 0.745 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.099 0.086 0.073 0.058 0.061 0.042 Hansen p-value 0.088 0.073 0.068 0.070 0.065 0.059 AR (2) p-value 0.149 0.139 0.121 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 6 Marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in wage share on excess final demand Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery C 0.106 0.158 0.104 0.054 I -0.049 -0.016 -0.071 -0.102 X+M -0.039 -0.020 -0.057 -0.076 Y 0.018 0.122 -0.024 -0.123 Financialization 274% 352% 107% 121% Foreignization 8% 9% 6% 2% RULC 13% 26% 8% 12% VAag/VAind 10% 5% 24% 4% Notes: The calculations of the effects on the final demand are based on the FD estimators, averages 1980-2018. The elasticities were transformed to marginal effects using the participation in the GDP as a weight. The average financialization of the semi-periphery excludes China. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 7 Growth contributions Change 2010-2018 Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery Aggregate 1 ΔC 26% 14% 30% 52% 2 ΔI 27% 13% 5% 35% Δ(X-M) -29% -51% -13% -7% 3 ΔY 26% 17% 29% 45% Consumption 4 ΔC-βYΔY 7% 1% 6% 14% 5 βwsΔWS -0.2% 0.2% -0.5% -0.1% 6 βEXΔEX 0.9% 0.1% -1.6% -0.6% 7 βFΔF 3.7% 3.1% -0.2% -0.9% Investment 8 ΔI-βYΔY-βrΔr -25% -20% -52% -54% 9 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 10 βEXΔEX -1.3% 0.0% -14.1% -5.4% 11 βGFΔGF -4.3% -3.6% -2.2% -8.6% Expo-Imp 12 βY*ΔY*-βYΔY 2.9% 6.4% 0.2% 1.4% 13 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 14 βDCΔDC -13% 0% -29% -11% 15 βGFΔGF -3.6% -1.1% -1.9% -7.2% GDP 16 βwsΔWS 0.2% 0.1% 1.5% 0.2% 17 βDCΔDC -13.6% 0.3% -44.9% -17.3% 18 βFΔF -4.2% -1.6% -4.4% -16.7% Notes: The coefficients correspond to FD estimator in tables (2) to (5). βFΔF = βGFΔGF+βDHΔDH y βDCΔDC = βEXΔEX+βRULCΔRULC+βEXPOΔEXPO. Table 8 Descriptive statistics Variable N Mean SD Min Max Unit Y 1365 1005.99 2142.31 4.69 17856.48 Billions (USD) C 1365 581.19 1359.78 2.39 12388.55 Billions (USD) I 1365 282.62 791.74 0.67 12388.55 Billions (USD) X 1365 213.69 346.55 0.46 2626.65 Billions (USD) M 1365 209.77 374.07 1.26 3203.78 Billions (USD) Y* 1365 35190.46 16933.20 17379.22 82709.21 Billions (USD) WS 1365 0.57 0.09 0.31 0.76 %GDP r 1301 0.27 3.42 -0.98 93.94 % DH 1360 91.76 63.34 10.51 347.48 %GDP RER 1361 101.50 78.94 12.41 512.90 2010=100 GF 1365 2.66 3.91 0.16 33.06 %GDP EX 1365 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.86 % capital stock EXPO 1321 0.11 0.09 0.01 0.39 Ratio RULC 1363 0.13 0.12 0.02 1.13 According to USA Table 9 Unit root test Variable Im, Pesaran and Shin1 Fisher ADF2 Fisher Phillips and Perron3 >I(d) no trend trend no trend trend no trend trend Y 1.0000 0.6693 1.0000 0.3585 1.0000 0.9584 I(1) WS 0.7885 0.5955 0.4857 0.4858 0.6258 0.6125 I(1) Y* 0.6325 1.0000 0.8965 1.0000 0.9325 1.0000 I(1) C 1.0000 0.2854 1.0000 0.2587 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) I 1.0000 0.8172 0.9999 0.1125 1.0000 0.8752 I(1) X 0.9991 0.9658 0.9999 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) M 1.0000 0.2158 1.0000 0.1115 1.0000 0.1984 I(1) RER 0.0000 0.0021 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0761 I(0) r 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) RULC 0.9586 0.9589 0.9586 0.9548 0.9518 0.9651 I(1) EX 0.4586 0.9436 0.8651 0.9961 0.6351 0.9993 I(1) EXPO 0.5358 0.6151 0.6583 0.9932 0.8591 1.0000 I(1) GF 0.1412 0.1506 0.2731 0.9542 0.1452 0.6702 I(1) DH 0.3521 0.1358 0.5326 0.4891 0.6531 0.8641 I(1) ΔY 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔWS 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔY* 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔI 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRER 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Δr 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRULC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEXPO 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔGF 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔDH 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Notes": he tests are performed on the logarithmic transformation of the variables, except in the case of the real interest rate. 1. H0: all panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary. The table shows the p-value of the W-t-bar statistic. 2. H0: the panels contain unit roots; H1: at least one panel is stationary. The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). 3. H0: ll panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary.The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). Estimates run using STATA 15. ).

As expected, foreign demand is positive and statistically significant, and the output elasticity is above one in all specifications. The effect of wage share on exports is negative and its size is larger in peripheral economies. Regarding real exchange rates, the sign of the coefficient indicates that the appreciation of domestic currency has a negative impact on exports. Financialization affects exports negatively. This result persists across different specifications and groups of countries. In general terms, these results hold when not controlling for the dependency-related variables. In all cases, the magnitude of the real exchange rate coefficient is smaller (in absolute values) when controlling for the productivity and GVC participation variables. The inclusion of the foreignization and financialization variables does not significantly modify the results.

Foreignization is a relevant variable only for the group of countries of the periphery. A positive sign has been obtained for the effect of foreignization on exports. The relation between domestic value added in agricultural and manufacturing exports is a relevant variable for total exports which has positive effects. The effect is greater in peripheral and semi-peripheral economies than in central economies. Finally, the Relative Unitary Labor Costs are positive and statistically significant for the peripheral and semi-peripheral economies but not for the central ones.

The GMM estimator overcomes the test of over-identification at 5% significance (not so at 10% significance). While for the A&H estimator, the over-identification tests indicate endogeneity problems with the instruments.

