Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

The Naive Central Banker

Abstracts

There has been in some countries a trend of assigning other functions to central banks besides price stability. The most suggested function to be added to monetary authority’s obligations is to pursue economic growth or full employment. In this paper we characterize the behavior and analyse the optimal monetary policy of, what we call, a naive central banker. We describe the naive behavior as one that does face the inflation-unemployment trade-off, but it tries to minimize both variables simultaneously. Our findings, both under discretion and commitment, indicate that the naive central banker delivers lower expected inflation and inflation variance than the benchmark behavior whenever the economy is rigid enough. However, the degree of conservativeness also affects this result, such that the less conservative the naive policymaker, the more rigidity is necessary.

Keywords:
Naive Central Banker; Inflationary Bias; Monetary Policy


Existe, em alguns países, uma tendência de atribuir outras funções ao banco central além da estabilização de preços. A função mais sugerida a ser incorporada nas obrigações da autoridade monetária é a perseguição do crescimento econômico ou do pleno emprego. Neste artigo caracterizamos o comportamento e analisamos a política monetária ótima do chamado banqueiro central ingênuo. Descrevemos o comportamento ingênuo como aquele que enfrenta o trade-off inflação-desemprego, mas tenta minimizar ambas variáveis simultaneamente. Nossos resultados, tanto sob discrição quanto sob commitment, indicam que o banqueiro central ingênuo gera inflação esperada e variância inflacionária menores do que o comportamento de referência, sempre que a economia apresentar rigidez suficiente. Entretanto, o grau de conservadorismo também afeta este resultado, tal que quanto menos conservador for o banqueiro ingênuo, mais rigidez é necessária.


1. INTRODUCTION

There has been in some countries a trend of assigning other functions to central banks besides price stability. This is particularly true in countries where the central banks are not independent and thus are potential targets of political pressure. The most suggested function to be added to monetary authority’s obligations is to pursue economic growth or full employment. The effects of the recent financial crisis, mainly the decreasing of GDP and the increasing of unemployment, may be considered a possible explanation for this suggestion. Based on the keynesian idea of stimulating the economy by using fiscal and monetary policy in period of crisis, some policymakers in those countries have cogitated to use the central bank as an “agent of development”.1 1 Observe that the trend we have mentioned is different from the controversy about the adoption of NGDP targeting versus price level targeting. While we are referring to a increase in the central bank’s functions-pursuing both targets, for instance-, this controversy is about choosing one of the two regimes.

The idea of central banks having to pursue economic growth is not new. While we can find the theoretical roots of such a controversy on the debate about the neutrality of money and whether monetary policy should be used to affect output, the history of central banking tells how practice has evolved over time.2 2 For more on central banking and its evolution throughout history, see Blinder (2008, 2010); Capie, Fischer, Goodhart, & Schnadt (1995); Goodhart (2011). Epstein (2005)Epstein, G. (2005). Central banks as agents of economic development. PERI Working Papers, 103., for example, presents an historically account of central bank’s action both in developed and developing countries. His conclusion is that the dominant “best practice” approach to central banking is dramatically different from the historically dominant theory and practice. In fact, it is argued all central banks have engaged in some kind of industrial policy or “selective targeting” in order to promote growth, and the only difference lies in which sector they have incentivized.

It is worthy to note the above historical view is not consentaneous. Orphanides (2012)Orphanides, A. (2012). New paradigms in central banking? Chapters in SUERF Studies, 13-32. is one of the authors which claim that throughout the existence of central banks their main objective has remained the same: stability. It is argued that what has been evolved over time is not central bank’s function or objectives but the central banker’s understanding on how to achieve and maintain stability. Even in financial crisis periods, the activist approach to monetary policy-one which wants to guide the economy towards attainment of its ideal output level-has not been the one chosen by central bankers, according to the author. Although the referred stability covers price, financial and economic dimensions, the point made is clear, namely the central bank’s behavior has changed too little over time.

