Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Confronting Theories of Firm Growth in Light of Degrees-of-Freedom Analysis

Confrontando Teorias de Crescimento da Firma à Luz da Análise de Graus de Liberdade

Abstracts

This article aims to confront four theories of firm growth – Optimum Firm Size, Stage Theory of Growth, The Theory of the Growth of the Firm and Dynamic Capabilities – with empirical data derived from a backward-looking longitudinal qualitative case of the growth trajectory of a Brazilian capital goods firm. To do so, we employed Degree of Freedom-Analysis for data analysis. This technique aims to test the empirical strengths of competing theories using statistical tests, in particular Chi-square test. Our results suggest that none of the four theories fully explained the growth of the firm we chose as empirical case. Nevertheless, Dynamic Capabilities was regarded as providing a more satisfactory explanatory power.

Firm Growth; Degree of Freedom Analysis; Dynamics Capabilities; Firm Trajectory


Este artigo objetiva confrontar quatro teorias de crescimento da firma – Tamanho Ótimo da Firma, Teoria de Estágio de Crescimento, Teoria de Crescimento da Firma e Capacidades Dinâmicas – com dados empíricos oriundos de um estudo longitudinal da trajetória de crescimento de uma empresa brasileira de bens de capital. Para tanto, nós utilizamos a Análise de Graus de Liberdade para análise de dados. Esta técnica tem como propósito testar a força empírica de teorias rivais utilizando dados estatísticos, especificamente o Teste de Qui-quadrado. Os nossos resultados sugerem que nenhuma das quatro teorias explica totalmente o crescimento da firma escolhida como caso empírico. No entanto, a teoria de Capacidades Dinâmicas foi vista como sendo a que possui o poder de explanação mais satisfatório.

Crescimento da firma; Análise de Graus de Liberdade; Capacidades Dinâmicas; Trajetória da Firma


Introduction

Quite often empirical studies of firm growth come up with some puzzling results. For example, Coad (2007)COAD, A. Testing the principle of ‘growth of the fitter": the relationship between profits and firm growth. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, v. 18, n.3, p. 370-386, 2007. found that growth of profits had no influence on the subsequent growth of employment or sales. Geroski, Lazarova, Urga and Walters (2003, p.55) revealed that firm size followed a random walk (LEVINTHAL, 1997LEVINTHAL, D. Adaptation on rugged landscapes. Management Science, v. 43, n. 7, p. 934-950, 1997.). This means that "[…] firms move[d] more or less randomly, changing their relative size and rank on a regular if unpredictable basis […]". In other words, differences in growth rates between firms were suggested to be transitory. Dosi, Lechevalier and Secchi (2010DOSI, G.; LECHEVALIER, S.; SECCHI, A. Introduction: Interfirm heterogeneity – nature, sources and consequences of industrial dynamics. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 19, n. 6, p. 1867-1890, 2010., p.1867) reminded us about the persistent heterogeneity "[…] in all dimensions of business firms' characteristics and dynamics […]" whereas Serrasqueiro, Nunes, Leitão and Armada (2010)SERRASQUEIRO, Z.; NUNES, P.; LEITÃO, J.; ARMANDA, M. Are there non-linearities between SME growth and its determinants? A quantile approach. Industrial and Corporate Change, v 19, n. 4, p. 1071-1108, 2010. brought nonlinearities between determinants and firm growth to the fore. Yet, Henderson, Raynor and Ahmed (2012)HENDERSON, A.; RAYNOR, M.; AHMED, M. How long must a firm be great to rule out chance? Benchmarking sustained superior performance without being fooled by randomness. Strategic Management Journal, v. 33, n. 4, p. 387-406, 2012. found a degree of support for the notion of imprint on firm growth.

In our view, these results are puzzling because they are at odds with some well- known theories, models and hypotheses on firm growth (COAD, 2009COAD, A. The growth of firms: a survey of theories and empirical evidences. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2009.), in particular those selected by Geroski (1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.) for closer examination: Optimum Firm Size (OFS), Stage Theory of Growth (STG), The Theory of the Growth of the Firm (TGF) and Dynamic Capabilities (DC).

How can we reconcile the hypothesis on random walks (LEVINTHAL, 1997LEVINTHAL, D. Adaptation on rugged landscapes. Management Science, v. 43, n. 7, p. 934-950, 1997.) with Penrose's (1959)PENROSE, E. Foreign investment and the growth of the firm. The Economic Journal, v. 66, n. 262, p. 220-235, 1956. TGF? On the one hand, random walks assume that adjustment costs are fixed whereas TGF suggests they are variable (GEROSKI, 1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.). By the same token, how can we accommodate the existence of nonlinearities between causal factors and firm growth to OFS which claims that a single determinant (price mechanism) sets the limits to firm growth (DEMSETZ, 1991DEMSETZ, H. The theory of the firm revisited. In: WILLIAMSON, O.; WINTER, S. (Ed.). The nature of the firm: origin, evolution and development. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991. p.159-178.)? This idea is also difficult to reconcile with STG theories such as Greiner's (1972)GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972. model that suggest that firms grow in stages or phases. In addition, the concept of imprint has no place in OFS (CONNER, 1991CONNER, K. A historical comparison of Resource-based Theory and five schools of through within Industrial Organization Economics: do we have a new theory of theory? Journal of Management, v. 17, n. 1, p. 121-154, 1991.) even though it is in accordance with DC (TEECE; PISANO; SHUEN, 1997TEECE, D.; PISANO, G.; SHUEN, A. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 18, n. 7, p. 509-533, 1997.).

More broadly, the mismatch between theory and data about firm growth has been spearheaded by Geroski and co-authors for a decade (GEROSKI, 1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.; GEROSKI; MAZZUCATO, 2002GEROSKI, P.; MAZZUCATO, M. Learning and the sources of corporate growth. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 11, n.4, p. 623-644, 2002.; GEROSKI et al., 2003GEROSKI, Paul A. et al. Are differences in firm size transitory or permanent? Journal of Applied Econometrics, v. 18, n. 1, p. 47-59, 2003.; GEROSKI; MATA; PORTUGAL, 2010GEROSKI, P. A.; MATA, J.; PORTUGAL, P. Founding conditions and the survival of new firms. Strategic Management Journal, v. 31, p. 510-529, 2010.). Specifically, Geroski (1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.) carried out a quantitative panel study in order to confront the tenets of the aforementioned theories with empirical data. He found that none of these theories fully explained the growth of the sampled firms. In a similar vein, Geroski, Mata and Portugal (2010) were unable to claim absolute superiority of a particular theory over the others. Interestingly enough, whereas Geroski (1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.) suggests that DC is a more promising theory for unpacking firm growth, Geroski, Mata and Portugal (2010)GEROSKI, P. A.; MATA, J.; PORTUGAL, P. Founding conditions and the survival of new firms. Strategic Management Journal, v. 31, p. 510-529, 2010. imply that a combination of theories is required so as to provide a finer-grained understanding of the growth of the firm.

Geroski's (1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.) contention is the starting point of this piece of research. It aims to confront the four theories of firm growth chosen by the American-born author with empirical data derived from a backward-looking qualitative case of the growth trajectory of a Brazilian capital goods firm. To do so, we built a matrix prediction that confronted the four theories of firm growth mentioned earlier. Subsequently we employed Degrees of Freedom Analysis (DFA) for data analysis. Based on Campbell (1975)CAMPBELL, T. Degrees of freedom and the case study. Comparative Political Studies, v. 8, n. 1, p. 178–193, 1975., this technique aims to test the empirical strengths of competing theories using statistical tests, in particular the Z-test and/or Chi-square test (WILSON; WOODSIDE, 1999WILSON, E.; WOODSIDE, A. Degrees-of-freedom analysis of case data in business marketing research. Industrial Marketing Management, v. 28, n. 3, p. 215–229, 1999.).

Although our data comes from a quite different context and our findings are drawn from a distinct research method, they are strikingly similar to Geroski's (1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998., 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.). Accordingly, none of the four theories fully explained the growth of the firm we chose as empirical case. Nevertheless, DC was regarded as providing a more satisfactory explanatory power.

This article is structured as follows. The following section covers the theoretical background of study. Initially we outline four theories of firm growth: OFS, STF, TGF and DC. We then build the prediction matrix with similar, complementary and competitive propositions about firm growth. Subsequently we present detailed information about how our investigation was carried out, and place particular emphasis on DFA. Our results comprise an overview of the growth trajectory of the selected firm as well as DFA outcomes. The final two sections contain the theoretical implications as well as contributions and limitations of our research.