The output elasticity of imports results positive and above one; a robust result across the different specifications. The wage share is positive and statistically significant for the FD estimator, but not for dynamic estimators (see Table 5 in the Appendix Appendix Table 2 Results for consumption function Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnCt-1 0.761*** 0.743*** 0.777*** 0.716*** 0.790*** 0.656*** (0.059) (0.055) (0.060) (0.083) (0.054) (0.088) lnY 0.731*** 0.581*** 0.501*** 0.721*** 0.541*** 0.556** 0.844*** 0.601*** 0.599*** (0.016) (0.068) (0.059) (0.028) (0.063) (0.110) (0.019) (0.064) (0.098) lnWS 0.116** 0.132** 0.098* 0.171*** 0.193** 0.126* 0.086** 0.080** 0.076** (0.014) (0.042) (0.041) (0.032) (0.061) (0.063) (0.012) (0.037) (0.051) lnGF -0.017*** -0.036*** -0.015* -0.007** -0.021*** -0.016* -0.025*** -0.039** -0.053 (0.004) (0.007) (0.009) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) (0.036) lnDH 0.095** 0.017** 0.012 0.126*** 0.096** 0.091* 0.036 0.028 0.012 (0.091) (0.126) (0.031) (0.091) (0.032) (0.063) (0.096) (0.098) (0.089) lnEX 0.018** 0.014** 0.013* 0.009** 0.007** 0.016** -0.015** -0.011* -0.090 (0.008) (0.012) (0.016) (0.003) (0.004) (0.015) (0.006) (0.009) (0.072) Observations 1,360 1,360 1,360 741 741 741 619 619 619 R-squared 0.899 0.796 0.778 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.106 0.103 0.098 0.091 0.096 0.090 Hansen p-value 0.133 0.121 0.109 0.106 0.101 0.097 AR (2) p-value 0.496 0.493 0.401 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 3 Results for investment function Investment Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnIt-1 0.866*** 0.892*** 0.829*** 0.876*** 0.889*** 0.791* (0.023) (0.057) (0.036) (0.059) (0.062) (0.101) lnY 1.991*** 1.969*** 2.041*** 1.872*** 1.998*** 2.020*** 1.983*** 2.057*** 2.051** (0.176) (0.192) (0.116) (0.118) (0.148) (0.214) (0.101) (0.173) (0.142) lnWS -0.135*** -0.126** -0.150** -0.048** -0.073*** -0.041* -0.188*** -0.189** -0.192** (0.064) (0.032) (0.059) (0.016) (0.023) (0.015) (0.073) (0.041) (0.043) r -0.185** -0.123** -0.112* -0.308*** -0.213** -0.206* -0.086** -0.081* 0.077 (0.051) (0.059) (0.063) (0.098) (0.086) (0.079) (0.046) (0.039) (0.041) lnGF -0.216** -0.150** -0.132* -0.153*** -0.131*** -0.128 -0.231*** -0.193* -0.281* (0.051) (0.029) (0.026) (0.089) (0.016) (0.061) (0.071) (0.066) (0.142) lnEX -0.026** -0.013** -0.012* -0.006* -0.002 0.057 -0.133*** -0.101** 0.178* (0.016) (0.011) (0.012) (0.003) (0.004) (0.068) (0.013) (0.013) (0.136) Observations 1,301 1,301 1,301 703 703 703 598 598 598 R-squared 0.894 0.691 0.663 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.331 0.279 0.297 0.209 0.203 0.111 Hansen p-value 0.312 0.261 0.241 0.201 0.211 0.119 AR (2) p-value 0.626 0.412 0.351 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 4 Results for exports function Exports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnXt-1 0.929*** 0.916*** 0.842*** 0.831*** 0.928*** 0.890** (0.132) (0.101) (0.106) (0.116) (0.099) (0.114) lnY* 1.531*** 1.691*** 1.706*** 1.791*** 2.091*** 1.854** 1.571*** 2.003*** 1.321** (0.119) (0.142) (0.151) (0.115) (0.203) (0.239) (0.126) (0.187) (0.198) lnWS -0.058** -0.079*** -0.099 -0.033* -0.051* -0.076 -0.081** -0.092** -0.109 (0.019) (0.042) (0.051) (0.017) (0.029) (0.061) (0.041) (0.053) (0.106) lnRER -0.088** -0.121** -0.139** -0.131*** -0.199*** -0.131 -0.049** -0.029** -0.012 (0.026) (0.069) (0.096) (0.052) (0.066) (0.105) (0.028) (0.016) (0.011) lnGF -0.041** -0.052** 0.058* -0.016** -0.026** -0.015 -0.036** -0.038** -0.097 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) (0.011) (0.017) (0.013) (0.021) (0.016) (0.068) lnEX 0.029* -0.053 -0.028 0.009 0.006 -0.016 0.097** 0.099** 0.083 (0.018) (0.019) (0.016) (0.005) (0.005) (0.013) (0.039) (0.055) (0.067) lnRULC -0.098** -0.064* -0.100 -0.044* -0.036 -0.038 -0.088** 0.067** 0.059** (0.043) (0.033) (0.081) (0.036) (0.031) (0.027) (0.044) (0.026) (0.042) lnEXPO 0.285*** 0.193*** 0.096 0.186*** 0.171*** 0.169 0.316*** 0.221*** 0.249* (0.127) (0.109) (0.091) (0.117) (0.107) (0.128) (0.291) (0.106) (0.196) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.786 0.771 0.693 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.291 0.219 0.171 0.148 0.098 0.089 Hansen p-value 0.319 0.299 0.197 0.192 0.108 0.107 AR (2) p-value 0.172 0.140 0.136 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 5 Results for imports function Imports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnMt-1 0.696*** 0.687*** 0.519*** 0.521** 0.526*** 0.618** (0.129) (0.188) (0.138) (0.191) (0.103) (0.189) lnY 1.421*** 1.462*** 1.398** 1.283*** 1.276*** 1.142** 1.531*** 1.479*** 1.387** (0.123) (0.129) (0.201) (0.074) (0.101) (0.266) (0.144) (0.101) (0.222) lnWS 0.066** 0.083* 0.081 0.033** 0.049* 0.043 0.097** 0.099** 0.112* (0.045) (0.041) (0.059) (0.017) (0.027) (0.019) (0.031) (0.091) (0.109) lnRER 0.078*** 0.069** 0.083 0.091** 0.077** -0.070* 0.040*** 0.038* 0.051 (0.033) (0.066) (0.071) (0.032) (0.069) (0.063) (0.029) (0.028) (0.042) lnGF 0.139*** 0.083** 0.089 0.031** 0.017** 0.020 0.159*** 0.133* 0.126** (0.063) (0.051) (0.079) (0.012) (0.015) (0.019) (0.099) (0.118) (0.101) lnEX 0.215** 0.206** 0.212** 0.116* 0.103** 0.103 0.329** 0.317*** 0.323** (0.101) (0.104) (0.101) (0.071) (0.096) (0.077) (0.097) (0.081) (0.116) lnRULC 0.091* 0.076* 0.071 0.039* 0.051 0.069 0.088* 0.081* 0.096 (0.081) (0.043) (0.069) (0.031) (0.043) (0.067) (0.077) (0.069) (0.091) lnEXPO 0.326*** 0.314*** 0.269** 0.139*** 0.121** 0.136** 0.346*** 0.363*** 0.301** (0.106) (0.103) (0.128) (0.118) (0.102) (0.117) (0.109) (0.191) (0.116) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.823 0.813 0.745 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.099 0.086 0.073 0.058 0.061 0.042 Hansen p-value 0.088 0.073 0.068 0.070 0.065 0.059 AR (2) p-value 0.149 0.139 0.121 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 6 Marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in wage share on excess final demand Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery C 0.106 0.158 0.104 0.054 I -0.049 -0.016 -0.071 -0.102 X+M -0.039 -0.020 -0.057 -0.076 Y 0.018 0.122 -0.024 -0.123 Financialization 274% 352% 107% 121% Foreignization 8% 9% 6% 2% RULC 13% 26% 8% 12% VAag/VAind 10% 5% 24% 4% Notes: The calculations of the effects on the final demand are based on the FD estimators, averages 1980-2018. The elasticities were transformed to marginal effects using the participation in the GDP as a weight. The average financialization of the semi-periphery excludes China. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 7 Growth contributions Change 2010-2018 Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery Aggregate 1 ΔC 26% 14% 30% 52% 2 ΔI 27% 13% 5% 35% Δ(X-M) -29% -51% -13% -7% 3 ΔY 26% 17% 29% 45% Consumption 4 ΔC-βYΔY 7% 1% 6% 14% 5 βwsΔWS -0.2% 0.2% -0.5% -0.1% 6 βEXΔEX 0.9% 0.1% -1.6% -0.6% 7 βFΔF 3.7% 3.1% -0.2% -0.9% Investment 8 ΔI-βYΔY-βrΔr -25% -20% -52% -54% 9 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 10 βEXΔEX -1.3% 0.0% -14.1% -5.4% 11 βGFΔGF -4.3% -3.6% -2.2% -8.6% Expo-Imp 12 βY*ΔY*-βYΔY 2.9% 6.4% 0.2% 1.4% 13 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 14 βDCΔDC -13% 0% -29% -11% 15 βGFΔGF -3.6% -1.1% -1.9% -7.2% GDP 16 βwsΔWS 0.2% 0.1% 1.5% 0.2% 17 βDCΔDC -13.6% 0.3% -44.9% -17.3% 18 βFΔF -4.2% -1.6% -4.4% -16.7% Notes: The coefficients correspond to FD estimator in tables (2) to (5). βFΔF = βGFΔGF+βDHΔDH y βDCΔDC = βEXΔEX+βRULCΔRULC+βEXPOΔEXPO. Table 8 Descriptive statistics Variable N Mean SD Min Max Unit Y 1365 1005.99 2142.31 4.69 17856.48 Billions (USD) C 1365 581.19 1359.78 2.39 12388.55 Billions (USD) I 1365 282.62 791.74 0.67 12388.55 Billions (USD) X 1365 213.69 346.55 0.46 2626.65 Billions (USD) M 1365 209.77 374.07 1.26 3203.78 Billions (USD) Y* 1365 35190.46 16933.20 17379.22 82709.21 Billions (USD) WS 1365 0.57 0.09 0.31 0.76 %GDP r 1301 0.27 3.42 -0.98 93.94 % DH 1360 91.76 63.34 10.51 347.48 %GDP RER 1361 101.50 78.94 12.41 512.90 2010=100 GF 1365 2.66 3.91 0.16 33.06 %GDP EX 1365 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.86 % capital stock EXPO 1321 0.11 0.09 0.01 0.39 Ratio RULC 1363 0.13 0.12 0.02 1.13 According to USA Table 9 Unit root test Variable Im, Pesaran and Shin1 Fisher ADF2 Fisher Phillips and Perron3 >I(d) no trend trend no trend trend no trend trend Y 1.0000 0.6693 1.0000 0.3585 1.0000 0.9584 I(1) WS 0.7885 0.5955 0.4857 0.4858 0.6258 0.6125 I(1) Y* 0.6325 1.0000 0.8965 1.0000 0.9325 1.0000 I(1) C 1.0000 0.2854 1.0000 0.2587 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) I 1.0000 0.8172 0.9999 0.1125 1.0000 0.8752 I(1) X 0.9991 0.9658 0.9999 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) M 1.0000 0.2158 1.0000 0.1115 1.0000 0.1984 I(1) RER 0.0000 0.0021 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0761 I(0) r 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) RULC 0.9586 0.9589 0.9586 0.9548 0.9518 0.9651 I(1) EX 0.4586 0.9436 0.8651 0.9961 0.6351 0.9993 I(1) EXPO 0.5358 0.6151 0.6583 0.9932 0.8591 1.0000 I(1) GF 0.1412 0.1506 0.2731 0.9542 0.1452 0.6702 I(1) DH 0.3521 0.1358 0.5326 0.4891 0.6531 0.8641 I(1) ΔY 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔWS 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔY* 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔI 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRER 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Δr 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRULC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEXPO 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔGF 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔDH 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Notes": he tests are performed on the logarithmic transformation of the variables, except in the case of the real interest rate. 1. H0: all panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary. The table shows the p-value of the W-t-bar statistic. 2. H0: the panels contain unit roots; H1: at least one panel is stationary. The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). 3. H0: ll panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary.The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). Estimates run using STATA 15. ). The size of the effect in absolute terms is greater than in the periphery. The Real Exchange Rate indicates that an appreciation of domestic money has a positive impact on imports. The significance and sign of these coefficients is maintained if we do not control for the dependency-related variables. However, the effect of the real exchange rate on imports is smaller in absolute terms when foreign ownership and GVC participation are included in the model.