However, the new trend of expanding central bank’s function is not just about making monetary policy more or less active. Instead the idea is to assign more statutory functions or goals for the central bank. This implies, for example, that promoting full employment would be in the same level of priority than pursuing price stability. One can say that a central banker who tries to achieve both targets at the same time, although he is aware about the role of the inflation-unemployment trade-off expressed by the Phillips Curve, presents a naive behavior.

But what are the economic effects of the monetary policy of a central bank which must fight inflation and stimulate output simultaneously? Literature both empirical and theoretical have not studied optimal monetary policy under those circunstances. In fact, there is a plenty of researchers exploring policies of the so called stabilizer central banker (about the nomenclature, see Griebeler, 2015Griebeler, M. d. C. (2015). On the existence of loss function for some useful classes of central bankers. International Journal of Monetary Economics and Finance, forthcoming.), whose preferences are represented by a loss function quadratic both in inflation and output (e.g. Backus & Driffill, 1985Backus, D., & Driffill, J. (1985). Inflation and reputation. American Economic Review, 75(3), 530-538.; Ball, 1995Ball, L. (1995). Time consistent inflation policy and persistent changes in inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 36(2), 329-350.; Canzoneri, 1985Canzoneri, M. (1985). Monetary policy games and the role of private information. American Economic Review, 75(4), 1056-1070.; Chari & Kehoe, 1990Chari, V., & Kehoe, P. (1990). Sustainable plans. Journal of Political Economy, 98(4), 783-802.; Cukierman & Liviatan, 1991Cukierman, A., & Liviatan, N. (1991). Optimal accommodation by strong policymakers under incomplete information. Journal of Monetary Economics, 27(1), 99-127.), in line with the seminal studies by Barro & Gordon (1983aBarro, R., & Gordon, D. (1983a). A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 589-610., 1983b)Barro, R., & Gordon, D. (1983b). Rules, discretion, and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economy, 12, 101-121.. But, to the best of our knowledge, none has considered a monetary authority which takes price and output stability as complementary targets.

In this paper we characterize the behavior and analyse the optimal monetary policy of, what we call, a naive central banker. We describe the naive behavior as one that does face the inflation-unemployment trade-off, but it tries to minimize both variables simultaneously. Specifically, it is defined as one that considers price and output stabilization as complementary “goods”. In particular, we are interested in investigating the effects on the inflationary bias under both discretion and commitment. In order to do so, we use the simple Barro–Gordon’s framework, in which the central bank must minimize its loss function subject to a Lucas’s supply curve and the rational expectations assumption. The novelty that we introduce in this context is a loss function which represents that kind of complementarity relationship. However, since our model is not dynamic, it is just a first step toward studying the effects of the naive behavior. In fact, reputation issues are out of our framework, such that we cannot study how central banker is penalized according to his choices over time.

Our main findings concern to the comparison between the results of the naive and the stabilizer central banker, our benchmark, who considers price and output stabilization as substitute goals. First, both behaviors present similarities: there is an inflationary bias, and this bias depend primarily on how conservative is the central banker. In fact, when his level of conservativeness is maximum, the bias vanishes. Second, when both policymakers act with discretion, for given level of conservativeness of both central bankers, a necessary and sufficient condition for the naive one delivers higher both expected inflation and inflation variance is that output be inelastic enough with relation to inflation surprise. Third, this result is also true under non-binding commitment, but now we have a difference, namely as the elasticity goes to infinity, inflation delivered by both central bankers converges. Finally, we compare the incentives to cheat the commitment that both face and found that, for the same 1% of deviation from the inflation target, the percentage gain in terms of welfare of the stabilizer central banker is twice as high as the gain of the naive one.

The above result indicates there is a case for the naive central banker. In fact, the naive policymaker delivers lower both expected inflation and inflation variance whenever the economy’s rigidity is high enough. By rigidity we mean mainly informational one, given we choose the Lucas supply curve, but we conjecture our results would change too little if we used a model with price or wage stickiness. Therefore, one could conclude that, in terms of inflation, it is preferable to have a naive individual conducting the monetary policy than a stabilizer one whenever such a rigidity is present in the economy. The drawback of such a conclusion is that how enough must be the economy’s rigidity depend on how conservative both central bankers are. Empirical evidence seems to indicate that a naive central banker would be a easier target of political pressure, what would reflect on a more populist behavior. Thus, the threshold of rigidity would be larger, decreasing the range in which there is a case for a naive central banker. In short, given the stabilizer central banker’s level of conservativeness, the less conservative the naive central banker, the more rigid must be the economy.