Theoretical Background

Four theories of firm growth

OFS has its roots in mainstream economics (KUPFER; HASENCLEVER, 2002KUPFER, D.; HASENCLEVER, L. Economia Industrial: fundamentos teóricos e práticos no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Campus, 2002.; SAUDERBRONN; SAUDERBROON; HASENCLEVER, 2011), which assumes that the firm operates within a perfectly competitive market (CYERT; MARCH, 1963CYERT, R.; MARCH, J. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1963.), i.e., an economic institution (WILLIAMSON, 1985WILLIAMSON, O. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: The Free Press, 1985.) represented by agents having complete information (CONNER, 1991CONNER, K. A historical comparison of Resource-based Theory and five schools of through within Industrial Organization Economics: do we have a new theory of theory? Journal of Management, v. 17, n. 1, p. 121-154, 1991.) about inputs and prices (CYERT; MARCH, 1963CYERT, R.; MARCH, J. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1963.) at zero costs (DEMSETZ, 1991DEMSETZ, H. The theory of the firm revisited. In: WILLIAMSON, O.; WINTER, S. (Ed.). The nature of the firm: origin, evolution and development. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991. p.159-178.). Under perfect competition, abnormal profits are washed away rapidly (DOSI; LECHEVALIER; SECCHI, 2010), which prevents the firm from sustaining a competitive advantage (ROSSETTI, 2003ROSSETTI, J. Introdução à economia. São Paulo: Atlas, 2003.). Against this backdrop, firm growth is a "movement towards the optimum size", as put nicely by Geroski (1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998., p.2). Graphically represented by the lowest point of the firm's cost curve (SLATER, 1980SLATER, M. Foreword. In: PENROSE, E. The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Oxford Basil Blackwell, 1980. p. vii-xxx.), the optimum size means that (all) firms maximize profits (RICHARDSON, 1972RICHARDSON, G. The organization of industry. The Economic Journal, v. 82, n. 327, p. 883-896, 1972.), stemming from the ideal mix of products and factors (CYERT; MARCH, 1963CYERT, R.; MARCH, J. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1963.). As equilibrium is reached with optimum size, in the long run firms are likely to display the same size (GEROSKI et al., 2003GEROSKI, Paul A. et al. Are differences in firm size transitory or permanent? Journal of Applied Econometrics, v. 18, n. 1, p. 47-59, 2003.).

Although STG is illustrated by a number of models (NECYK; FREZATTI, 2010NECYK, G.; FREZATTI, F. A contabilidade gerencial: uma perspectiva de ciclo de vida de seu desenvolvimento nas organizações. Organização & Sociedade, v. 17, n. 55, p. 725-744, 2010.; KLANN; KLANN; POSTAI; RIBEIRO, 2012), following Geroski (1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.), we look closer at Greiner's (1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972., 1988) and Mueller's (1972)MUELLER, D. A life cycle theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, v. 20, n. 3, p. 199-219, 1972. models. Broadly speaking, both models suggest that the firm grows in stages or phases, this process being contingent on firm size and age (COSTA; BOENTE, 2012COSTA, G.; BOENTE, D. Análise do perfil da produção científica sobre ciclo de vida no período de 2000 a 2011. Ambiente Contábil, v. 4, n. 1, p. 106-119, 2012.). Greiner's (1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972.; 1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.) model is grounded on the idea that the firm goes through periods of evolution and revolution which can be theoretically divided into five interconnected phases: creativity, direction, delegation, coordination and collaboration. Mueller's (1972)MUELLER, D. A life cycle theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, v. 20, n. 3, p. 199-219, 1972. model suggests that each phase of growth is associated with innovation either in terms of products or processes. The earlier phases embrace the foundation of the firm and product or process renewals whereas the later phases involve agency conflicts and diversification.

TGF is built upon two assumptions (GEROSKI, 1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.): i) services rendered from resources fuel firm growth (PENROSE, 1959); ii) there are managerial limits to the firm growth rate (KOR; MAHONEY, 2000KOR, Y; MAHONEY, J. Penrose's resource-based approach: the process and product of research creativity. Journal of Management Studies, v. 37, n. 1, p. 109-137, 2000.) - the so-called Penrose effect (SLATER, 1980SLATER, M. Foreword. In: PENROSE, E. The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Oxford Basil Blackwell, 1980. p. vii-xxx.). TGF suggests that the growth of the firm is largely determined by firm's internal resources (PENROSE, 1956PENROSE, E. Foreign investment and the growth of the firm. The Economic Journal, v. 66, n. 262, p. 220-235, 1956.). Resources such as machines, managers and the like (KOR; MAHONEY, 2000KOR, Y; MAHONEY, J. Penrose's resource-based approach: the process and product of research creativity. Journal of Management Studies, v. 37, n. 1, p. 109-137, 2000.) are indivisible or discrete (GEROSKI, 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.) therefore the firm is likely to have underutilized resources (FLECK, 2009) which can render services at near zero marginal cost (PITELIS, 2002PITELIS, C. On the garden of Edith: some themes. In: PITELIS, C (Ed.). The growth of the firm: the legacy of Edith Penrose. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. p. 1-16.; 2007). This provides an incentive for firm growth (PENROSE, 1959). Penrose (1956PENROSE, E. Foreign investment and the growth of the firm. The Economic Journal, v. 66, n. 262, p. 220-235, 1956.; 1959; 1971) places particular emphasis on the managerial limits to firm growth. As the administrative cadre is considered an inelastic resource (TAN; MAHONEY, 2007TAN, D.; MAHONEY, J. The dynamics of Japanese firm growth in U.S. industries: the Penrose effect. Management International Review, v. 47, n. 2, p. 259-279, 2007.), the firm takes deliberate and costly actions to develop and maintain it internally (JACOBIDES; WINTER; KASSBERGER, 2012JACOBIDES, M.; WINTER, S.; KASSBERGER, S. The dynamics of wealth, profit, and sustainable advantage. Strategic Management Journal, v. 33, p. 1384-1410, 2012.). This takes time notwithstanding, hindering firms from growing as smoothly (FOSS, 2002FOSS, N. Edith Penrose: economics and strategic management. In: PITELIS, C. (Ed.). The growth of the firm: the legacy of Edith Penrose. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. p. 147-164.) or quickly as planned (SLATER, 1980SLATER, M. Foreword. In: PENROSE, E. The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Oxford Basil Blackwell, 1980. p. vii-xxx.).

DC suggests that firm's capabilities are positively correlated to sustained superior returns (TEECE; PISANO; SHUEN, 1997; TEECE, 2007TEECE, D. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 28, p. 1319-1350, 2007.) or Schumpeterian returns (AUGIER; TEECE, 2009AUGIER, M; TEECE, D. Dynamic capabilities and the role of managers in business strategy and economic performance. Organization Science, v. 20, n. 2, p. 410-421, 2009.). These capabilities refer to the ability of the firm to deploy resources (AMIT; SCHOEMAKER, 1993AMIT, R.; SCHOEMAKER, P. Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, v. 14, n. 1, p. 33-46, 1993.) or "[…] to achieve new and innovative forms of competitive advantage […]" (TEECE; PISANO; SHUEN, 1997TEECE, D.; PISANO, G.; SHUEN, A. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 18, n. 7, p. 509-533, 1997., p. 516). In this sense, DC emphasizes sense-making in fast-changing environments (EISENHARDT; MARTIN, 2000EISENHARDT, K.; MARTIN, J. Dynamic Capabilities: what are they? Strategic Management Journal, v. 21, n. 10-11, p. 1105-1121, 2000.) such as opportunity discovery (AUGIER; TEECE, 2009AUGIER, M; TEECE, D. Dynamic capabilities and the role of managers in business strategy and economic performance. Organization Science, v. 20, n. 2, p. 410-421, 2009.) and environmental adaptation and reshaping (TEECE, 2007TEECE, D. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 28, p. 1319-1350, 2007.; DRNEVICH; KRIAUCIUNAS, 2011DRNEVICH, P.; KRIAUCIUNAS, A. Clarifying the conditions and limits of the contributions of ordinary and dynamics capabilities to relative firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 32, p. 254-279, 2011.; HELFAT; WINTER, 2011HELFAT, C.; WINTER, S. Untangling dynamic and operational capabilities: strategy for the (n)ever-changing world. Strategic Management Journal, v. 32, p. 1243-1250, 2011.). Dosi, Lechevalier and Secchi (2010) put forward that dynamic capabilities are grounded on organizational knowledge whereas Arikan and McGahan (2010)ARIKAN, A.; MCGAHAN, A. The development of capabilities in new firms. Strategic Management Journal, v. 31, p. 1-18, 2010. state that they are embedded in activities and routines. Regardless, authors such as Amit and Schoemaker (1993)AMIT, R.; SCHOEMAKER, P. Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, v. 14, n. 1, p. 33-46, 1993. and Teece, Pisano and Shuen (1997)TEECE, D.; PISANO, G.; SHUEN, A. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 18, n. 7, p. 509-533, 1997. forcefully suggest that dynamic capabilities are developed over time, usually through experiential learning (FLEURY; FLEURY, 2004FLEURY, M.; FLEURY, A. Alinhando Estratégia e Competências. Revista de Administração de Empresas, v. 44, n. 1, p. 44-57, 2004.). This makes them hard to observe and difficult to imitate (DUTTA; NARASHIMAHAN; RAJIV, 2005DUTTA, S.; NARASHIMHAN, O.; RAJIV, S. Conceptualizing and measuring capabilities: methodology and empirical application. Strategic Management Journal, v. 26, p. 177-287, 2005.; TEECE, 2007TEECE, D. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 28, p. 1319-1350, 2007.). It goes without saying that DC views the growth of the firm as the result of the development and maintenance of dynamic capabilities (GEROSKI, 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.).

The prediction matrix

The four theories reviewed earlier are the bedrock of a prediction matrix comprised of similar, complementary and competitive propositions about firm growth (WILSON; WOODSIDE, 1999WILSON, E.; WOODSIDE, A. Degrees-of-freedom analysis of case data in business marketing research. Industrial Marketing Management, v. 28, n. 3, p. 215–229, 1999.). We drew each proposition from a particular theory and then contrasted it with the other three theories in order to show whether it can be confirmed (C), partially confirmed (P), or not confirmed (N) in each of them (see Table 1).