Financialization has a positive effect on imports, but its size is small. Regarding the variable EXPO, the effect is positive and statistically significant both for the whole panel and for different country groups. The magnitude of the effect is significantly larger in peripheral countries than in central ones. As for the RULC, neither in the center nor in the peripheries have significant differential effects been identified.

Demand regime and Growth Contribution

We discuss here the results related to demand regimes (for data details see Table 6 in the Appendix Appendix Table 2 Results for consumption function Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnCt-1 0.761*** 0.743*** 0.777*** 0.716*** 0.790*** 0.656*** (0.059) (0.055) (0.060) (0.083) (0.054) (0.088) lnY 0.731*** 0.581*** 0.501*** 0.721*** 0.541*** 0.556** 0.844*** 0.601*** 0.599*** (0.016) (0.068) (0.059) (0.028) (0.063) (0.110) (0.019) (0.064) (0.098) lnWS 0.116** 0.132** 0.098* 0.171*** 0.193** 0.126* 0.086** 0.080** 0.076** (0.014) (0.042) (0.041) (0.032) (0.061) (0.063) (0.012) (0.037) (0.051) lnGF -0.017*** -0.036*** -0.015* -0.007** -0.021*** -0.016* -0.025*** -0.039** -0.053 (0.004) (0.007) (0.009) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) (0.036) lnDH 0.095** 0.017** 0.012 0.126*** 0.096** 0.091* 0.036 0.028 0.012 (0.091) (0.126) (0.031) (0.091) (0.032) (0.063) (0.096) (0.098) (0.089) lnEX 0.018** 0.014** 0.013* 0.009** 0.007** 0.016** -0.015** -0.011* -0.090 (0.008) (0.012) (0.016) (0.003) (0.004) (0.015) (0.006) (0.009) (0.072) Observations 1,360 1,360 1,360 741 741 741 619 619 619 R-squared 0.899 0.796 0.778 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.106 0.103 0.098 0.091 0.096 0.090 Hansen p-value 0.133 0.121 0.109 0.106 0.101 0.097 AR (2) p-value 0.496 0.493 0.401 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 3 Results for investment function Investment Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnIt-1 0.866*** 0.892*** 0.829*** 0.876*** 0.889*** 0.791* (0.023) (0.057) (0.036) (0.059) (0.062) (0.101) lnY 1.991*** 1.969*** 2.041*** 1.872*** 1.998*** 2.020*** 1.983*** 2.057*** 2.051** (0.176) (0.192) (0.116) (0.118) (0.148) (0.214) (0.101) (0.173) (0.142) lnWS -0.135*** -0.126** -0.150** -0.048** -0.073*** -0.041* -0.188*** -0.189** -0.192** (0.064) (0.032) (0.059) (0.016) (0.023) (0.015) (0.073) (0.041) (0.043) r -0.185** -0.123** -0.112* -0.308*** -0.213** -0.206* -0.086** -0.081* 0.077 (0.051) (0.059) (0.063) (0.098) (0.086) (0.079) (0.046) (0.039) (0.041) lnGF -0.216** -0.150** -0.132* -0.153*** -0.131*** -0.128 -0.231*** -0.193* -0.281* (0.051) (0.029) (0.026) (0.089) (0.016) (0.061) (0.071) (0.066) (0.142) lnEX -0.026** -0.013** -0.012* -0.006* -0.002 0.057 -0.133*** -0.101** 0.178* (0.016) (0.011) (0.012) (0.003) (0.004) (0.068) (0.013) (0.013) (0.136) Observations 1,301 1,301 1,301 703 703 703 598 598 598 R-squared 0.894 0.691 0.663 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.331 0.279 0.297 0.209 0.203 0.111 Hansen p-value 0.312 0.261 0.241 0.201 0.211 0.119 AR (2) p-value 0.626 0.412 0.351 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 4 Results for exports function Exports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnXt-1 0.929*** 0.916*** 0.842*** 0.831*** 0.928*** 0.890** (0.132) (0.101) (0.106) (0.116) (0.099) (0.114) lnY* 1.531*** 1.691*** 1.706*** 1.791*** 2.091*** 1.854** 1.571*** 2.003*** 1.321** (0.119) (0.142) (0.151) (0.115) (0.203) (0.239) (0.126) (0.187) (0.198) lnWS -0.058** -0.079*** -0.099 -0.033* -0.051* -0.076 -0.081** -0.092** -0.109 (0.019) (0.042) (0.051) (0.017) (0.029) (0.061) (0.041) (0.053) (0.106) lnRER -0.088** -0.121** -0.139** -0.131*** -0.199*** -0.131 -0.049** -0.029** -0.012 (0.026) (0.069) (0.096) (0.052) (0.066) (0.105) (0.028) (0.016) (0.011) lnGF -0.041** -0.052** 0.058* -0.016** -0.026** -0.015 -0.036** -0.038** -0.097 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) (0.011) (0.017) (0.013) (0.021) (0.016) (0.068) lnEX 0.029* -0.053 -0.028 0.009 0.006 -0.016 0.097** 0.099** 0.083 (0.018) (0.019) (0.016) (0.005) (0.005) (0.013) (0.039) (0.055) (0.067) lnRULC -0.098** -0.064* -0.100 -0.044* -0.036 -0.038 -0.088** 0.067** 0.059** (0.043) (0.033) (0.081) (0.036) (0.031) (0.027) (0.044) (0.026) (0.042) lnEXPO 0.285*** 0.193*** 0.096 0.186*** 0.171*** 0.169 0.316*** 0.221*** 0.249* (0.127) (0.109) (0.091) (0.117) (0.107) (0.128) (0.291) (0.106) (0.196) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.786 0.771 0.693 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.291 0.219 0.171 0.148 0.098 0.089 Hansen p-value 0.319 0.299 0.197 0.192 0.108 0.107 AR (2) p-value 0.172 0.140 0.136 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 5 Results for imports function Imports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnMt-1 0.696*** 0.687*** 0.519*** 0.521** 0.526*** 0.618** (0.129) (0.188) (0.138) (0.191) (0.103) (0.189) lnY 1.421*** 1.462*** 1.398** 1.283*** 1.276*** 1.142** 1.531*** 1.479*** 1.387** (0.123) (0.129) (0.201) (0.074) (0.101) (0.266) (0.144) (0.101) (0.222) lnWS 0.066** 0.083* 0.081 0.033** 0.049* 0.043 0.097** 0.099** 0.112* (0.045) (0.041) (0.059) (0.017) (0.027) (0.019) (0.031) (0.091) (0.109) lnRER 0.078*** 0.069** 0.083 0.091** 0.077** -0.070* 0.040*** 0.038* 0.051 (0.033) (0.066) (0.071) (0.032) (0.069) (0.063) (0.029) (0.028) (0.042) lnGF 0.139*** 0.083** 0.089 0.031** 0.017** 0.020 0.159*** 0.133* 0.126** (0.063) (0.051) (0.079) (0.012) (0.015) (0.019) (0.099) (0.118) (0.101) lnEX 0.215** 0.206** 0.212** 0.116* 0.103** 0.103 0.329** 0.317*** 0.323** (0.101) (0.104) (0.101) (0.071) (0.096) (0.077) (0.097) (0.081) (0.116) lnRULC 0.091* 0.076* 0.071 0.039* 0.051 0.069 0.088* 0.081* 0.096 (0.081) (0.043) (0.069) (0.031) (0.043) (0.067) (0.077) (0.069) (0.091) lnEXPO 0.326*** 0.314*** 0.269** 0.139*** 0.121** 0.136** 0.346*** 0.363*** 0.301** (0.106) (0.103) (0.128) (0.118) (0.102) (0.117) (0.109) (0.191) (0.116) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.823 0.813 0.745 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.099 0.086 0.073 0.058 0.061 0.042 Hansen p-value 0.088 0.073 0.068 0.070 0.065 0.059 AR (2) p-value 0.149 0.139 0.121 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 6 Marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in wage share on excess final demand Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery C 0.106 0.158 0.104 0.054 I -0.049 -0.016 -0.071 -0.102 X+M -0.039 -0.020 -0.057 -0.076 Y 0.018 0.122 -0.024 -0.123 Financialization 274% 352% 107% 121% Foreignization 8% 9% 6% 2% RULC 13% 26% 8% 12% VAag/VAind 10% 5% 24% 4% Notes: The calculations of the effects on the final demand are based on the FD estimators, averages 1980-2018. The elasticities were transformed to marginal effects using the participation in the GDP as a weight. The average financialization of the semi-periphery excludes China. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 7 Growth contributions Change 2010-2018 Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery Aggregate 1 ΔC 26% 14% 30% 52% 2 ΔI 27% 13% 5% 35% Δ(X-M) -29% -51% -13% -7% 3 ΔY 26% 17% 29% 45% Consumption 4 ΔC-βYΔY 7% 1% 6% 14% 5 βwsΔWS -0.2% 0.2% -0.5% -0.1% 6 βEXΔEX 0.9% 0.1% -1.6% -0.6% 7 βFΔF 3.7% 3.1% -0.2% -0.9% Investment 8 ΔI-βYΔY-βrΔr -25% -20% -52% -54% 9 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 10 βEXΔEX -1.3% 0.0% -14.1% -5.4% 11 βGFΔGF -4.3% -3.6% -2.2% -8.6% Expo-Imp 12 βY*ΔY*-βYΔY 2.9% 6.4% 0.2% 1.4% 13 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 14 βDCΔDC -13% 0% -29% -11% 15 βGFΔGF -3.6% -1.1% -1.9% -7.2% GDP 16 βwsΔWS 0.2% 0.1% 1.5% 0.2% 17 βDCΔDC -13.6% 0.3% -44.9% -17.3% 18 βFΔF -4.2% -1.6% -4.4% -16.7% Notes: The coefficients correspond to FD estimator in tables (2) to (5). βFΔF = βGFΔGF+βDHΔDH y βDCΔDC = βEXΔEX+βRULCΔRULC+βEXPOΔEXPO. Table 8 Descriptive statistics Variable N Mean SD Min Max Unit Y 1365 1005.99 2142.31 4.69 17856.48 Billions (USD) C 1365 581.19 1359.78 2.39 12388.55 Billions (USD) I 1365 282.62 791.74 0.67 12388.55 Billions (USD) X 1365 213.69 346.55 0.46 2626.65 Billions (USD) M 1365 209.77 374.07 1.26 3203.78 Billions (USD) Y* 1365 35190.46 16933.20 17379.22 82709.21 Billions (USD) WS 1365 0.57 0.09 0.31 0.76 %GDP r 1301 0.27 3.42 -0.98 93.94 % DH 1360 91.76 63.34 10.51 347.48 %GDP RER 1361 101.50 78.94 12.41 512.90 2010=100 GF 1365 2.66 3.91 0.16 33.06 %GDP EX 1365 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.86 % capital stock EXPO 1321 0.11 0.09 0.01 0.39 Ratio RULC 1363 0.13 0.12 0.02 1.13 According to USA Table 9 Unit root test Variable Im, Pesaran and Shin1 Fisher ADF2 Fisher Phillips and Perron3 >I(d) no trend trend no trend trend no trend trend Y 1.0000 0.6693 1.0000 0.3585 1.0000 0.9584 I(1) WS 0.7885 0.5955 0.4857 0.4858 0.6258 0.6125 I(1) Y* 0.6325 1.0000 0.8965 1.0000 0.9325 1.0000 I(1) C 1.0000 0.2854 1.0000 0.2587 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) I 1.0000 0.8172 0.9999 0.1125 1.0000 0.8752 I(1) X 0.9991 0.9658 0.9999 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) M 1.0000 0.2158 1.0000 0.1115 1.0000 0.1984 I(1) RER 0.0000 0.0021 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0761 I(0) r 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) RULC 0.9586 0.9589 0.9586 0.9548 0.9518 0.9651 I(1) EX 0.4586 0.9436 0.8651 0.9961 0.6351 0.9993 I(1) EXPO 0.5358 0.6151 0.6583 0.9932 0.8591 1.0000 I(1) GF 0.1412 0.1506 0.2731 0.9542 0.1452 0.6702 I(1) DH 0.3521 0.1358 0.5326 0.4891 0.6531 0.8641 I(1) ΔY 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔWS 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔY* 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔI 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRER 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Δr 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRULC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEXPO 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔGF 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔDH 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Notes": he tests are performed on the logarithmic transformation of the variables, except in the case of the real interest rate. 1. H0: all panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary. The table shows the p-value of the W-t-bar statistic. 2. H0: the panels contain unit roots; H1: at least one panel is stationary. The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). 3. H0: ll panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary.The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). Estimates run using STATA 15. ). It is based on the first difference estimator of the aggregate demand components. As in Stockhammer and Wildauer (2016Stockhammer, E. and Wildauer, R. (2016). Debt-driven growth? Wealth, distribution and demand in OECD countries, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 40, no. 6, 1609-1634), the marginal effect of an increase in the wage share has been calculated as follows:

d Y d W s * 1 Y = β c , w s θ C Y 1 θ W S + β i , w s θ I Y 1 θ W S + β x , w s θ X Y 1 θ W S + β m , w s θ M Y 1 θ W S (6)

where β j,ws with j = c, i, x, m c,ws , is the estimated elasticity of consumption, investment, exports and imports respectively, with respect to wage share, and is a weighting factor based on the income share of country i in the world income. In this way, β j ,Y together with j = c, i, x, m c,ws , represent the income weighted average of the ratio of consumption, investment, exports and imports to GDP respectively, and similarly, θWS represents the income weighted average of the wage share. The effect of an increase of one percentage point on the wage share is shown separately for consumption, investment and net exports of imports. Then, the effect on aggregate demand is calculated as the sum of the latter.

In the case of the whole panel, we have found a demand regime led by wages, since an increase of one percentage point in the wage share has a positive effect on the final demand. As expected, this result persists in the central countries but not in the peripheral and semi-peripheral countries. This result is in line with the findings of other research, for example Onaran and Galanis (2014Onaran, Ö. and Galanis, G. (2014). Income distribution and growth: a global model, Environment and Planning A, vol. 46, no. 10, 2489-2513), who have found wage-led regimes in European OECD countries and profit-led regimes in peripheral economies.

In peripheral and semi-peripheral countries, where demand is led by profits, we have found a negative effect of an increase of one percentage point of the wage share on investment. Also, we have found that the effect on net exports of imports is higher (in absolute value) in peripheral and semi-peripheral countries than in the center. These results are in line with a major importance of primary products in these countries’ exports and with levels of foreignization which are not related with financial activity or financialization.

In addition, we can observe to what extent explanatory variables, especially those linked to global dependence and the financialization process can account for the changes in consumption and investment in the 2010-2018 period. The results are shown for the complete panel and for the three groups of countries classified as center, periphery and semi-periphery. In the observed period, consumption and investment grew more in the peripheries than in the center, as can be observed. On another hand, we can observe the growth of consumption, investment and net exports respectively, which are not explained for the growth of product. In the case of investment, we find that the expansion in the gross capital formation is explained mainly by the economic growth (as it was to be expected in a recovering worldwide economy). In the case of net exports, the growth which is not explained by the product is positive in all cases, although it is significantly higher in the case of central countries6 6 For more details, see Table 6 in the Appendix. .

Changes in the wage share do not explain a significant part of the growth of the components of the aggregate demand. In every case, the contributions to the growth are inferior to 1% in absolute value. Inasmuch as the wage share has a negative variation in the peripheries and a positive one in the center during the analyzed period, the contributions about consumption and investment show the opposite sign to the one found for the elasticities in consumption and investment. In relation to the variables that give an account of dependent conditions, the contribution of the foreignization to growth consumption, investment and net exports in peripheral countries is negative, while it has not been relevant for central countries in the analyzed period. At the same time, the unitary relative labor costs do not explain the growth of the net exports in the center, although they have had a negative contribution in the peripheral countries (greater effect in absolute value in the periphery with respect to the semi-periphery).

The relation between agricultural value added and the manufacturing value added contained in the exports brought a positive contribution in the center and in the semi-periphery (although highly lower in the last), but the contribution in the periphery resulted to be negative. Finally, in relation to the variables linked to the process of financialization of the economies, we find that the debt in the households had a positive contribution to the growth of consumption in the center (3%), while in the peripheries it did not contribute to the growth of this component of the aggregate demand. Financial globalization (measured by the sum of external assets and liabilities in relation to the GDP) contributed negatively in investment and in net exports, both in peripheral countries and in central ones, but it does not explain the growth in consumption in the former7 7 Contributions to growth of wage share, variables linked to the dependency in the peripheries and variables associated to the financialization can be seen in Table 7 in the Appendix in rows 16, 17, 18; and they also summarize what has been previously described. .

These results illustrate that the considered variables (foreignization, positions in international commerce, relative unit labor costs, debt and financial globalization) can explain the different performances among the groups of countries.