Our findings are related to all the literature about inflationary bias and the potential solutions for this problem. Besides the studies which followed the seminal model of Barro & Gordon (1983aBarro, R., & Gordon, D. (1983a). A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 589-610., 1983b)Barro, R., & Gordon, D. (1983b). Rules, discretion, and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economy, 12, 101-121., many of them mentioned in one the above paragraphs, there are several slightly modified versions of the original one which are close to our analysis. Examples are works which consider persistence in output and asymmetric preferences for the central bank (e.g. Jonsson, 1997Jonsson, G. (1997). Monetary politics and unemployment persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics, 39(2), 303-325.; Nobay & Peel, 2003Nobay, A., & Peel, D. (2003). Optimal discretionary monetary policy in a model of asymmetric central bank preferences. The Economic Journal, 113, 657-665.; Ruge-Murcia, 2003Ruge-Murcia, F. (2003). Inflation targeting under asymmetric preferences. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 35(5), 763-785.). Another branch in this literature is the modern approach provided by the New Keynesian models (e.g. Clarida, Galí, & Gertler, 1999Clarida, R., Galí, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). The science of monetary policy: A new keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 1661-1707.; Damjanovic, Damjanovic, & Nolan, 2008Damjanovic, T., Damjanovic, V., & Nolan, C. (2008). Unconditionally optimal monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(3), 491-500.; Sauer, 2010Sauer, S. (2010). When discretion is better: Initial conditions and the timeless perspective. Economics Letters, 107(2), 128-130.). However, by analysing the behavior of a specific type of central banker, our results are more close to those of Guzzo & Velasco (1999)Guzzo, V., & Velasco, A. (1999). The case for a populist central banker. European Economic Review, 43(7), 1317-1344.; Jerger (2002)Jerger, J. (2002). How strong is the case for a populist central banker? A note. European Economic Review, 46(3), 623-632.; Lippi (2002)Lippi, F. (2002). Revisiting the case for a populist central banker. European Economic Review, 46(3), 601-612., which found there is a case for a populist central banker, and Herrendorf & Lockwood (1997)Herrendorf, B., & Lockwood, B. (1997). Rogoff 's "conservative" central banker restored. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 476-495.; Rogoff (1985)Rogoff, K. (1985). The optimal commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(4), 1169-1189., which focus on the behavior of the conservative central banker. A good survey on the inflationary bias problem may be found in Walsh (2010)Walsh, C. (2010). Monetary theory and policy (3rd ed.). Cambridge: MIT Press..