Table 1
– Prediction matrix

The first proposition states that the firm is able to sustain competitive advantage. This goes against OFS as this theory posits that sustained competitive advantages are difficult, even impossible (GEROSKI, 1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.). Although STG does not deal with this explicitly, Klann et al. (2012)KLANN, R. C. et al. Relação entre o ciclo de vida organizacional e o planejamento em empresas metalúrgicas do município de Brusque-SC. Revista de Contabilidade e Organizações, v. 6, n. 16, p. 119-142, 2012. suggest a positive relation between firm life cycle and competitive advantage. If this holds, competitive advantage may be sustained in more successful stages or phases. This reasoning rests on the assumption that competitors are not able (BARNEY, 1991BARNEY, J. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, v.17, n.1, p. 99-120, 1991.) and do not want (MADHOK; LI; PRIEM, 2010MADHOK, A.; LI, S.; PRIEM, R. The resource-based view revisited: Comparative firm advantage, willingness-based isolating mechanisms and competitive heterogeneity. European Management Review, v. 7, n. 2, p. 91-100, 2010.) to imitate the firm life cycle, in particular the successful stages or phases. However, if they want and succeed in mimicking it, the competitive advantage of the firm will, at best, be temporary. This proposition is in line with TGF and CD, although TGF does not discuss inimitability (AUGIER; TEECE, 2009AUGIER, M; TEECE, D. Dynamic capabilities and the role of managers in business strategy and economic performance. Organization Science, v. 20, n. 2, p. 410-421, 2009.), which is germane to the competitive advantage debate (POSEN; LEE; YI, 2013POSEN, H.; LEE, J.; YI, S. The power of imperfect imitation. Strategic Management Journal, v. 34, p. 149-164, 2013.).

The second proposition points out that firm growth is determined by outputs (products). Whereas this proposition is one of OFS's tenets (CYER; MARCH, 1963CYERT, R.; MARCH, J. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1963.), it is not line with STG, TGF and DC. STG associates growth with firm age and size (GREINER, 1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972.) and innovation (MUELLER, 1972MUELLER, D. A life cycle theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, v. 20, n. 3, p. 199-219, 1972.). TGF explains firm growth by singling internal resources out (PENROSE, 1959PENROSE, E. Problems associated with the growth of international firms. In: PENROSE, E. The growth of firms, Middle East Oil and other essays. London: Frank Cass and Company, 1971. p. 82-90.) and DC replaces internal resources with dynamic capabilities (TEECE; PISANO; SHUEN, 1997TEECE, D.; PISANO, G.; SHUEN, A. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 18, n. 7, p. 509-533, 1997.).

The optimum size of the firm is the base of our third proposition. Needless to say, it is line with OFS. In relation to STG, we assume that this proposition can be partially confirmed to the extent that Mueller (1972)MUELLER, D. A life cycle theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, v. 20, n. 3, p. 199-219, 1972. points to a limit to the growth of the firm. However, it has a place in neither TGF nor DC. For instance, Penrose (1959) starts her acclaimed book by saying that there is no limit to firm growth.

Our next four propositions are inspired by STG. The fourth proposition maintains that firm growth is characterized by phases. This goes against the tenets of OFS, TGF and DC. In OFS, "[…] growth is simply a matter of adjusting to the equilibrium size of the firm" (FOSS, 2002FOSS, N. Edith Penrose: economics and strategic management. In: PITELIS, C. (Ed.). The growth of the firm: the legacy of Edith Penrose. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. p. 147-164., p.154). As TGF views firm growth as an evolutionary process driven by the interplay of resources and services (KOR; MAHONEY, 2000KOR, Y; MAHONEY, J. Penrose's resource-based approach: the process and product of research creativity. Journal of Management Studies, v. 37, n. 1, p. 109-137, 2000.), there is no room for pre-determined stages or phases. DC subscribes to the notion of path dependence (TEECE; PISANO; SHUEN, 1997TEECE, D.; PISANO, G.; SHUEN, A. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 18, n. 7, p. 509-533, 1997.; TEECE, 2007TEECE, D. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 28, p. 1319-1350, 2007.), which dismisses pre-determined stages or phases as well (ARAUJO; REZENDE, 2003ARAUJO, L.; REZENDE, S. Path dependence, MNCs and the internationalisation process: a relational approach. International Business Review, v. 12, n. 6, p. 719-737, 2003.).

The fifth proposition suggests that firm size influences firm growth. This is in accordance with OFS inasmuch as it pioneers the idea of optimum firm size. This is also in line with STG. For instance, Greiner (1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972., p.8) suggests that size is one of the dimensions for building what he calls "a model of organization development". In contrast, proposition five is supported in neither TGF nor DC.

Our next proposition states that firm growth is influenced by firm age. OFS disregards age as it assumes that all firms are identical (CONNER, 1991CONNER, K. A historical comparison of Resource-based Theory and five schools of through within Industrial Organization Economics: do we have a new theory of theory? Journal of Management, v. 17, n. 1, p. 121-154, 1991.). Together with size, age is one of the key dimensions of STG for explaining firm growth (GREINER, 1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972.). Although age is not explicitly discussed in TGF and DC, we suggest that this proposition can be partially confirmed in both theories. Whereas TGF assumes that firm growth is the result of a cumulative process of resource learning (FOSS, 2002FOSS, N. Edith Penrose: economics and strategic management. In: PITELIS, C. (Ed.). The growth of the firm: the legacy of Edith Penrose. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. p. 147-164.), DC advances the idea that the development of dynamic capabilities is to a certain degree related to firm experience (MAKADOK, 2001MAKADOK, R. Toward a synthesis of the resource-based and dynamic-capability views of rent creation. Strategic Management Journal, v. 22, n. 5, p. 387-401, 2001.).

Proposition seven asserts that firm growth is characterized by stable and long-standing growth phases. The same logic of reasoning developed in proposition four applies here. Apart from STG, this proposition is supported in none of the theories formerly outlined. For STG firm growth comprises stable and long-standing growth phases, each one ranging from four to eight years (GREINER, 1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972.).

The eighth proposition highlights firm history as it suggests that firm growth in t=1 is dependent on firm growth in t=0. Whereas history does not matter in OFS, it plays a pivotal role in STG, TGF and DC. In OFS the firm is considered a-historical (CONNER, 1991CONNER, K. A historical comparison of Resource-based Theory and five schools of through within Industrial Organization Economics: do we have a new theory of theory? Journal of Management, v. 17, n. 1, p. 121-154, 1991.). In STG history comes to the forefront for explaining firm growth (GREINER, 1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972.). This also holds for TGF (BLOCH; FINCH, 2010BLOCH, H.; FINCH, J. Firms and industries in evolutionary economics: lessons from Marshall, Young, Steindl and Penrose. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, v. 20, n. 1, p. 139-162, 2010.) and DC (ZOLLO; WINTER, 2002ZOLLO, M.; WINTER, S. Deliberate learning and the evolution of dynamic capabilities. Organization Science, v. 13, n. 3, p. 339-351, 2002.).

Proposition nine indicates that growth opportunities depend on underutilized internal resources. This proposition can only be confirmed in TGF: it is one of its spokes (GEROSKI, 1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.). In OFS it has no room as this theory views firm growth as regulated by the price mechanism (COASE, 1937COASE, R. H. The nature of the firm. Economica, v. 4, n. 16, p. 386-405, 1937.), which means that market forces set the limits to firm growth (VASCONCELOS; CYRINO, 2000VASCONCELOS, F.; CYRINO. Vantagem Competitiva. Revista de Administração de Empresas, v. 40, n. 4, p. 30-37, 2000.). It cannot be confirmed in STG or DC either. The focus of STG is on stages or phases, not on underutilized resources (MUELLER, 1972MUELLER, D. A life cycle theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, v. 20, n. 3, p. 199-219, 1972.), whereas in DC dynamic capabilities "drive the flow of resources" (LE MENS; HANNAN; POLOS, 2011LE MENS, G.; HANNAN, M.; PÓLOS, L. Founding conditions, learning, and organizational life chances: age dependence revisited. Administrative Science Quarterly, v. 56, p. 95-126, 2011., p. 96).

The tenth proposition highlights the manager as a conduit for firm growth. Only in OFS are purposeful decisions by managers disregarded (AUGIER; TEECE, 2009AUGIER, M; TEECE, D. Dynamic capabilities and the role of managers in business strategy and economic performance. Organization Science, v. 20, n. 2, p. 410-421, 2009.). In STG managers have some discretion as the firm evolves, and this influences its growth (MUELLER, 1972MUELLER, D. A life cycle theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, v. 20, n. 3, p. 199-219, 1972.). The Penrose effect has to do with the limits to firm growth set by managerial resources (SLATER, 1980SLATER, M. Foreword. In: PENROSE, E. The theory of the growth of the firm. Oxford: Oxford Basil Blackwell, 1980. p. vii-xxx.). DC also places emphasis on agency for explaining the development of dynamic capabilities and consequently firm growth (DI STEFANO; PETERAF; VERONA, 2010DI STEFANO, G.; PETERAF, M.; VERONA, G. Dynamic capabilities deconstructed: a bibliographic investigation into the origins, development, and future direction of the research domain. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 19, n. 4, p. 1187-1204, 2010.), especially in the earlier years of the firm (WINTER, 2012WINTER, S. Capabilities: their origins and ancestry. Journal of Management Studies, v. 49, p. 1402-1406, 2012.).

Proposition eleven states that the growth of the firm is endogenous, i.e., it is based on the firm's internal activities. This proposition is at opposite ends of OFS (DEMSETZ, 1991DEMSETZ, H. The theory of the firm revisited. In: WILLIAMSON, O.; WINTER, S. (Ed.). The nature of the firm: origin, evolution and development. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991. p.159-178.). However, it can be confirmed both in STG and TGF. In relation to DC, we suggest that this proposition can be partially confirmed. On the one hand, dynamic capabilities are the result of internal processes (TEECE; PISANO; SHUEN, 1997TEECE, D.; PISANO, G.; SHUEN, A. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 18, n. 7, p. 509-533, 1997.) and, therefore, reside within the firm (MAHMOOD; ZHU; ZAJAC, 2011MAHMOOD, I.; ZHU, H.; ZAJAC, E. Where can capabilities come from? Network ties and capabilities acquisition in business groups. Strategic Management Journal, v. 32, n. 8, p. 820-848, 2011.). On the other hand, they are shaped by the context in which the firm is embedded (EISENHARDT; MARTIN, 2000EISENHARDT, K.; MARTIN, J. Dynamic Capabilities: what are they? Strategic Management Journal, v. 21, n. 10-11, p. 1105-1121, 2000.; TEECE, 2007TEECE, D. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 28, p. 1319-1350, 2007.).