5. CONCLUDING REMARKS

In this job we analyzed the role of functional income distribution, the financialization and the structural conditions of dependency in consumption, investment and foreign trade (exports and imports). In the econometric analysis we incorporated 35 countries, central and peripheral from different world regions, with data for the period 1980-2018. Among the results found, we highlight the existence of a statistically significant and robust relation of the participation of wages in the national income about consumption, investment and exports and imports. Qualitatively, we find differences among the countries in the center and the peripheries, especially in the case of investment. While an increment of the participation of wages in the income has a slightly negative effect on the investment of central countries, for the peripheral and semi-peripheral ones, the magnitude of this effect is sensitively stronger.

In relation to the financialization of consumption, approximated by the household debt, we find positive and statistically significant effects just for the case of central countries; in the periphery, this variable does not result to be relevant (statistically speaking) to explain consumption. On its part, the financialization indicator measured as the sum of external assets and liabilities in relation to the PBI reveals a negative and statistically significant effect on consumption, investment and exports. The size of the effect seems to be higher in absolute terms in peripheral countries than in central ones.

The main contribution of the text was aimed to top up these results in relation to the structural differential conditions of the economies of the center, the periphery and the semi-periphery. As it has been shown throughout the text, the results are sensitive to the conditions of international insertion of the countries in terms of the positions in the global value chains and the levels of foreignization of the economies. We have not found conclusive results as regards differentials in the relative unit labor costs (competitiveness indicator). We consider that this study is a contribution to differentiate the growth regimes not only for the income distribution and financialization, but also to have consideration about the power asymmetry within the global capitalist order.