This paper is organized as following. In section 2 we present the benchmark behavior, namely the stabilizer central banker’s one. We analyse his optimal monetary policy under discretion and commitment, as well as the resulting inflationary bias and its determinants. The naive central banker is characterized in section 3. We also investigate the optimal choice under discretion and commitment in this section and in the next. Thus, in section 4, inflation and output delivered by both policymakers are compared. Section 5 presents a further comparison between the naive behavior and the benchmark by analysing the elasticity of their welfare with respect to deviations from the commitment of delivering the inflation target. We make final comments regarding the limitations of our model as well as to potential extensions in section 6. Details of the results’ derivation can be found in Appendix A APPENDIX A. THE STABILIZER CENTRAL BANKER’S OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY Discretion The loss function of the stabilizer central banker as a function only of inflation is given by which yields the following first order condition (FOC): By rearranging the terms of (A-1) and using the fact of πe = π we have By substituing (A-2) into (1) we have the economy’s output: Commitment We have already seen that when the commitment is binding e = π*. Then, we have, which yields y = . On the other hand, when the commitment is not binding, the central banker’s optimization problem yields (A-1) as its FOC, but now π+∈, By substituing (A-3) into the supply curve (1), The gain of the deviation under commitment Let us calculate the elasticity ηS: , for the stabilizer central banker, and Appendix B APPENDIX B. THE NAIVE CENTRAL BANKER’S OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY The steps of the results of commitment and discretion are shown in the text. The gain of the deviation under commitment By using Proposition 2, one can see that π* is lower than πCN, such that it is in decreasing part of LN (see (10)). Thus, ∂LN=∂π = -aΦ and LN(π) = Φ|CN - π*) + ∈ - y*, which yields + a(π where we use the fact of y* > and assume that ϵ is small, since it is a shock. , for the naive one. Finally, Appendix C APPENDIX C. OMMITED PROOFS Proof. Proposition 1 (i) (ii) which implies (C-4) and then (C-5). (iii) such that a sufficient condition is Φ - λa ≥ 0, that is, a ≤ Φ/λ. (iv) By applying the L’Hôpital rule in (4), (5), (6), (8), (9), and (10) we can obtain Proof. Proposition 2 Let π1 and π2 be the solutions of π - π* = Φ[* + a(π-πe)+∈] and π - π*=-Φ[* + a(π-πe)+∈], respectively. For given π*, y*, a, Φ and πe, it suffices to show that |π1 - π*|>|π2 - π*|, because |πi - π*|= Φ|yi - y*| for i = 1,2. We already computed π2 when we solved the model with discretion, such that π2 = πD, given by (11). For π1, we have - y-y When one solves for π1, one obtains Then, by subtracting π* of both sides and taking the absolute value, it results in For π2, observe that we can once again subtract π* in both sides of (11) and then take the absolute value, such that Now, given that |x|=|-x| for all x, the numerators of (C-6) and (C-7) are equal. Still, recall that Φa>0, such that |1-Φa|<|1+Φa|. Therefore, |π2-π*|<|π1-π*|, which implies that L(π2;y2)<L(π1;y1). Proof. Proposition 3 (i) (ii) presents the propositions’ proofs omitted throughout the text, and Appendix D APPENDIX D. GRAPHICS Figure D-1 Gráficos. shows some graphics of our findings.

2. THE BENCHMARK CASE: THE STABILIZER CENTRAL BANKER

We follow literature by assuming that central banker has preferences over only two variables, namely inflation, π, and output, y. Let Π and Y be the subsets of π,y) ∈ Π × Y3 Before we introduce the naive central banker, we define the benchmark case for future comparisons. Our choice is the so called stabilizer central banker, the most common behavior used in the literature. This kind of central banker wishes to minimize deviations of inflation from its target and of output from its social optimal level. These two goal are considered substitutes and the central banker gives different weights to each one in its loss function. Formally, we can use the definition suggested by Griebeler (2015)Griebeler, M. d. C. (2015). On the existence of loss function for some useful classes of central bankers. International Journal of Monetary Economics and Finance, forthcoming.:, then (× .

Definition 1. Let λ be a parameter that measures the relative weight given to output y, y* be the output target, π be the inflation, and π*be the inflation target. e define preferences of a stabilizer central banker as (π1,y1) π2,y2) if and only if |π1π*| + λ |y1y*| ≤ |π2π*| + λ|y2y*|.STA (

It is possible to show (Griebeler, 2015Griebeler, M. d. C. (2015). On the existence of loss function for some useful classes of central bankers. International Journal of Monetary Economics and Finance, forthcoming.) that preferences like those defined above have an utility representation. Due to the non-smoothness of the absolute value function, it is useful to adopt the following well known functional form to represent them:

As usual, throughout the paper, we assume policymaker’s choices are constrained by a Lucas supply curve, given by

where is a supply shock, with mean and variance given by a is a measure of output’s sensitiveness with respect to inflation surprise. Assume we are considering variables in log, then a is the output’s elasticity with respect to (π − πe). Furthermore, in order to have a source of inflationary bias in our model, we assume that y* > Kydland & Prescott (1977)Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. The Journal of Political Economy, 473-491., for example. With those assumption we are able to analyse optimal monetary policy., respectively. The parameter is the inflation expectation, is the potential level of output (of long run), , by the reasons suggested by and