The twelfth proposition states that learning affects firm growth. Whereas this proposition is not in line with OFS (GEROSKI, 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.) it can be confirmed in STG, TGF and DC. For example, in STG learning is the result of each stage or phase, and it can be used in subsequent phases or cycles (GREINER, 1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972.). Yet, in TGF learning has to do with resource using (PENROSE, 1959) and in DC with previous activities (TEECE; PISANO; SHUEN, 1997TEECE, D.; PISANO, G.; SHUEN, A. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 18, n. 7, p. 509-533, 1997.).

Proposition thirteen suggests that there is no relation between firm growth and industry growth. This proposition cannot be confirmed in both OFS and STG. For example, in STG industry is considered one of the cornerstones of organizational development (GREINER, 1972GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972.). However, it is in accordance with TGF and DC since both models accommodate the idea of idiosyncratic patterns of firm growth trajectories (DRNEVICH; KRIAUCIUNAS, 2011DRNEVICH, P.; KRIAUCIUNAS, A. Clarifying the conditions and limits of the contributions of ordinary and dynamics capabilities to relative firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 32, p. 254-279, 2011.).

Finally, our last proposition states that firm performance changes as firm evolves. Although this is not directly discussed in OFS, it cannot be confirmed in it. In OFS market forces eliminate abnormal rents very rapidly (DOSI; LECHEVALIER; SECCHI, 2010), forcing firms to reach a similar level of performance (GEROSKI et al., 2003GEROSKI, Paul A. et al. Are differences in firm size transitory or permanent? Journal of Applied Econometrics, v. 18, n. 1, p. 47-59, 2003.). STG has a different view to the extent that it suggests that firm performance is contingent upon the stage or phase which the firm goes through (MILLER; FRIESEN, 1984MILLER, D.; FRIESEN, P. A longitudinal study of the corporate life cycle. Management Science, v. 30, n. 10, p. 1161-1183, 1984.). In relation to both TGF and DC, we suggest that this proposition is partially confirmed. Both models argue that differences in performance across firms persist for a while (RUGMAN; VERBEKE, 2002RUGMAN, A.; VERBEKE, A. Edith Penrose's contribution to the resource-based view of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 23, n. 8, p. 769-780, 2002.) due to either heterogeneous resources (TGF) or dynamic capabilities (DC). This implies that firm performance has a stable component in order to maintain these differences (DOSI; LECHEVALIER; SECCHI, 2010DOSI, G.; LECHEVALIER, S.; SECCHI, A. Introduction: Interfirm heterogeneity – nature, sources and consequences of industrial dynamics. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 19, n. 6, p. 1867-1890, 2010.). However, as Penrose states (1956), there is no reason to assume that this will continue indefinitely. If this holds, firm performance is likely to change, yet not as long as the firm evolves.

Methodology

We constructed a single case study to address our research aim (EASTON, 2000EASTON, G. Case research as a method for industrial networks: a realist apologia. In: ACKROYD, S.; FLEETWOOD, S. (Orgs.). Realist perspectives on management and organizations. London: Routledge, 2000. p. 178-194.). Initially, we collected backward-looking qualitative data (BLUHM; HARMAN; LEE; MITCHELL, 2011) as we intended to trace the trajectory of the firm (GEORGE; BENNETT, 2005GEORGE, A.; BENNETT, A. Case studies and theory development in the social sciences. Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press, 2005.) - defined as a chain of causally connected events (BURGELMAN, 2011BURGELMAN, R. Bridging history and reductionism: a key role for longitudinal qualitative research. Journal of International Business Studies, v. 42, n. 5, p. 591-601, 2011.) - by highlighting events related to firm growth (FLECK, 2009FLECK. D. Archetypes of organizational success and failure. Brazilian Administrative Review, v. 6, n. 2, p. 78-100, 2009.). Subsequently, this data was analyzed in light of Degrees of Freedom Analysis (DFA).

We selected the growth trajectory of EIP (fictitious name) based on two broad criteria. First, it was required that this trajectory would comprise a "number" of events that illustrated firm growth. Based on the assumption that the trajectory of older firms is likely to exhibit more of this type of event, our first criterion was firm age (SERRASQUEIRO et al., 2010SERRASQUEIRO, Z.; NUNES, P.; LEITÃO, J.; ARMANDA, M. Are there non-linearities between SME growth and its determinants? A quantile approach. Industrial and Corporate Change, v 19, n. 4, p. 1071-1108, 2010.). Second, access not only to primary data collected from face-to-face interviews with upper-echelon managers and directors, but also secondary data, in particular archival data and financial figures which are usually hard to obtain (GRAHAM; HARVEY; RAJGOPAL, 2005GRAHAM, J.; HARVEY, C.; RAJGOPAL, S. The Economic Implications of Corporate Financial Reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 40, n. 1–3, p. 3–73, 2005.), was also required. In this sense, our second criterion was data access (LANGLEY, 1999LANGLEY, A. Strategies for theorizing from process data. Academy of Management Review, v. 24, n. 4, p. 691-710, 1999.).

Having gotten the consent of the firm, we started collecting data by gathering secondary data. In addition to official data about the capital goods industry obtained from the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE, 2011INSTITUTO BRASILEIRO DE GEOGRAFIA E ESTATÍSTICA. Portal Institucional. Available from: <http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/pesquisas/pesquisa_resultados.php?indicador=1&id_pesquisa=4>. Acess 2011 Feb.
http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/...
) and the National Bank for Economic and Social Development (BNDES, 2011BANCO NACIONAL DE DESENVOLVIMENTO ECONÔMICO E SOCIAL. Portal Institucional. Available from: <http://www.bndes.gov.br/SiteBNDES/bndes/bndes_pt/index.html>. Acess 2011 Feb.
http://www.bndes.gov.br/SiteBNDES/bndes/...
), between November 2010 and February 2011 we collected data from EIP's accounting registers, in particular financial statements between 1977 and 2009. The 1989 financial statement was missing because the accounting register had been eaten by moths. We were not able to find the financial statements between 1964 (foundation of the firm) and 1976 either. In this period, accountancy was outsourced, and the financial management of the firm was based on cash flow.

We also collected archival data such as a number of managerial reports, especially those aimed at detailing the plant production capacity to potential buyers as well as EIP investments over the years, all documents prepared for bids in which EIP participated over nearly fifty years, and an extensive amount of documents containing the description and technical details of all equipment manufactured by the firm. All this data was later coded and compiled resulting in nearly 600 pages of singled-space text.

In terms of primary data, we interviewed the founder and seven individuals such as the CEO, directors, upper-echelon managers and former managers. These interviews were carried out and tape-recorded between May and August 2011, each one lasting 163 minutes on average.

The interviews were supported by a protocol divided into three parts. In the first part we aimed to get an overview of EIP growth trajectory since EIP inception. To do so, we asked the following questions: i) What are the roots of EIP?; ii) Tell me the history and the trajectory of EIP by pointing out the events you consider relevant; iii) What were the major transformations of the firm over the course of its history?

In the second part we furthered our understanding of the EIP growth trajectory by asking more specific questions which were formulated based on five indicators built from secondary data. The first indicator, the evolution of the firm, is illustrated by the ratio of the turnover of the firm to the Brazilian Gross National Product (GNP) (T/G). According to Fleck (2004FLECK, D. Crescimento, dominância continuada e declínio da empresa: insights das histórias da General Electric e da Westinghouse. Revista de Administração Contemporânea, Edição Especial, p. 79-106, 2004.; 2009FLECK. D. Archetypes of organizational success and failure. Brazilian Administrative Review, v. 6, n. 2, p. 78-100, 2009.), this indicator embeds automatic adjustments in terms of inflation and deflation that are considered relevant in studies of firm growth. The second indicator is turnover annual growth, calculated from the ratio of EIP turnover in t=1 to t=0. The third indicator is gross profit annual growth, based on the ratio of EIP gross profit in t=1 to t=0. The fourth indicator is GNP annual growth, based on the ratio of GNP in t=1 to t=0. The fifth and last indicator is similar to the fourth one to the extent that it refers to the GNP measured for the capital goods industry (GNP BK). We took into account the GNP implicit deflator retrieved from the IBGE site in order to calculate all indicators except the first. We also cared about currency changes over the years.

These indicators were plotted in graphs and used as the bedrock for the second part of the interview. We encouraged the interviewees to explain the curves according to their point of view by placing emphasis on their highest and lowest points. Finally, the last part of the interview was dedicated to asking questions directly related to the theoretical propositions of our research.

The inductive data analysis began by merging secondary and primary data texts, which, in turn, enabled us to triangulate data at three levels (JICK, 1979JICK, T. Mixing Qualitative and quantitative methods: triangulation in action. Administrative Science Quarterly, v. 24, n. 4, p. 602-611, 1979.): secondary data itself, primary data itself and secondary data vis-à-vis primary data. As a number of divergences were found, we went back to the original documents as well as carried out another interview with the founder of the firm, which lasted 90 minutes.