REFERENCES

  • Amin, S. (1988) . L’Accumulation à l’échelle mondiale: préface à la nouvelle édition.
  • Anderson, T. W. and Hsiao, C. (1982). Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using panel data, Journal of econometrics, vol. 18, no. 1, 47-82
  • Arellano, M. and Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations, The review of economic studies, vol. 58, no. 2, 277-297
  • Arrighi, G. (1994). The long twentieth century: Money, power, and the origins of our times, verso.
  • Bhaduri, A. and Marglin, S. (1990.) Unemployment and the real wage: the economic basis for contesting political ideologies, Cambridge Journal of Economics, vol. 14, no. 4, 375-393
  • Bizberg, I. (2018) Varieties of capitalism, growth and redistribution in Asia and Latin America, Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, vol. 38, no. 2, 261-279
  • Blecker, R. (2002). Distribution, demand and growth in neo-Kaleckian macro-models, Chapters, Advance Access published 2002
  • Blecker, R. A. (2016). Wage-led versus profit-led demand regimes: the long and the short of it, Review of Keynesian Economics, vol. 4, no. 4, 373-390
  • Cardoso, F. H. and Faletto, E. (1979). Dependency and development in Latin America (Dependencia y desarrollo en América Latina, engl.), Univ of California Press
  • Choi, I. (2001). Unit root tests for panel data, Journal of international money and Finance, vol. 20, no. 2, 249-272
  • Cueva, A. (1998). El desarrollo del capitalismo en América Latina: ensayo de interpretación histórica, Siglo XXI
  • De Oliveira G and Sousa E (2021) Wage-led and profit-led growth regimes: a panel data approach, Review of Keynesian Economics vol. 9 Issue 3, p394-412.
  • Diamand, M. (1972). La estructura productiva desequilibrada argentina y el tipo de cambio, Desarrollo económico, vol. 12, no. 45, 25-47
  • Fernández, V. R. and Trevignani, M. F. (2015). Cadeias Globais de Valor e Desenvolvimento: Perspectivas Críticas do Sul Global, Dados, vol. 58, no. 2, 499-536
  • Frieden, J. A. (2007). Global capitalism: Its fall and rise in the twentieth century, WW Norton & Company
  • Gaggero, A., Schorr, M., and Wainer, A. (2014). Restricción eterna: el poder económico durante el kirchnerismo, Futuro Anterior
  • Hartwig, J. (2014). Testing the Bhaduri-Marglin model with OECD panel data, International Review of Applied Economics, vol. 28, no. 4, 419-435
  • Harvey, D. (2007). Breve historia del neoliberalismo, Ediciones Akal
  • Hein, E. (2012). Finance-dominated capitalism, re-distribution, household debt and financial fragility in a Kaleckian distribution and growth model, PSL Quarterly Review, vol. 65, no. 260, 11-51
  • Hein, E. (2014). Distribution and growth after Keynes: A Post-Keynesian guide, Edward Elgar Publishing
  • Im, K. S., Pesaran, M. H., and Shin, Y. (2003). Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels, Journal of econometrics , vol. 115, no. 1, 53-74
  • Kiefer, D. and Rada, C. 2015. Profit maximising goes global: the race to the bottom, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 39, no. 5, 1333-1350.
  • Lopez, E. and Barrera Insua, F. (2018). The deep inheritance of dependency. Extraordinary profits and capitalist competition in Argentina (2002-2015), América Latina Hoy-Revista de Ciencias Sociales, vol. 80, 119-141
  • López, E. and Barrera Insua, F. (2019). The Specific Conditions of the Valorization of Capital in a Dependent Nation: The Case of Argentina (2002-2014), Review of Radical Political Economics, vol. 51, no. 1, 75-94
  • Marglin, S. A. and Schor, J. B. (1991). The golden age of capitalism: reinterpreting the postwar experience, Oxford University Press
  • Marini, R. M. (1972). Dialéctica de la dependencia: la economía exportadora, Sociedad y desarrollo, vol. 1, 35-52
  • Marini, R. M. (2007). Proceso y tendencias de la globalización capitalista y otros textos (Antología), Prometeo Libros Editorial
  • Milberg, W. & Winkler, D. (2013). Outsourcing Economics. Global Value Chains in Capitalist Development, Cambridge University Press.
  • Onaran, Ö. (2011). Globalisation, macroeconomic performance and distribution, A Modern Guide to Keynesian Macroeconomics and Economic Policies, 240
  • Onaran, Ö. and Galanis, G. (2014). Income distribution and growth: a global model, Environment and Planning A, vol. 46, no. 10, 2489-2513
  • Onaran, Ö., Stockhammer, E., and Grafl, L. (2011). Financialisation, income distribution and aggregate demand in the USA, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 35, no. 4, 637-661
  • Pinto, A. (1973). Heterogeneidad estructural y modelo de desarrollo reciente de la América Latina, CEPAL
  • Prebisch, R. (1986). El desarrollo económico de la América Latina y algunos de sus principales problemas, Desarrollo económico, 479-502
  • Roodman, D. (2009). A note on the theme of too many instruments, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and statistics, vol. 71, no. 1, 135-158
  • Rosenmann, M. R. (2008). Pensar América Latina: el desarrollo de la sociología latinoamericana, Clacso
  • Rostow, W. W. (1960). The stages of growth: A non-communist manifesto, Cambridge University Press
  • Skott, P. (1989). Effective demand, class struggle and cyclical growth, International Economic Review, 231-247
  • Stockhammer, E. and Wildauer, R. (2016). Debt-driven growth? Wealth, distribution and demand in OECD countries, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 40, no. 6, 1609-1634
  • Thompson, S. (2018). Profit squeeze in the Duménil and Lévy model, Review of Radical Political Economics , vol. 50, no. 2, 297-316
  • Wallerstein, I. (1974). The rise and future demise of the world capitalist system: Concepts for comparative analysis, Comparative studies in society and history, vol. 16, no. 4, 387-415
  • Yang, C. (2016). Relocating labour-intensive manufacturing firms from China to Southeast Asia: a preliminary investigation, Bandung, vol. 3, no. 1, 1-13
  • 1
    Some exceptions to highlight are Onaran et al. (2011Onaran, Ö., Stockhammer, E., and Grafl, L. (2011). Financialisation, income distribution and aggregate demand in the USA, Cambridge Journal of Economics , vol. 35, no. 4, 637-661) and Onaran and Galanis (2014Onaran, Ö. and Galanis, G. (2014). Income distribution and growth: a global model, Environment and Planning A, vol. 46, no. 10, 2489-2513). However, none of these works take into consideration the structural characteristics of peripheral countries, which we consider relevant in this article.
  • 2
    This concept refers to the increasing weight of international capital in domestic economies. This Spanish concept does not possess an exact translation in English.
  • 3
    Naturally, by comparing the peripheries, we find that in the countries of Asia the contribution of manufacturing exports in value added is predominant as opposed to Latin American countries. In any case, the key point here is that while most of the central countries have balanced export contributions to the value of both branches, the peripheral and semi-peripheral countries have an imbalance due to the international division of labor that has not been substantially modified, with the exception of China.
  • 4
    The countries included in the empirical study are: Central: Australia, Austria, Canada, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland, England, United States. Semi-periphery: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, India, Malaysia, Mexico, South Korea, South Africa, Thailand. Periphery: Bolivia, Colombia, Costa Rica, Ecuador, Honduras, Nicaragua, Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay, Venezuela.
  • 5
    One issue to take into account is that there may be common shocks across countries and differential impacts of these shocks that are not discriminated in this model from those shocks specific to the countries. However, we consider that, given that the estimators we use control for autoregression adequately, this does not represent major problems for the specification strategy of the model.
  • 6
    For more details, see Table 6 in the Appendix Appendix Table 2 Results for consumption function Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnCt-1 0.761*** 0.743*** 0.777*** 0.716*** 0.790*** 0.656*** (0.059) (0.055) (0.060) (0.083) (0.054) (0.088) lnY 0.731*** 0.581*** 0.501*** 0.721*** 0.541*** 0.556** 0.844*** 0.601*** 0.599*** (0.016) (0.068) (0.059) (0.028) (0.063) (0.110) (0.019) (0.064) (0.098) lnWS 0.116** 0.132** 0.098* 0.171*** 0.193** 0.126* 0.086** 0.080** 0.076** (0.014) (0.042) (0.041) (0.032) (0.061) (0.063) (0.012) (0.037) (0.051) lnGF -0.017*** -0.036*** -0.015* -0.007** -0.021*** -0.016* -0.025*** -0.039** -0.053 (0.004) (0.007) (0.009) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) (0.036) lnDH 0.095** 0.017** 0.012 0.126*** 0.096** 0.091* 0.036 0.028 0.012 (0.091) (0.126) (0.031) (0.091) (0.032) (0.063) (0.096) (0.098) (0.089) lnEX 0.018** 0.014** 0.013* 0.009** 0.007** 0.016** -0.015** -0.011* -0.090 (0.008) (0.012) (0.016) (0.003) (0.004) (0.015) (0.006) (0.009) (0.072) Observations 1,360 1,360 1,360 741 741 741 619 619 619 R-squared 0.899 0.796 0.778 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.106 0.103 0.098 0.091 0.096 0.090 Hansen p-value 0.133 0.121 0.109 0.106 0.101 0.097 AR (2) p-value 0.496 0.493 0.401 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 3 Results for investment function Investment Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnIt-1 0.866*** 0.892*** 0.829*** 0.876*** 0.889*** 0.791* (0.023) (0.057) (0.036) (0.059) (0.062) (0.101) lnY 1.991*** 1.969*** 2.041*** 1.872*** 1.998*** 2.020*** 1.983*** 2.057*** 2.051** (0.176) (0.192) (0.116) (0.118) (0.148) (0.214) (0.101) (0.173) (0.142) lnWS -0.135*** -0.126** -0.150** -0.048** -0.073*** -0.041* -0.188*** -0.189** -0.192** (0.064) (0.032) (0.059) (0.016) (0.023) (0.015) (0.073) (0.041) (0.043) r -0.185** -0.123** -0.112* -0.308*** -0.213** -0.206* -0.086** -0.081* 0.077 (0.051) (0.059) (0.063) (0.098) (0.086) (0.079) (0.046) (0.039) (0.041) lnGF -0.216** -0.150** -0.132* -0.153*** -0.131*** -0.128 -0.231*** -0.193* -0.281* (0.051) (0.029) (0.026) (0.089) (0.016) (0.061) (0.071) (0.066) (0.142) lnEX -0.026** -0.013** -0.012* -0.006* -0.002 0.057 -0.133*** -0.101** 0.178* (0.016) (0.011) (0.012) (0.003) (0.004) (0.068) (0.013) (0.013) (0.136) Observations 1,301 1,301 1,301 703 703 703 598 598 598 R-squared 0.894 0.691 0.663 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.331 0.279 0.297 0.209 0.203 0.111 Hansen p-value 0.312 0.261 0.241 0.201 0.211 0.119 AR (2) p-value 0.626 0.412 0.351 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 4 Results for exports function Exports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnXt-1 0.929*** 0.916*** 0.842*** 0.831*** 0.928*** 0.890** (0.132) (0.101) (0.106) (0.116) (0.099) (0.114) lnY* 1.531*** 1.691*** 1.706*** 1.791*** 2.091*** 1.854** 1.571*** 2.003*** 1.321** (0.119) (0.142) (0.151) (0.115) (0.203) (0.239) (0.126) (0.187) (0.198) lnWS -0.058** -0.079*** -0.099 -0.033* -0.051* -0.076 -0.081** -0.092** -0.109 (0.019) (0.042) (0.051) (0.017) (0.029) (0.061) (0.041) (0.053) (0.106) lnRER -0.088** -0.121** -0.139** -0.131*** -0.199*** -0.131 -0.049** -0.029** -0.012 (0.026) (0.069) (0.096) (0.052) (0.066) (0.105) (0.028) (0.016) (0.011) lnGF -0.041** -0.052** 0.058* -0.016** -0.026** -0.015 -0.036** -0.038** -0.097 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) (0.011) (0.017) (0.013) (0.021) (0.016) (0.068) lnEX 0.029* -0.053 -0.028 0.009 0.006 -0.016 0.097** 0.099** 0.083 (0.018) (0.019) (0.016) (0.005) (0.005) (0.013) (0.039) (0.055) (0.067) lnRULC -0.098** -0.064* -0.100 -0.044* -0.036 -0.038 -0.088** 0.067** 0.059** (0.043) (0.033) (0.081) (0.036) (0.031) (0.027) (0.044) (0.026) (0.042) lnEXPO 0.285*** 0.193*** 0.096 0.186*** 0.171*** 0.169 0.316*** 0.221*** 0.249* (0.127) (0.109) (0.091) (0.117) (0.107) (0.128) (0.291) (0.106) (0.196) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.786 0.771 0.693 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.291 0.219 0.171 0.148 0.098 0.089 Hansen p-value 0.319 0.299 0.197 0.192 0.108 0.107 AR (2) p-value 0.172 0.140 0.136 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 5 Results for imports function Imports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnMt-1 0.696*** 0.687*** 0.519*** 0.521** 0.526*** 0.618** (0.129) (0.188) (0.138) (0.191) (0.103) (0.189) lnY 1.421*** 1.462*** 1.398** 1.283*** 1.276*** 1.142** 1.531*** 1.479*** 1.387** (0.123) (0.129) (0.201) (0.074) (0.101) (0.266) (0.144) (0.101) (0.222) lnWS 0.066** 0.083* 0.081 0.033** 0.049* 0.043 0.097** 0.099** 0.112* (0.045) (0.041) (0.059) (0.017) (0.027) (0.019) (0.031) (0.091) (0.109) lnRER 0.078*** 0.069** 0.083 0.091** 0.077** -0.070* 0.040*** 0.038* 0.051 (0.033) (0.066) (0.071) (0.032) (0.069) (0.063) (0.029) (0.028) (0.042) lnGF 0.139*** 0.083** 0.089 0.031** 0.017** 0.020 0.159*** 0.133* 0.126** (0.063) (0.051) (0.079) (0.012) (0.015) (0.019) (0.099) (0.118) (0.101) lnEX 0.215** 0.206** 0.212** 0.116* 0.103** 0.103 0.329** 0.317*** 0.323** (0.101) (0.104) (0.101) (0.071) (0.096) (0.077) (0.097) (0.081) (0.116) lnRULC 0.091* 0.076* 0.071 0.039* 0.051 0.069 0.088* 0.081* 0.096 (0.081) (0.043) (0.069) (0.031) (0.043) (0.067) (0.077) (0.069) (0.091) lnEXPO 0.326*** 0.314*** 0.269** 0.139*** 0.121** 0.136** 0.346*** 0.363*** 0.301** (0.106) (0.103) (0.128) (0.118) (0.102) (0.117) (0.109) (0.191) (0.116) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.823 0.813 0.745 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.099 0.086 0.073 0.058 0.061 0.042 Hansen p-value 0.088 0.073 0.068 0.070 0.065 0.059 AR (2) p-value 0.149 0.139 0.121 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 6 Marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in wage share on excess final demand Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery C 0.106 0.158 0.104 0.054 I -0.049 -0.016 -0.071 -0.102 X+M -0.039 -0.020 -0.057 -0.076 Y 0.018 0.122 -0.024 -0.123 Financialization 274% 352% 107% 121% Foreignization 8% 9% 6% 2% RULC 13% 26% 8% 12% VAag/VAind 10% 5% 24% 4% Notes: The calculations of the effects on the final demand are based on the FD estimators, averages 1980-2018. The elasticities were transformed to marginal effects using the participation in the GDP as a weight. The average financialization of the semi-periphery excludes China. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 7 Growth contributions Change 2010-2018 Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery Aggregate 1 ΔC 26% 14% 30% 52% 2 ΔI 27% 13% 5% 35% Δ(X-M) -29% -51% -13% -7% 3 ΔY 26% 17% 29% 45% Consumption 4 ΔC-βYΔY 7% 1% 6% 14% 5 βwsΔWS -0.2% 0.2% -0.5% -0.1% 6 βEXΔEX 0.9% 0.1% -1.6% -0.6% 7 βFΔF 3.7% 3.1% -0.2% -0.9% Investment 8 ΔI-βYΔY-βrΔr -25% -20% -52% -54% 9 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 10 βEXΔEX -1.3% 0.0% -14.1% -5.4% 11 βGFΔGF -4.3% -3.6% -2.2% -8.6% Expo-Imp 12 βY*ΔY*-βYΔY 2.9% 6.4% 0.2% 1.4% 13 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 14 βDCΔDC -13% 0% -29% -11% 15 βGFΔGF -3.6% -1.1% -1.9% -7.2% GDP 16 βwsΔWS 0.2% 0.1% 1.5% 0.2% 17 βDCΔDC -13.6% 0.3% -44.9% -17.3% 18 βFΔF -4.2% -1.6% -4.4% -16.7% Notes: The coefficients correspond to FD estimator in tables (2) to (5). βFΔF = βGFΔGF+βDHΔDH y βDCΔDC = βEXΔEX+βRULCΔRULC+βEXPOΔEXPO. Table 8 Descriptive statistics Variable N Mean SD Min Max Unit Y 1365 1005.99 2142.31 4.69 17856.48 Billions (USD) C 1365 581.19 1359.78 2.39 12388.55 Billions (USD) I 1365 282.62 791.74 0.67 12388.55 Billions (USD) X 1365 213.69 346.55 0.46 2626.65 Billions (USD) M 1365 209.77 374.07 1.26 3203.78 Billions (USD) Y* 1365 35190.46 16933.20 17379.22 82709.21 Billions (USD) WS 1365 0.57 0.09 0.31 0.76 %GDP r 1301 0.27 3.42 -0.98 93.94 % DH 1360 91.76 63.34 10.51 347.48 %GDP RER 1361 101.50 78.94 12.41 512.90 2010=100 GF 1365 2.66 3.91 0.16 33.06 %GDP EX 1365 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.86 % capital stock EXPO 1321 0.11 0.09 0.01 0.39 Ratio RULC 1363 0.13 0.12 0.02 1.13 According to USA Table 9 Unit root test Variable Im, Pesaran and Shin1 Fisher ADF2 Fisher Phillips and Perron3 >I(d) no trend trend no trend trend no trend trend Y 1.0000 0.6693 1.0000 0.3585 1.0000 0.9584 I(1) WS 0.7885 0.5955 0.4857 0.4858 0.6258 0.6125 I(1) Y* 0.6325 1.0000 0.8965 1.0000 0.9325 1.0000 I(1) C 1.0000 0.2854 1.0000 0.2587 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) I 1.0000 0.8172 0.9999 0.1125 1.0000 0.8752 I(1) X 0.9991 0.9658 0.9999 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) M 1.0000 0.2158 1.0000 0.1115 1.0000 0.1984 I(1) RER 0.0000 0.0021 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0761 I(0) r 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) RULC 0.9586 0.9589 0.9586 0.9548 0.9518 0.9651 I(1) EX 0.4586 0.9436 0.8651 0.9961 0.6351 0.9993 I(1) EXPO 0.5358 0.6151 0.6583 0.9932 0.8591 1.0000 I(1) GF 0.1412 0.1506 0.2731 0.9542 0.1452 0.6702 I(1) DH 0.3521 0.1358 0.5326 0.4891 0.6531 0.8641 I(1) ΔY 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔWS 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔY* 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔI 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRER 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Δr 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRULC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEXPO 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔGF 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔDH 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Notes": he tests are performed on the logarithmic transformation of the variables, except in the case of the real interest rate. 1. H0: all panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary. The table shows the p-value of the W-t-bar statistic. 2. H0: the panels contain unit roots; H1: at least one panel is stationary. The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). 3. H0: ll panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary.The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). Estimates run using STATA 15. .
  • 7
    Contributions to growth of wage share, variables linked to the dependency in the peripheries and variables associated to the financialization can be seen in Table 7 in the Appendix Appendix Table 2 Results for consumption function Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnCt-1 0.761*** 0.743*** 0.777*** 0.716*** 0.790*** 0.656*** (0.059) (0.055) (0.060) (0.083) (0.054) (0.088) lnY 0.731*** 0.581*** 0.501*** 0.721*** 0.541*** 0.556** 0.844*** 0.601*** 0.599*** (0.016) (0.068) (0.059) (0.028) (0.063) (0.110) (0.019) (0.064) (0.098) lnWS 0.116** 0.132** 0.098* 0.171*** 0.193** 0.126* 0.086** 0.080** 0.076** (0.014) (0.042) (0.041) (0.032) (0.061) (0.063) (0.012) (0.037) (0.051) lnGF -0.017*** -0.036*** -0.015* -0.007** -0.021*** -0.016* -0.025*** -0.039** -0.053 (0.004) (0.007) (0.009) (0.006) (0.004) (0.008) (0.008) (0.015) (0.036) lnDH 0.095** 0.017** 0.012 0.126*** 0.096** 0.091* 0.036 0.028 0.012 (0.091) (0.126) (0.031) (0.091) (0.032) (0.063) (0.096) (0.098) (0.089) lnEX 0.018** 0.014** 0.013* 0.009** 0.007** 0.016** -0.015** -0.011* -0.090 (0.008) (0.012) (0.016) (0.003) (0.004) (0.015) (0.006) (0.009) (0.072) Observations 1,360 1,360 1,360 741 741 741 619 619 619 R-squared 0.899 0.796 0.778 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.106 0.103 0.098 0.091 0.096 0.090 Hansen p-value 0.133 0.121 0.109 0.106 0.101 0.097 AR (2) p-value 0.496 0.493 0.401 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 3 Results for investment function Investment Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnIt-1 0.866*** 0.892*** 0.829*** 0.876*** 0.889*** 0.791* (0.023) (0.057) (0.036) (0.059) (0.062) (0.101) lnY 