2.1. Discretion

There is no uncertainty in our model, such that we can think of policymaker as choosing inflation directly. Thus, when central banker chooses inflation taking inflation expectation as given, his optimal choice results in

Some conclusions may be drawn from (2) and (3). First, under discretion, there is an inflationary bias and its magnitude is given by a, the higher the volatility of inflation is. The same is true about parameter λ. Once again, an ultra conservative central banker yields inflation’s variance equal to zero. Finally, by substituing πDS into (1), we find that πSD. and . Therefore, the bias is determined by three factors: how high is the social optimal output in relation to the potential level, the degree of conservativeness of the policymaker, and the output’s elasticity with respect to inflation surprise. Still, an ultra conservative central banker (λ = 0) is a sufficient condition to vanish the bias. Second, the higher the value of , that is, there is no gain in terms of output by implementing

The value of the stabilizer central banker’s expected loss under discretion is

2.2. Commitment

Suppose now that the stabilizer central banker makes a binding commitment about what inflation will be before expected inflation is determined. Since the commitment is binding, πe = π, which implies y = and thus the policymaker’s problem is to minimize π. The solution is simply . However, the central banker could make an announcement of pursuing a determined level of inflation and then does not fullfill his promise. The reason for such a behavior is to create an inflation surprise and hence to increase output above its potential level. by choosing +

Lets investigate what the stabilizer central banker gains by cheating the public. Suppose that his announcement makes πe = π*, such that now its optimal expected inflation and variance are given by

We can use the expressions above to find the expected output and its variance:

The gain of cheating can be seen in terms of welfare,

because . So, there exists an incentive to the stabilizer central banker to create inflation surprise. In fact, it is possible to see that and the higher the output’s variance are., which yields the improvement in his welfare. We will return to this topic later, when this incentive will be compared to one of the naive central banker. Also, observe the role of the degree of conservativeness of the stabilizer central banker in the output’s behavior: the lower λ (more conservative) is, the lower the difference

3. THE NAIVE CENTRAL BANKER

We call a naive behavior one which considers stabilization of price and output complementary goals of policy. The reason for this name is that a central banker with such a behavior, even though knows the trade-off between the two goals, he tries to achieve them simultaneously. A naive central banker therefore prefers a state of the economy, defined by a pair (π,y), to another if and only if both inflation and output are closer to their targets. Formally:

Definition 2. Let π* and y* be the inflation and the output desired by society, respectively. We define the preference of a naive central banker, N, by: (π1,y1) N (π2,y2) if and only if max{|π1π*|,Φ|y1y*|} ≤ max{|π2π*|,Φ|y2y*|}, where Φ is a constant which indicates the degree of complementarity between price and output stabilizations.

Definition 2 clearly satisfies transitivity, completeness and continuity such that there exists a continuous utility function which represent such a preference. In fact, the behavior described above is similar to that of consumer choosing his bundle with two complementary goods. Thus, a function of Leontief’s type may be a good choice to represent it.4 4 More on preferences that can be representad by a Leontief utility function, see Voorneveld (2014). Observe, however, that, since there is a point of satiety, (π*,y*), the indifference curves will be rectangles rather than the traditional “L” shape. Following the literature, we study the minimization problem of the central banker, such that N may be represented by a loss (disutility) function:

In some examples in the next sections we will assume Φ = 1, what we consider the most intuitive case and the nearest of the behavior described in the introduction, because the central banker gives the same weight to both targets. Nevertheless, our general form (7) allows different degrees of complementarity between inflation and output targets. In the rest of the paper we will say the higher the value of Φ, the less conservative (the more populist) the naive central banker is. The reason for adopting such an informal definition is explained by an example. Consider two different naive central bankers, one with Φ = 1 and other with Φ' = 2. For the same pair (π,y), the banker with Φ' = 2 always earns twice as much disutility than the one with Φ = 1. In fact, in the example they will achieve the same welfare only if output deviation of Φ' is the half of the deviation of Φ. In short, the higher the value of Φ, the more weight is given to output stabilization by the naive central banker.