Our next step in terms of data analysis was to select the critical events in the EIP growth trajectory. Borrowing the concept of critical events introduced by Halinen, Havila and Salmi (1999) and further developed by Halinen, Tornroos and Elo (2013)HALINEN, A.; TORNROOS, J-A.; ELO, M. Network process analysis: an event-based approach to study business network dynamics. Industrial Marketing Management, 2013. in the context of business networks, we considered critical events as those incidents that left a mark on the firm's growth trajectory. Based on the interpretations of the interviewees as well as secondary data, we concluded that the critical events in the EIP growth trajectory were empirically illustrated by the following categories: number and types of bids, number and types of equipment manufactured, and diversification strategies. In this sense, we wrote a first draft of the case guided by the presence of any of these types of event. This version was sent to the founder of the firm for comments and criticisms. In general, he considered that the case mirrored the EIP growth trajectory.

We proceeded with data analysis by guaranteeing that the case contained enough empirical evidence to enable the judges to assess the theoretical propositions of the prediction matrix. Grounded on the literature review, we wrote a document in which we detailed such evidences, reaching an average of 2.6 instances of evidences per theoretical proposition.

At this point, we were ready to use DFA. According to Wilson and Woodside (1999)WILSON, E.; WOODSIDE, A. Degrees-of-freedom analysis of case data in business marketing research. Industrial Marketing Management, v. 28, n. 3, p. 215–229, 1999., the heart of DFA is the development of a prediction matrix. As shown in the theoretical background, our matrix had 56 cells (14 propositions versus 4 theories) indicating whether each theoretical proposition could be confirmed (C), partially confirmed (P) or not be confirmed (N) in each theory.

We selected three judges familiar with the four theories (a CFO who holds a MBA and two senior lecturers in Management, both holding a PhD in Management) to whom in November 2011 we sent the case of the EIP growth trajectory, a brief description of each theoretical proposition and a blank table. They were asked to indicate whether each theoretical proposition could be confirmed, partially confirmed or not be confirmed in the case. We received the filled tables in December 2011.

Initially, we assessed the level of agreement across the judges. Following Wilson and Woodside (1999)WILSON, E.; WOODSIDE, A. Degrees-of-freedom analysis of case data in business marketing research. Industrial Marketing Management, v. 28, n. 3, p. 215–229, 1999., four agreement levels could be reached by the judges: perfect – the three judges would agree (CCC), partially agree (PPP) or not agree (NNN); near perfect – two judges would agree (CCP), partially agree (CPP or NPP) or not agree (NNP); some – two judges would agree and one would not agree (CCN) or two judges would not agree and one would agree (CNN); and finally, none – the three judges would not agree (CPN). By chance it is expected that the distribution would be 11% perfect, 44% near perfect, 22% some and 22% none.

The agreement levels across the judges were 22% perfect, 64% near perfect, 7% some and 7% none. Based on the chi-square test (x2), these distributions are not significantly different (x2=0.138, ns). This means that they display agreement levels that are not different from those expected by chance (FONSECA; MARTINS, 1996FONSECA, J.; MARTINS, G. Curso de estatística. São Paulo: Atlas, 1996.).

Having tested the agreement levels across the judges, the last step of data analysis using DFA was to contrast the prediction matrix with the matrix built from the assessments of the judges (WILSON; WOODSIDE, 1999WILSON, E.; WOODSIDE, A. Degrees-of-freedom analysis of case data in business marketing research. Industrial Marketing Management, v. 28, n. 3, p. 215–229, 1999.). This means counting the number of hits, i.e., confirmed theoretical propositions. For a second time, we used the chi-square test. Our aim was to evaluate the 42 results (14 theoretical propositions versus 3 judges) so as to detect whether there was a "[…] significant difference between the observed distribution of hits (i.e., confirmed predictions) and the distribution one would expect by chance" (WILSON; WOODSIDE, 1999WILSON, E.; WOODSIDE, A. Degrees-of-freedom analysis of case data in business marketing research. Industrial Marketing Management, v. 28, n. 3, p. 215–229, 1999., p. 222). The results are detailed in next section.

Results

EIP growth trajectory: an overview

EIP is a capital goods firm organized in three business units: Energy, Industry and Petroleum. Its growth trajectory, illustrated by the ratio of its turnover to the Brazilian GNP (T/G), can be seen in Figure 1. Broadly, there is a rising curve between 1977 and 1979, the best T/G in the EIP growth trajectory being reached in 1979. From this year on, T/G declines, touching the lowest point in 2001. This decline, however, is not smooth and constant inasmuch as the curve that illustrates it is characterized by a number of peaks (1981, 1984, 1988, 1992, 1995 e 1999). In 2001, the decline of the curve is interrupted. It is the beginning of an eight-year period in which T/G grows, although not linearly.

Figure 1
– Turnover/Brazilian GNP

Going into detail, EIP dates back to 1964. It was founded in São Paulo by three individuals, one of them an engineer. In the very beginning, there were only three machines (a lathe, a drill press and a grinder motor) for manufacturing nuts, special screws and machined parts. One year later, one of the founders bought the shares from the other two and soon afterwards sold them to the current President of the board of EIP. At that time he was only twenty years old. His first decision was to transfer EIP to Belo Horizonte, in the state of Minas Gerais, into an area of less than 90 square meters. In the following years, he invited his three brothers to become shareholders of the firm.

The first worthy business opportunity was identified three years later when EIP made an agreement with a multinational firm in the aluminum business for manufacturing hardware for aluminum spools. To a certain degree, this contract enabled EIP to buy, via loan, an 80-ton hot stamping screw press. In doing so, EIP increased the quality of special screws considerably which, in turn, attracted new buyers interested in higher quality products.

During the first National Development Plan (PND), EIP began to supply series parts for earthmoving machines to another multinational firm. In 1974, EIP's owners identified a business opportunity to rebuild the aluminum multinational's electrical furnace used for manufacturing ferroalloys. Later, EIP won a bid for producing 168 aluminum melting furnaces (electrolytic cells) for this same firm.

The second PND, implemented in 1975, provided incentives for constructing national roads and building electrical and nuclear power stations. In this context, EIP's owners mapped out new business opportunities and, as a result, decided to acquire a 51,000 m2 area where they built a new plant for increasing the production capacity of the firm.

A couple of years later, one of the largest Brazilian state-owned steel producers invited bids for enlarging a number of its plants. With the aim of increasing its chance to win some of the bids, EIP signed an agreement for producing plate processing equipment with the Brazilian subsidiary of a French multinational. This paid off to the extent that EIP won two bids for manufacturing continuous steel coil galvanizing lines. As a result, EIP's turnover increased 21% in 1977 and 56% in 1978. As mentioned earlier, the best T/G in EIP's growth trajectory is reached in 1979 (see Figure 1).

The financial resources resulted from these contracts were partly used for building a new plant which came into operation in 1977. From this time on, EIP would not only manufacture equipment, but also develop custom engineering projects.

In this same year, due to the particular interest of a shareholder, EIP diversified its activities into a cattle farm and a eucalyptus plantation. In 1978, EIP furthered its diversification by acquiring a project for building silicon and manganese alloys plant, which came into operation in 1980 (herein RSZ). Interestingly enough, T/G started declining in this year (see Figure 1).

In 1983, the RSZ's second furnace came into operation enabling RSZ to increase production capacity as well as sales considerably. As RSZ overtook EIP in terms of turnover and profitability, it received more financial and managerial resources. Unable to obtain new contracts, EIP went adrift and later became dependent on RSZ. This situation went on up to 1991 when EIP won three important contracts, thus interrupting the decline of T/G.

Meanwhile, the firm shareholders unexpectedly split due to a number of divergences. As a consequence, they decided that the first shareholder would be in charge of EIP whereas the other three would run RSZ. Following the shareholder split, a new CEO for EIP was hired. In addition, the sons of the remaining shareholder began their professional careers at EIP.

At this point, it is interesting to highlight that the initial diversifications snowballed covering unrelated areas such as IT, iron exporting, hydraulic pump manufacturing, but they failed after a while.

In 1999, PETROBRAS, the Brazilian state-owned petroleum firm, invited EIP to make a bid for manufacturing equipment called Cyclone. The firm won the bid, and this hallmarked its entry into the petroleum industry. Three years later, EIP started operating in the petroleum refinement value chain by developing more value-added equipment. At this time, EIP decided to reorganize itself by creating three business units: Energy, Industry and Petroleum.

The initial equipment supplies to PETROBRAS, however, resulted in financial loss. For example, EIP's turnover jumped from R$ 8.2 million in 2000 to R$ 43.4 million in 2005 whereas its gross profit went down from 23% to 13% in the same period. In fact, manufacturing and delivery of this type of equipment required engineering, manufacturing and welding capabilities not totally mastered yet.

Despite this, EIP succeeded in developing them. Later, they became a springboard for manufacturing new products for the petroleum industry such as cooling towers. On top of that, it made and won a number of bids invited by either PETROBRAS or its suppliers. As a consequence, the petroleum unit became EIP's most important business unit.

In the following two years, there were two critical events in the EIP growth trajectory. First, PETROBRAS paved the way for EIP to become a partner of an American firm for manufacturing submarine petroleum equipment. Second, together with a German Firm EIP founded a new firm called EIP Services by taking over the Brazilian subsidiary of the German firm's plant.

This acquisition was controversial notwithstanding these circumstances. Some managers and directors considered managerial resources to be already scarce and insufficient to render enough services to run the acquired firm. To a certain degree they were right inasmuch as underpriced orders were taken and a number of deliveries were delayed. Yet, operational activities nearly collapsed.

Facing these issues, they came to the conclusion that management practices in EIP should be revised entirely. In addition, the sons of the shareholder gained control of the firm, each one being in charge of a particular functional area such as marketing, procurement and human resources. The CEO quit the firm.