1.991*** 1.969*** 2.041*** 1.872*** 1.998*** 2.020*** 1.983*** 2.057*** 2.051** (0.176) (0.192) (0.116) (0.118) (0.148) (0.214) (0.101) (0.173) (0.142) lnWS -0.135*** -0.126** -0.150** -0.048** -0.073*** -0.041* -0.188*** -0.189** -0.192** (0.064) (0.032) (0.059) (0.016) (0.023) (0.015) (0.073) (0.041) (0.043) r -0.185** -0.123** -0.112* -0.308*** -0.213** -0.206* -0.086** -0.081* 0.077 (0.051) (0.059) (0.063) (0.098) (0.086) (0.079) (0.046) (0.039) (0.041) lnGF -0.216** -0.150** -0.132* -0.153*** -0.131*** -0.128 -0.231*** -0.193* -0.281* (0.051) (0.029) (0.026) (0.089) (0.016) (0.061) (0.071) (0.066) (0.142) lnEX -0.026** -0.013** -0.012* -0.006* -0.002 0.057 -0.133*** -0.101** 0.178* (0.016) (0.011) (0.012) (0.003) (0.004) (0.068) (0.013) (0.013) (0.136) Observations 1,301 1,301 1,301 703 703 703 598 598 598 R-squared 0.894 0.691 0.663 Number of id 35 35 19 19 16 16 Sargan p-value 0.331 0.279 0.297 0.209 0.203 0.111 Hansen p-value 0.312 0.261 0.241 0.201 0.211 0.119 AR (2) p-value 0.626 0.412 0.351 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 4 Results for exports function Exports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnXt-1 0.929*** 0.916*** 0.842*** 0.831*** 0.928*** 0.890** (0.132) (0.101) (0.106) (0.116) (0.099) (0.114) lnY* 1.531*** 1.691*** 1.706*** 1.791*** 2.091*** 1.854** 1.571*** 2.003*** 1.321** (0.119) (0.142) (0.151) (0.115) (0.203) (0.239) (0.126) (0.187) (0.198) lnWS -0.058** -0.079*** -0.099 -0.033* -0.051* -0.076 -0.081** -0.092** -0.109 (0.019) (0.042) (0.051) (0.017) (0.029) (0.061) (0.041) (0.053) (0.106) lnRER -0.088** -0.121** -0.139** -0.131*** -0.199*** -0.131 -0.049** -0.029** -0.012 (0.026) (0.069) (0.096) (0.052) (0.066) (0.105) (0.028) (0.016) (0.011) lnGF -0.041** -0.052** 0.058* -0.016** -0.026** -0.015 -0.036** -0.038** -0.097 (0.016) (0.023) (0.023) (0.011) (0.017) (0.013) (0.021) (0.016) (0.068) lnEX 0.029* -0.053 -0.028 0.009 0.006 -0.016 0.097** 0.099** 0.083 (0.018) (0.019) (0.016) (0.005) (0.005) (0.013) (0.039) (0.055) (0.067) lnRULC -0.098** -0.064* -0.100 -0.044* -0.036 -0.038 -0.088** 0.067** 0.059** (0.043) (0.033) (0.081) (0.036) (0.031) (0.027) (0.044) (0.026) (0.042) lnEXPO 0.285*** 0.193*** 0.096 0.186*** 0.171*** 0.169 0.316*** 0.221*** 0.249* (0.127) (0.109) (0.091) (0.117) (0.107) (0.128) (0.291) (0.106) (0.196) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.786 0.771 0.693 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.291 0.219 0.171 0.148 0.098 0.089 Hansen p-value 0.319 0.299 0.197 0.192 0.108 0.107 AR (2) p-value 0.172 0.140 0.136 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 5 Results for imports function Imports Panel Center Periphery and semi-periphery (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H FD GMM A&H lnMt-1 0.696*** 0.687*** 0.519*** 0.521** 0.526*** 0.618** (0.129) (0.188) (0.138) (0.191) (0.103) (0.189) lnY 1.421*** 1.462*** 1.398** 1.283*** 1.276*** 1.142** 1.531*** 1.479*** 1.387** (0.123) (0.129) (0.201) (0.074) (0.101) (0.266) (0.144) (0.101) (0.222) lnWS 0.066** 0.083* 0.081 0.033** 0.049* 0.043 0.097** 0.099** 0.112* (0.045) (0.041) (0.059) (0.017) (0.027) (0.019) (0.031) (0.091) (0.109) lnRER 0.078*** 0.069** 0.083 0.091** 0.077** -0.070* 0.040*** 0.038* 0.051 (0.033) (0.066) (0.071) (0.032) (0.069) (0.063) (0.029) (0.028) (0.042) lnGF 0.139*** 0.083** 0.089 0.031** 0.017** 0.020 0.159*** 0.133* 0.126** (0.063) (0.051) (0.079) (0.012) (0.015) (0.019) (0.099) (0.118) (0.101) lnEX 0.215** 0.206** 0.212** 0.116* 0.103** 0.103 0.329** 0.317*** 0.323** (0.101) (0.104) (0.101) (0.071) (0.096) (0.077) (0.097) (0.081) (0.116) lnRULC 0.091* 0.076* 0.071 0.039* 0.051 0.069 0.088* 0.081* 0.096 (0.081) (0.043) (0.069) (0.031) (0.043) (0.067) (0.077) (0.069) (0.091) lnEXPO 0.326*** 0.314*** 0.269** 0.139*** 0.121** 0.136** 0.346*** 0.363*** 0.301** (0.106) (0.103) (0.128) (0.118) (0.102) (0.117) (0.109) (0.191) (0.116) Observations 1,321 1,321 1,321 745 745 745 576 576 576 R-squared 0.823 0.813 0.745 Number of id 34 34 19 19 15 15 Sargan p-value 0.099 0.086 0.073 0.058 0.061 0.042 Hansen p-value 0.088 0.073 0.068 0.070 0.065 0.059 AR (2) p-value 0.149 0.139 0.121 Notes: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation robust standard errors in parentheses. Venezuela was omitted from the calculation since there is no information on GVC. FD refers to the first difference estimator, GMM to the Arellano and Bond (1991) estimator and A&H is the Anderson and Hsiao (1981, 1982) estimator. Sargan and Hansen are two tests for overidentification and AR (2) is the autocorrelation Arellano and Bond (1991) test. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 6 Marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in wage share on excess final demand Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery C 0.106 0.158 0.104 0.054 I -0.049 -0.016 -0.071 -0.102 X+M -0.039 -0.020 -0.057 -0.076 Y 0.018 0.122 -0.024 -0.123 Financialization 274% 352% 107% 121% Foreignization 8% 9% 6% 2% RULC 13% 26% 8% 12% VAag/VAind 10% 5% 24% 4% Notes: The calculations of the effects on the final demand are based on the FD estimators, averages 1980-2018. The elasticities were transformed to marginal effects using the participation in the GDP as a weight. The average financialization of the semi-periphery excludes China. Estimates run using STATA 15. Table 7 Growth contributions Change 2010-2018 Panel Center Periphery Semi-periphery Aggregate 1 ΔC 26% 14% 30% 52% 2 ΔI 27% 13% 5% 35% Δ(X-M) -29% -51% -13% -7% 3 ΔY 26% 17% 29% 45% Consumption 4 ΔC-βYΔY 7% 1% 6% 14% 5 βwsΔWS -0.2% 0.2% -0.5% -0.1% 6 βEXΔEX 0.9% 0.1% -1.6% -0.6% 7 βFΔF 3.7% 3.1% -0.2% -0.9% Investment 8 ΔI-βYΔY-βrΔr -25% -20% -52% -54% 9 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 10 βEXΔEX -1.3% 0.0% -14.1% -5.4% 11 βGFΔGF -4.3% -3.6% -2.2% -8.6% Expo-Imp 12 βY*ΔY*-βYΔY 2.9% 6.4% 0.2% 1.4% 13 βwsΔWS 0.2% -0.1% 1.0% 0.1% 14 βDCΔDC -13% 0% -29% -11% 15 βGFΔGF -3.6% -1.1% -1.9% -7.2% GDP 16 βwsΔWS 0.2% 0.1% 1.5% 0.2% 17 βDCΔDC -13.6% 0.3% -44.9% -17.3% 18 βFΔF -4.2% -1.6% -4.4% -16.7% Notes: The coefficients correspond to FD estimator in tables (2) to (5). βFΔF = βGFΔGF+βDHΔDH y βDCΔDC = βEXΔEX+βRULCΔRULC+βEXPOΔEXPO. Table 8 Descriptive statistics Variable N Mean SD Min Max Unit Y 1365 1005.99 2142.31 4.69 17856.48 Billions (USD) C 1365 581.19 1359.78 2.39 12388.55 Billions (USD) I 1365 282.62 791.74 0.67 12388.55 Billions (USD) X 1365 213.69 346.55 0.46 2626.65 Billions (USD) M 1365 209.77 374.07 1.26 3203.78 Billions (USD) Y* 1365 35190.46 16933.20 17379.22 82709.21 Billions (USD) WS 1365 0.57 0.09 0.31 0.76 %GDP r 1301 0.27 3.42 -0.98 93.94 % DH 1360 91.76 63.34 10.51 347.48 %GDP RER 1361 101.50 78.94 12.41 512.90 2010=100 GF 1365 2.66 3.91 0.16 33.06 %GDP EX 1365 0.06 0.08 0.00 0.86 % capital stock EXPO 1321 0.11 0.09 0.01 0.39 Ratio RULC 1363 0.13 0.12 0.02 1.13 According to USA Table 9 Unit root test Variable Im, Pesaran and Shin1 Fisher ADF2 Fisher Phillips and Perron3 >I(d) no trend trend no trend trend no trend trend Y 1.0000 0.6693 1.0000 0.3585 1.0000 0.9584 I(1) WS 0.7885 0.5955 0.4857 0.4858 0.6258 0.6125 I(1) Y* 0.6325 1.0000 0.8965 1.0000 0.9325 1.0000 I(1) C 1.0000 0.2854 1.0000 0.2587 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) I 1.0000 0.8172 0.9999 0.1125 1.0000 0.8752 I(1) X 0.9991 0.9658 0.9999 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 I(1) M 1.0000 0.2158 1.0000 0.1115 1.0000 0.1984 I(1) RER 0.0000 0.0021 0.0000 0.0006 0.0000 0.0761 I(0) r 0.0000 0.0000 0.0003 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) RULC 0.9586 0.9589 0.9586 0.9548 0.9518 0.9651 I(1) EX 0.4586 0.9436 0.8651 0.9961 0.6351 0.9993 I(1) EXPO 0.5358 0.6151 0.6583 0.9932 0.8591 1.0000 I(1) GF 0.1412 0.1506 0.2731 0.9542 0.1452 0.6702 I(1) DH 0.3521 0.1358 0.5326 0.4891 0.6531 0.8641 I(1) ΔY 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔWS 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔY* 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔI 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔM 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRER 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Δr 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔRULC 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEX 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔEXPO 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔGF 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) ΔDH 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 I(0) Notes": he tests are performed on the logarithmic transformation of the variables, except in the case of the real interest rate. 1. H0: all panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary. The table shows the p-value of the W-t-bar statistic. 2. H0: the panels contain unit roots; H1: at least one panel is stationary. The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). 3. H0: ll panels contain unit roots; H1: some panels are stationary.The table shows the p-value of the Z statistic (normal inverse). Estimates run using STATA 15. in rows 16, 17, 18; and they also summarize what has been previously described.
  • 8
    JEL Classification: F43; E25; C33.

Appendix

Table 2
Results for consumption function
Table 3
Results for investment function
Table 4
Results for exports function
Table 5
Results for imports function
Table 6
Marginal effect of a one percentage point increase in wage share on excess final demand
Table 7
Growth contributions

Table 8
Descriptive statistics

Table 9
Unit root test

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    07 Aug 2023
  • Date of issue
    Jul-Sep 2023

History

  • Received
    16 Feb 2022
  • Accepted
    24 Oct 2022
Centro de Economia Política Rua Araripina, 106, CEP 05603-030 São Paulo - SP, Tel. (55 11) 3816-6053 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: cecilia.heise@bjpe.org.br