It is trivial to see that (7) does formally represent N. An example is helpful to show intuitively that the naive behavior described in the introduction is well described by N (and then by (7)). Suppose that π* = y* = 2, Φ = 1, and there are two available bundles, (1,1) and (1,1.5). By applying the definition of N, we have (1,1) ∼N (1, 1.5), which means that the naive central banker is indifferent between a pair of inflation and output in which both deviate 1 from their targets and a pair in which inflation deviates 1 and output deviates 0.5. This is exactly the essence of the behavior which “ignores” inflation-output trade-off: his welfare only increases when both aims approach their targets simultaneously, such that there is no opportunity of substitution between them. In contrast, (1, 1.5) S (1,1), because the stabilizer behavior does consider price and output stabilization as substitutes. In short, N is a suitable way of capturing such a naive behavior. However, we can also show that the representation by (7) is not unique, such that N as well. Our choice by (7) is due to its straightforward interpretation, since absolute value is a measure of deviation. Moreover, the advantage in terms of differentiability presented by N is needless, because the maximum function is already non-smooth. represents

Given that central banker’s preferences are represented by a loss function rather than an utility one, his problem is a minimization:

To learn more about the behavior of the naive central banker, lets show that he faces an incentive to choose inflation higher than π* in order to try to cause inflation surprise and then to affect positively the output. Suppose that people believe in the central banker’s announcement that inflation target will be surely achieved, such that their inflation expectation is πe = π*. Further, suppose that the central banker does have discretion. Thus the Lucas supply curve (1) becomes y = a(ππ*)+, such that the central banker’s problem as function only of π is LN(π,y(π)) = max{|π − π*|,Φ|y* + a(π − π*) + |}. The optimal inflation satisfies |π − π*|= Φ|y* + a(π − π*)+ | and then we would have to consider two cases: π − π* = Φ[y* + a(π − π*) + ] and π − π* = −Φ [y* + a(π − π*) + ]. +

Figura 1 plots the rectangle of indifferences of the naive central banker and the Lucas supply curve. First, observe that the “smaller” is the rectangle-namely, its area-the lower is the loss, such that the minimum of L(π,y) occurs in (π* , y*). In addition, the degree of complementarity affects both height and width of the rectangles. Since Φ multiplies the term of output stabilization in (7), for given π* and y*, the higher Φ, the lower the height of the rectangles is. We can see that by observing that, for a fixed π0, the height of the rectangle is h(π0) = 2(π*π0), such that limΦ≥→∞ h(π0) = 0. On the other hand, the higher Φ, the higher the width is: for a fixed y0, the width of the rectangle is w(y0) = 2Φ(y*y0), such that limΦ≥→ w(y0) = → (assuming y* >y0).

Figure 1
Rectangles of indifference of the naive central banker.

By determining the perimeter of the rectangles of indifference, its height and width determine also how many differents pairs of inflation and output yield the same welfare for the banker. A higher perimeter offers more options for a given level of disutility. Therefore, it is fundamental to know how conservative is the naive central banker in order to study his avaiable choices. For example, for a central banker with Φ = 2, 1% of inflation deviation from its target yields the same loss that any value up to 0.5% of output deviation from its desirable level. Alternatively, if Φ = , the loss yielded by 1% of deviation in inflation is the same of any deviation in output up to 2%.

Second, as the supply curve is upward-sloping, one can wonder whether the solution of the constrained problem may be any of four corners of the rectangles. The two cases we have to analyse are:

In the next section we explore both cases and show which one will occur (see Proposition 2 below). For now, assume the case (ii) as true, such that π − π* = −Φ[y* + a(π − π*) + ]. Then, the optimal (expected) inflation and its variance are given by

where one can see that there exists inflationary bias, because y* > . This inflation surprise makes (expected) output be above its potential level:

The expected central banker’s loss in this setting is then5 5 There is no closed form for . By doing so, we have . However, given that the absolute value is a convex function, we can apply the Jensen inequality and obtain a lower bound for . Thus,

The above results can be compared to those of the stabilizer central banker under the same conditions (non-binding commitment). For example, by comparing expected inflation and its variance, we find that Φ − λa ≥ 0. This same condition also plays an important role when we compare the results related to output and its variability. Proposition 1 below brings more details about such a comparison. if and only if