In 2008 EIP took over EIP Services by acquiring the shares of the German firm. Soon afterwards, new management changes were introduced once again. For example, new directors were hired and seats on the board of EIP were offered to the sons. EIP's growth trajectory ends at this point with the implementation of governance mechanisms that were expected to help the firm face upcoming challenges. Figure 2 portrays EIP growth trajectory by highlighting its major events.

Figure 2
EIP growth trajectory

Degrees of freedom analysis

We started DFA by assessing the agreement levels across the judges. As detailed in Table 2, they were in perfect agreement for 21% of the evaluations, corresponding to three propositions. Near perfect agreement occurred for 64% of the evaluations, i.e., nine propositions. Some agreement and none agreement occurred for 7% of the evaluations each.

Table 2
Agreement levels across the judges

Specifically, the judges perfectly agreed that one proposition was confirmed in the case of EIP growth trajectory. Accordingly, EIP's managers had a relevant role in the growth of the firm, thus supporting proposition ten. They also perfectly agreed that propositions one and four were not confirmed in this case. Whereas proposition one highlights the ability of the firm to sustain competitive advantage, proposition four states that firm growth is characterized by phases. Empirically, this means that EIP was neither able to maintain competitive advantages nor grew in stages or phases.

A near perfect agreement level occurred for nine propositions, representing three different situations. First, two judges disagreed and one partially agreed on four propositions. In their point of view, EIP did not reach an optimum size (proposition three), its growth was not influenced by size (proposition five), age (proposition six) and was not dependent on previous historical events (proposition eight). Second, one judge agreed and two partially disagreed on three propositions: propositions two, eleven and thirteen. In this sense, the evaluations of the judges slightly suggest that EIP growth was neither determined by outputs nor by internal resources. Yet, they related EIP growth with the capital goods industry growth. Third, two judges agreed and one disagreed on propositions twelve and thirteen. The twelfth proposition states that learning influences firm growth whereas the thirteenth proposition suggests that firm performance changes as the firm evolves.

The two remaining propositions had some and zero agreement levels. Some agreement occurred for the proposition that states that firm growth is characterized by stable and long-standing phases. One judge agreed and two disagreed that this proposition was confirmed in the case of EIP growth trajectory. No agreement level occurred for proposition nine: growth opportunities depend on underutilized internal resources.

Altogether, these results demonstrate that OFS had 14 out of 42 hits, corresponding to 33%. STG had 11 out 42 hits, which is equivalent to 26%. TGF had a 45% hit rate, meaning 19 out of 42 hits. DC had the highest hit rate: 48% (20 out of 42 hits). That is, according to the judges none of the theories considered here (OFS, STG, TGF and DC) can fully explain EIP's growth trajectory. Against this backdrop, it is suggested that DC is the theory with the highest explanatory power (48%) followed by TGF (45%). The explanatory power of OFS and STG is lower: 33% and 26% respectively. As shown in Table 3, this distribution is not significantly different from the one expected by chance (x2=0.337, ns).

Table 3
– Results: four theories of firm growth

Discussion and Implications

The results show that hit rates ranged from 26% to 48%. This means that none of the four theories considered here provided a crystal-clear explanation of the EIP growth trajectory. According to the judges, DC stood out nevertheless: it had the highest hit rate (48%). Provided we consider DC hit rate at face value we can make a bold comparison with firm growth quantitative studies r2 (e.g. GEROSKI; MAZZUCATO, 2002GEROSKI, P.; MAZZUCATO, M. Learning and the sources of corporate growth. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 11, n.4, p. 623-644, 2002.), and conclude (again boldly) that the DC hit rate is not bad at all!

Interestingly, these findings are amazingly akin to those presented by Geroski (1988GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.) even though they are embedded in a rather distinct context as well as being drawn from a diverse research method.

Together with our qualitative data, we offer two different, yet overlapping interpretations of these results. The first interpretation is backed up by Coad's (2010)COAD, A. Exploring the processes of firm growth: evidence form a vector auto-regression. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 19, n. 6, p. 1667-1703, 2010. claim that firm growth is a multidimensional phenomenon, which militates against an overarching theory of firm growth, as well as Geroski, Mata and Portugal's (2010)GEROSKI, P. A.; MATA, J.; PORTUGAL, P. Founding conditions and the survival of new firms. Strategic Management Journal, v. 31, p. 510-529, 2010. assertion of the lack of superiority of a particular theory for accounting for the growth of Portuguese firms. This interpretation explains why none of the theories considered here fully explained the case of EIP's growth trajectory. The second interpretation is supported by Geroski's (1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.) findings that indicate DC as the most promising theory of firm growth. This interpretation lends a degree of support to the fact that DC had the highest hit rate, although not much higher than TGF. In our view, the first interpretation implies combining theories to further our understanding of firm growth whereas the second one requires strengthening the explanatory power of DC by relaxing some of its assumption.

According to the first interpretation, a more satisfactory explanation of the EIP growth trajectory requires a bridge between theories of firm growth. Framed by our empirical results, we suggest a conversation between OFS and DC gravitating towards the trade-off between competitive markets (OFS) and idiosyncrasy of firm growth trajectory (DC). This conversation is encapsulated by the following proposition: firm growth is a rather idiosyncratic process that unfolds within competitive markets.

More specifically, the judges considered the relation between EIP growth and the capital goods industry growth. From a theoretical standpoint, this assessment goes against the idea of matchless growth trajectory espoused by DC, but it is in accordance with OFS. We wonder whether a particular firm's dynamic capabilities can be conceptualized as exhibiting common features across other firms' dynamic capabilities (EISENHARDT; MARTIN, 2000EISENHARDT, K.; MARTIN, J. Dynamic Capabilities: what are they? Strategic Management Journal, v. 21, n. 10-11, p. 1105-1121, 2000.). If it can, we are able to advance the idea that the development and maintenance of dynamic capabilities is to an extent shaped by market forces. This reduces the degree of idiosyncrasy in terms of firm growth trajectories, but does not erase it. At the same time, it opens up the possibility of commonalities across growth trajectories brought about by market forces.

Two issues lie behind this proposition. First, a careful definition and delimitation of competitive markets is needed so as to avoid conflating them with the concept of an industry as advocated by OFS. As Dosi, Lechevalier and Secchi (2010) remark, theories of firm growth need to rethink the locus of competition by considering the notion of submarkets populated by heterogeneous firms. In submarkets, market forces are not too effective as they are in perfect competition because they do not equalize firm size and firm growth trajectories. Notwithstanding, they do have the causal power to reduce idiosyncrasies. Under competition pressure in submarkets, firms with different sizes attempt to imitate one another. This leads us to the second issue, that is, some imitation is likely to occur across firms. However, it is neither near totally perfect as espoused by OFS nor near totally imperfect as conceived by DC. In submarkets, it lies in between like the notion of imperfect imitation recently discussed by Posen, Lee and Yi (2013)POSEN, H.; LEE, J.; YI, S. The power of imperfect imitation. Strategic Management Journal, v. 34, p. 149-164, 2013.. If firms imitate one another although imperfectly, it is expected that at least some of their dynamic capabilities (or their effects) will be alike (EISENHARDT; MARTIN, 2000EISENHARDT, K.; MARTIN, J. Dynamic Capabilities: what are they? Strategic Management Journal, v. 21, n. 10-11, p. 1105-1121, 2000.; DRNEVIC; KRIAUCIUNAS, 2011DUTTA, S.; NARASHIMHAN, O.; RAJIV, S. Conceptualizing and measuring capabilities: methodology and empirical application. Strategic Management Journal, v. 26, p. 177-287, 2005.).

By following the second interpretation, some assumptions of DC are to be relaxed with the aim of increasing its explanatory power of firm growth. This is carried out without borrowing concepts from the other theories of firm growth considered here. Grounded on our empirical results, we select the proposition that highlights firm performance fluctuation along the existence of the firm, that is to say, firm performance does not necessarily have a stable component. This interpretation is captured by the following proposition: firm performance fluctuates non-linearly as the firm grows.

More specifically, the judges considered performance fluctuations along the EIP growth trajectory, which is, in our view, partially confirmed in DC. As discussed earlier, DC subscribes the idea that firm performance has a stable component so as to sustain the firm competitive advantage. We wonder whether uneven and erratic performance can be accommodated by DC (GEROSKI, 1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.). If it can, we open up the possibility of conceptualizing firm growth trajectory as stochastic. In this regard, firm growth trajectory and performance will be driven by boundedly rational individuals facing "[…] strategic choices that involve high levels of uncertainty, causal ambiguity, and chaotic complexity" (HENDERSON; RAYNOR; AHMED, 2012HENDERSON, A.; RAYNOR, M.; AHMED, M. How long must a firm be great to rule out chance? Benchmarking sustained superior performance without being fooled by randomness. Strategic Management Journal, v. 33, n. 4, p. 387-406, 2012., p. 389). This means that firm growth trajectory will be driven by choices made in a world populated by boundedly rational decision-makers (WILLIAMSON, 1985WILLIAMSON, O. The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: The Free Press, 1985.)1. In this world, the happenstance of history (MEYER; BROOKS; GOES, 1990MEYER, A.; BROOKS, G.; GOES, J. Environmental jolts and industry revolutions: organizational responses to discontinuous change. Strategic Management Journal, v. 11, p. 93-110, 1990.) plays a role which, in turn, brings randomness to the forefront (LEVINTHAL, 1997LEVINTHAL, D. Adaptation on rugged landscapes. Management Science, v. 43, n. 7, p. 934-950, 1997.). Because random events usually fall off the decision-makers' radar screen, they can only be fully grasped with the benefit of hindsight (ARTHUR, 1989ARTHUR, B. Competing technologies, increasing returns and lock-in by historical events. The Economic Journal, v. 99, p. 116-131, 1989.).

Differently put, firm growth will be a combination of expected and unexpected determinants, or, as Geroski (1998)GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998. names them, shocks. This is similar to say that firm growth will follow a random walk (LEVINTHAL, 1991LEVINTHAL, D. Random walks and organizational mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly, v. 36, p.397-420, 1991.). In this conception, the heterogeneity across firms, one of the tenets of DC (DI STEFANO; PETERAF; VERONA, 2010DI STEFANO, G.; PETERAF, M.; VERONA, G. Dynamic capabilities deconstructed: a bibliographic investigation into the origins, development, and future direction of the research domain. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 19, n. 4, p. 1187-1204, 2010.), remains untouchable.

Conclusion

By using DFA to analyze backward-looking qualitative data about the growth trajectory of a Brazilian capital goods firm, we found that none of the four theories of firm growth selected here – Optimum Firm Size, Stage Theory of Growth, The Theory of the Growth of the Firm and Dynamic Capabilities – provided a satisfactory explanation for the growth of the selected firm. In spite of this, DC was judged to offer the best account. Two theoretical implications are drawn from these results. The first proposes a bridge between OFS and DC (JACOBIDES; WINTER; KASSEBERGER, 2012JACOBIDES, M.; WINTER, S.; KASSBERGER, S. The dynamics of wealth, profit, and sustainable advantage. Strategic Management Journal, v. 33, p. 1384-1410, 2012.). In this regard, firm growth trajectory is still considered idiosyncratic, but embedded within competitive markets. The second implies relaxing some assumptions of DC, in particular the one related to nonlinearities in firm performance (GEROSKI, 1998GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.; 2000).

On the face of it, our contributions to research on firm growth are as follows: i) we provided a detailed account of the growth trajectory of a particular firm from its inception using not only qualitative, but also quantitative data collected from multiple sources. Subsequently, we employed qualitative and quantitative data analysis techniques simultaneously (BYRNE; RAGIN, 2009BYRNE, D.; RAGIN, C. The Sage handbook of case-based methods. London: Sage, 2009.), which is far from trivial. To our knowledge, DFA as a case data analysis technique had not been used in firm growth studies until now; ii) we built a prediction matrix composed of similar, complementary and competitive propositions about firm growth. In our view, it can be used as a starting point in future studies of firm growth; and iii) we suggested news avenues of exploration for theories of firm growth. It either combines theories such as OFS and DC or relaxes some assumptions of DC without compromising its building blocks.

Nevertheless, these claims should be treated with cautions. Firstly, our findings are based on a single case study which prevents us from making statistical generalization (YIN, 2005YIN, R. Estudo de caso: planejamento e métodos. Porto Alegre: Bookman, 2005.). Closely related, they are bounded by a number of contextual factors such as industry and geography (POULIS; POULIS; PLAKOYIANNAKI, 2013POULIS, K.; POULIS, E.; PLAKOYIANNAKI, E. The role of context in case study selection: an international business perspective. International Business Review, v. 22, 304-337, 2013.). Secondly, the account of EIP's growth trajectory was guided by three categories of critical events. In doing so, other types of event considered relevant in the studies of firm growth were disregarded (FLECK, 2009). Thirdly, we took into account four theories of firm growth, thus leaving theories such as Population Ecology (HANNAN; FREEMAN, 1984HANNAN, M.; FREEMAN, J. Structural inertia and organizational change. American Sociological Review, v. 49, p. 149-164, 1984.), Evolutionary Theory of the Firm (NELSON; WINTER, 1982NELSON, R.; WINTER, S. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Belknap Press: Cambridge, 1982.), Resource-based View (BARNEY, 1991BARNEY, J. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, v.17, n.1, p. 99-120, 1991.) and Institutional Theory (SCOTT, 2001SCOTT, R. Institutions and organizations. London: Sage Publications, 2001.) out. Fourthly, our propositions covered sets of the four theories selected here therefore they cannot be taken as fully representing them. By the same token, the propositions did not provide a sharp limit between TGF and DC, which might have contributed to the tiny difference between their hit rates.

Acknolwedgements

We are grateful to the anonymous reviewers for their comments. The remaining errors are ours. Sérgio Rezende is grateful to The National Council for Scientific and Technological Development (CNPq) and Fapemig Minas Gerais State Research Foundation (FAPEMIG) for financial support.