Proposition 1. Under non-binding commitment, the following statements are true:

One way to interpret the results of Proposition 1 is by assuming that both levels of conservativeness, λ and Φ, are fixed, such that relevant parameter for the analysis is the output’s elasticity with respect to inflation surprise, a. Thus, a necessary and sufficient condition for the naive central banker to deliver expected inflation and inflation variance higher than the stabilizer one is that the elasticity a be low enough. If, for instance, both central bankers have the same degree of conservativeness-even though their measures are not perfectly comparable-, such that Φ/λ = 1, then such a condition becomes: output has to be inelastic with relation to inflation surprise. Note also that the same condition is only sufficient for the expected output delivered by the naive central banker be higher than one delivered by the stabilizer one.

Another important point to note in the above results is that, despite the fact of high values of a implies both a increases the difference between the inflation results of both policymakers tends to zero. This means that, as the benefit of inflation surprise becomes greater, the behavior of both central bankers related to inflation converges. The same is not true about output: in many cases, for low enough values of a, the naive delivers higher output; for “intermediate” values, the stabilizer is who delivers higher output; and, as a increases (and exceeds a given value 6 6 To be more precise, the behavior of a = 0 and Figure D-1c, for example, we have the case of two different real roots (Φ/λ = 1 and Φ/λ< 1) and the case of complex roots (Φ/λ > 1). depends on the values of all parameters in the model. In fact, , such that its roots are which can be either real (either a single or two differents) or complex. In One can visualize those results in figures D-1a, D-1b, D-1c, and D-1d in Appendix D APPENDIX A. THE STABILIZER CENTRAL BANKER’S OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY Discretion The loss function of the stabilizer central banker as a function only of inflation is given by which yields the following first order condition (FOC): By rearranging the terms of (A-1) and using the fact of πe = π we have By substituing (A-2) into (1) we have the economy’s output: Commitment We have already seen that when the commitment is binding e = π*. Then, we have, which yields y = . On the other hand, when the commitment is not binding, the central banker’s optimization problem yields (A-1) as its FOC, but now π+∈, By substituing (A-3) into the supply curve (1), The gain of the deviation under commitment Let us calculate the elasticity ηS: , where are shown the differences a. We also consider three possible cases: Φ/λ = 1, Φ/λ > 1 and Φ/λ < 1., as and and ) the naive again delivers higher output., respectively, as a function of

4. OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

4.1. Discretion

Under discretion, central banker chooses inflation taking expectations of inflation as given. Substituing (1) into (7), we have the unconstrained problem of minimization L(π) = max{|π − π*|, Φ|y*+ a(π − πe) + |}. The solution is given by the points that satisfy |π − π*|= Φ|y*+ a(π − πe)+ |. There are two possibilities to consider (cases (i) and (ii) in section 3). Proposition 2 states that the optimum always occurs either π > π* and y < y* or π < π* and y > y*. Undoubtedly, the most commom situation in practice is inflation higher than its target and output lower than its potential level, which henceforth we assume as true.

Proposition 2. Consider the two possible cases of solution of |π − π*|= Φ|y*+ a(π − πe)+ |, namely (i) π − π* = Φ[y − y* + a(π − πe)+ ] and (ii) π − π* = −Φ[y*+ a(π − πe)+ ]. Then, case (ii) always gives the minimun loss for the naive central banker.

By using the result above, we may obtain the inflation as a function of public’s expectation,

With rational expectations, people form their expectations by knowing central banker’s incentive to stimulate inflation surprise, such that πe = π. By substituing this into (11), we obtain the (expected) inflation of equilibrium and its variance:

Still, the expected output of equilibrium under dicretion is equal to its potential level, ., and its variance is

The results of the naive central banker under discretion are quite similar to those yielded by the stabilizer one. First, observe that there is an inflationary bias as well, and its magnitude also depends on both how higher is the social optimal level output compared to the long run level and the degree of conservativeness. The difference is in the absence of the output elasticity with respect to inflation surprise. Still, an ultra conservative central banker (Φ = 0) delivers the expected inflation equal to the inflation target. Second, the same can be said about the determinants of the inflation variance. Finally, given the assumption of rational expectations, inflation is completely antecipated by the agents, and the expected output is equal to its level of long run.