References

  • AMIT, R.; SCHOEMAKER, P. Strategic assets and organizational rent. Strategic Management Journal, v. 14, n. 1, p. 33-46, 1993.
  • AUGIER, M; TEECE, D. Dynamic capabilities and the role of managers in business strategy and economic performance. Organization Science, v. 20, n. 2, p. 410-421, 2009.
  • ARAUJO, L.; REZENDE, S. Path dependence, MNCs and the internationalisation process: a relational approach. International Business Review, v. 12, n. 6, p. 719-737, 2003.
  • ARIKAN, A.; MCGAHAN, A. The development of capabilities in new firms. Strategic Management Journal, v. 31, p. 1-18, 2010.
  • ARTHUR, B. Competing technologies, increasing returns and lock-in by historical events. The Economic Journal, v. 99, p. 116-131, 1989.
  • BARNEY, J. Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, v.17, n.1, p. 99-120, 1991.
  • BANCO NACIONAL DE DESENVOLVIMENTO ECONÔMICO E SOCIAL. Portal Institucional. Available from: <http://www.bndes.gov.br/SiteBNDES/bndes/bndes_pt/index.html>. Acess 2011 Feb.
    » http://www.bndes.gov.br/SiteBNDES/bndes/bndes_pt/index.html>
  • BLOCH, H.; FINCH, J. Firms and industries in evolutionary economics: lessons from Marshall, Young, Steindl and Penrose. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, v. 20, n. 1, p. 139-162, 2010.
  • BLUHM, Dustin J. et al. Qualitative research in management: a decade of progress. Journal of Management Studies, v. 48, n. 8, p. 1866-1891, 2011.
  • BURGELMAN, R. Bridging history and reductionism: a key role for longitudinal qualitative research. Journal of International Business Studies, v. 42, n. 5, p. 591-601, 2011.
  • BYRNE, D.; RAGIN, C. The Sage handbook of case-based methods London: Sage, 2009.
  • CAMPBELL, T. Degrees of freedom and the case study. Comparative Political Studies, v. 8, n. 1, p. 178–193, 1975.
  • COAD, A. Testing the principle of ‘growth of the fitter": the relationship between profits and firm growth. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, v. 18, n.3, p. 370-386, 2007.
  • COAD, A. The growth of firms: a survey of theories and empirical evidences. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, 2009.
  • COAD, A. Exploring the processes of firm growth: evidence form a vector auto-regression. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 19, n. 6, p. 1667-1703, 2010.
  • COASE, R. H. The nature of the firm. Economica, v. 4, n. 16, p. 386-405, 1937.
  • CONNER, K. A historical comparison of Resource-based Theory and five schools of through within Industrial Organization Economics: do we have a new theory of theory? Journal of Management, v. 17, n. 1, p. 121-154, 1991.
  • COSTA, G.; BOENTE, D. Análise do perfil da produção científica sobre ciclo de vida no período de 2000 a 2011. Ambiente Contábil, v. 4, n. 1, p. 106-119, 2012.
  • CYERT, R.; MARCH, J. A behavioral theory of the firm. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice Hall, 1963.
  • DEMSETZ, H. The theory of the firm revisited. In: WILLIAMSON, O.; WINTER, S. (Ed.). The nature of the firm: origin, evolution and development. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991. p.159-178.
  • DI STEFANO, G.; PETERAF, M.; VERONA, G. Dynamic capabilities deconstructed: a bibliographic investigation into the origins, development, and future direction of the research domain. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 19, n. 4, p. 1187-1204, 2010.
  • DOSI, G.; LECHEVALIER, S.; SECCHI, A. Introduction: Interfirm heterogeneity – nature, sources and consequences of industrial dynamics. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 19, n. 6, p. 1867-1890, 2010.
  • DRNEVICH, P.; KRIAUCIUNAS, A. Clarifying the conditions and limits of the contributions of ordinary and dynamics capabilities to relative firm performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 32, p. 254-279, 2011.
  • DUTTA, S.; NARASHIMHAN, O.; RAJIV, S. Conceptualizing and measuring capabilities: methodology and empirical application. Strategic Management Journal, v. 26, p. 177-287, 2005.
  • EASTON, G. Case research as a method for industrial networks: a realist apologia. In: ACKROYD, S.; FLEETWOOD, S. (Orgs.). Realist perspectives on management and organizations London: Routledge, 2000. p. 178-194.
  • EISENHARDT, K.; MARTIN, J. Dynamic Capabilities: what are they? Strategic Management Journal, v. 21, n. 10-11, p. 1105-1121, 2000.
  • FLECK, D. Crescimento, dominância continuada e declínio da empresa: insights das histórias da General Electric e da Westinghouse. Revista de Administração Contemporânea, Edição Especial, p. 79-106, 2004.
  • FLECK. D. Archetypes of organizational success and failure. Brazilian Administrative Review, v. 6, n. 2, p. 78-100, 2009.
  • FLEURY, M.; FLEURY, A. Alinhando Estratégia e Competências. Revista de Administração de Empresas, v. 44, n. 1, p. 44-57, 2004.
  • FONSECA, J.; MARTINS, G. Curso de estatística São Paulo: Atlas, 1996.
  • FOSS, N. Edith Penrose: economics and strategic management. In: PITELIS, C. (Ed.). The growth of the firm: the legacy of Edith Penrose. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. p. 147-164.
  • GEORGE, A.; BENNETT, A. Case studies and theory development in the social sciences. Cambridge (Mass.): MIT Press, 2005.
  • GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: DRUID Conference on "Competencies, Governance and Entrepreneurship". Bornholm, 1998.
  • GEROSKI, P. The growth of firms in theory and in practice. In: FOSS, N.; MAHNKE, V. (Ed.). Competences, governance and entrepreneurship: advances in Strategy Research. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2000. p. 168-185.
  • GEROSKI, P.; MAZZUCATO, M. Learning and the sources of corporate growth. Industrial and Corporate Change, v. 11, n.4, p. 623-644, 2002.
  • GEROSKI, Paul A. et al. Are differences in firm size transitory or permanent? Journal of Applied Econometrics, v. 18, n. 1, p. 47-59, 2003.
  • GEROSKI, P. A.; MATA, J.; PORTUGAL, P. Founding conditions and the survival of new firms. Strategic Management Journal, v. 31, p. 510-529, 2010.
  • GRAHAM, J.; HARVEY, C.; RAJGOPAL, S. The Economic Implications of Corporate Financial Reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, v. 40, n. 1–3, p. 3–73, 2005.
  • GREINER, L. Evolution and revolution as organizations grow. Harvard Business Review, v. 50, n. 4, p. 37-46, 1972.
  • GREINER, L. Revolution is still inevitable. Harvard Business Review, v. 76, n. 3, p. 64-65, 1998.
  • Halinen, A.; Törnroos, J.; Elo, M. Network process analysis: an event-based approach to study business network dynamics. Industrial Marketing Management, v. 42, n. 8, p. 1213-1222, 2013.
  • HALINEN, A.; TORNROOS, J-A.; ELO, M. Network process analysis: an event-based approach to study business network dynamics. Industrial Marketing Management, 2013.
  • HANNAN, M.; FREEMAN, J. Structural inertia and organizational change. American Sociological Review, v. 49, p. 149-164, 1984.
  • HELFAT, C.; WINTER, S. Untangling dynamic and operational capabilities: strategy for the (n)ever-changing world. Strategic Management Journal, v. 32, p. 1243-1250, 2011.
  • HENDERSON, A.; RAYNOR, M.; AHMED, M. How long must a firm be great to rule out chance? Benchmarking sustained superior performance without being fooled by randomness. Strategic Management Journal, v. 33, n. 4, p. 387-406, 2012.
  • INSTITUTO BRASILEIRO DE GEOGRAFIA E ESTATÍSTICA. Portal Institucional. Available from: <http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/pesquisas/pesquisa_resultados.php?indicador=1&id_pesquisa=4>. Acess 2011 Feb.
    » http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/pesquisas/pesquisa_resultados.php?indicador=1&id_pesquisa=4>
  • JACOBIDES, M.; WINTER, S.; KASSBERGER, S. The dynamics of wealth, profit, and sustainable advantage. Strategic Management Journal, v. 33, p. 1384-1410, 2012.
  • JICK, T. Mixing Qualitative and quantitative methods: triangulation in action. Administrative Science Quarterly, v. 24, n. 4, p. 602-611, 1979.
  • KLANN, R. C. et al. Relação entre o ciclo de vida organizacional e o planejamento em empresas metalúrgicas do município de Brusque-SC. Revista de Contabilidade e Organizações, v. 6, n. 16, p. 119-142, 2012.
  • KOR, Y; MAHONEY, J. Penrose's resource-based approach: the process and product of research creativity. Journal of Management Studies, v. 37, n. 1, p. 109-137, 2000.
  • KUPFER, D.; HASENCLEVER, L. Economia Industrial: fundamentos teóricos e práticos no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Campus, 2002.
  • LANGLEY, A. Strategies for theorizing from process data. Academy of Management Review, v. 24, n. 4, p. 691-710, 1999.
  • LE MENS, G.; HANNAN, M.; PÓLOS, L. Founding conditions, learning, and organizational life chances: age dependence revisited. Administrative Science Quarterly, v. 56, p. 95-126, 2011.
  • LEVINTHAL, D. Random walks and organizational mortality. Administrative Science Quarterly, v. 36, p.397-420, 1991.
  • LEVINTHAL, D. Adaptation on rugged landscapes. Management Science, v. 43, n. 7, p. 934-950, 1997.
  • MAHMOOD, I.; ZHU, H.; ZAJAC, E. Where can capabilities come from? Network ties and capabilities acquisition in business groups. Strategic Management Journal, v. 32, n. 8, p. 820-848, 2011.
  • MADHOK, A.; LI, S.; PRIEM, R. The resource-based view revisited: Comparative firm advantage, willingness-based isolating mechanisms and competitive heterogeneity. European Management Review, v. 7, n. 2, p. 91-100, 2010.
  • MAKADOK, R. Toward a synthesis of the resource-based and dynamic-capability views of rent creation. Strategic Management Journal, v. 22, n. 5, p. 387-401, 2001.
  • MEYER, A.; BROOKS, G.; GOES, J. Environmental jolts and industry revolutions: organizational responses to discontinuous change. Strategic Management Journal, v. 11, p. 93-110, 1990.
  • MILLER, D.; FRIESEN, P. A longitudinal study of the corporate life cycle. Management Science, v. 30, n. 10, p. 1161-1183, 1984.
  • MUELLER, D. A life cycle theory of the firm. Journal of Industrial Economics, v. 20, n. 3, p. 199-219, 1972.
  • NECYK, G.; FREZATTI, F. A contabilidade gerencial: uma perspectiva de ciclo de vida de seu desenvolvimento nas organizações. Organização & Sociedade, v. 17, n. 55, p. 725-744, 2010.
  • NELSON, R.; WINTER, S. An evolutionary theory of economic change Belknap Press: Cambridge, 1982.
  • PENROSE, E. Foreign investment and the growth of the firm. The Economic Journal, v. 66, n. 262, p. 220-235, 1956.
  • PENROSE, E. The theory of the growth of the firm 2. ed. Oxford: Oxford Basil Blackwell, 1980.
  • PENROSE, E. Problems associated with the growth of international firms. In: PENROSE, E. The growth of firms, Middle East Oil and other essays London: Frank Cass and Company, 1971. p. 82-90.
  • PITELIS, C. On the garden of Edith: some themes. In: PITELIS, C (Ed.). The growth of the firm: the legacy of Edith Penrose Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2002. p. 1-16.
  • PITELIS, C. PITELIS, C. A behavioral resource-based view of the firm: the synergy of Cyert and March (1963) and Penrose (1959). Organization Science, v. 18, n. 3, p. 478-490, 2007.
  • POSEN, H.; LEE, J.; YI, S. The power of imperfect imitation. Strategic Management Journal, v. 34, p. 149-164, 2013.
  • POULIS, K.; POULIS, E.; PLAKOYIANNAKI, E. The role of context in case study selection: an international business perspective. International Business Review, v. 22, 304-337, 2013.
  • RICHARDSON, G. The organization of industry. The Economic Journal, v. 82, n. 327, p. 883-896, 1972.
  • ROSSETTI, J. Introdução à economia. São Paulo: Atlas, 2003.
  • RUGMAN, A.; VERBEKE, A. Edith Penrose's contribution to the resource-based view of strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 23, n. 8, p. 769-780, 2002.
  • SCOTT, R. Institutions and organizations London: Sage Publications, 2001.
  • SERRASQUEIRO, Z.; NUNES, P.; LEITÃO, J.; ARMANDA, M. Are there non-linearities between SME growth and its determinants? A quantile approach. Industrial and Corporate Change, v 19, n. 4, p. 1071-1108, 2010.
  • SLATER, M. Foreword. In: PENROSE, E. The theory of the growth of the firm Oxford: Oxford Basil Blackwell, 1980. p. vii-xxx.
  • TAN, D.; MAHONEY, J. The dynamics of Japanese firm growth in U.S. industries: the Penrose effect. Management International Review, v. 47, n. 2, p. 259-279, 2007.
  • TEECE, D. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal, v. 28, p. 1319-1350, 2007.
  • TEECE, D.; PISANO, G.; SHUEN, A. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal, v. 18, n. 7, p. 509-533, 1997.
  • VASCONCELOS, F.; CYRINO. Vantagem Competitiva. Revista de Administração de Empresas, v. 40, n. 4, p. 30-37, 2000.
  • WILLIAMSON, O. The economic institutions of capitalism New York: The Free Press, 1985.
  • WILSON, E.; WOODSIDE, A. Degrees-of-freedom analysis of case data in business marketing research. Industrial Marketing Management, v. 28, n. 3, p. 215–229, 1999.
  • WINTER, S. Capabilities: their origins and ancestry. Journal of Management Studies, v. 49, p. 1402-1406, 2012.
  • YIN, R. Estudo de caso: planejamento e métodos. Porto Alegre: Bookman, 2005.
  • ZOLLO, M.; WINTER, S. Deliberate learning and the evolution of dynamic capabilities. Organization Science, v. 13, n. 3, p. 339-351, 2002.
  • 1
    We are indebted to a reviewer for this suggestion.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Jul-Sep 2015

History

  • Received
    06 Sept 2013
  • Accepted
    28 Oct 2014
Escola de Administração da Universidade Federal da Bahia Av. Reitor Miguel Calmon, s/n 3o. sala 29, 41110-903 Salvador-BA Brasil, Tel.: (55 71) 3283-7344, Fax.:(55 71) 3283-7667 - Salvador - BA - Brazil
E-mail: revistaoes@ufba.br