We can compute the welfare of the naive central banker under discretion, which is given by

Clearly, we have , which implies that there is a worsening in the policymaker’s welfare with relation to the setting under ono-binding commitment.

Proposition 3. Under discretion, the following statements are true:

It is possible to see Proposition 3 is based on the same condition of Proposition 1 and presents similar results. Therefore, the interpretation of itens (i) and (ii) of both are almost the same. The only difference is the fact of inflation and output now are yielded when policymakers act with discretion rather than with non-binding commitment. However, Proposition 3 no longer states convergence between expected inflations and inflation variances. In fact, as we can see in Figure D-1e in Appendix D APPENDIX A. THE STABILIZER CENTRAL BANKER’S OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY Discretion The loss function of the stabilizer central banker as a function only of inflation is given by which yields the following first order condition (FOC): By rearranging the terms of (A-1) and using the fact of πe = π we have By substituing (A-2) into (1) we have the economy’s output: Commitment We have already seen that when the commitment is binding e = π*. Then, we have, which yields y = . On the other hand, when the commitment is not binding, the central banker’s optimization problem yields (A-1) as its FOC, but now π+∈, By substituing (A-3) into the supply curve (1), The gain of the deviation under commitment Let us calculate the elasticity ηS: , as a goes to infinity, goes to −→, that is, the inflation delivered by the stabilizer central banker becomes infinitely higher than one delivered by the naive one. The same is true about the variance. Mathematically, this difference is evident, because now we have monotonic functions while with commitment they present increasing and decreasing intervals.

The reason for the absence of convergence between inflations under discretion is on the features of both central bankers’ behavior. Recall that under discretion the expected inflation delivered by the stabilizer policymaker, given by (2), depends on the output’s elasticity with respect to inflation surprise. As he chooses inflation taking the inflation expectation as given, the higher the elasticity, the more the marginal gain of the inflation surprise in terms of output. Thus, as a increases, his inflation is higher with the aim of creating inflation surprise. On the other hand, the inflation delivered by the naive policymaker does not depend on a, what we can see in (12). As this central banker does not improve his welfare by substituting price level by output, a higher elasticity would improve y but also would not changed π, what would let his welfare unchanged. Therefore, his incentive to create inflation surprise is not affected by changes in the elasticity.

4.2. Commitment

We have already seen the results of both central bankers under commitment, but it is worthy to take a deeper look in the naive behavior in this setting, given its singular features. Recall that, under commitment, the central banker’s promise of pursuing the inflation target is credible, such that πe = π = π* and there is no inflationary bias. In this case, the expected output is equal to its potential level as well. By keeping its promise, the monetary authority’s expected loss is then π,y). In order to see this, observe that now the supply curve is just y = , such that it is represented by a horizontal line in the plane π − y.. In addition, the characteristics of the naive behavior make this same welfare be achieved for infinitely many other pairs ( +

As Figura 2 shows, the fact of the naive central banker has rectangles of indiference implies there is a line segment in which the supply curve coincides with the loss function’s level curve. Therefore, there is a continuum of inflation levels which yields the same loss that the inflation target does. In fact, notice that inflation target is the center of the interval [πMIN,πMAX]. We must characterize it, especially with respect to its width and its determinants. In order to do so, we first have to find the value of its endpoints. Note that πMIN < π and πMAX > π, such that the first one fits item (i) and the second fits item (ii) of Proposition 2. Therefore, they must satisfy

Figure 2
Naive behavior under commitment.

where we use the fact of y = y*. <

This first analysis, however, may be misleading, because it might indicate that the naive central banker can choose any inflation in the range [πMIN, πMAX] without changing the slope of the supply curve and thus letting his welfare be unchanged. Recall that his optimization problem is constrained by (1), such that its slope changes whenever πeπ. Therefore, if the central banker chooses ππ* and public believes that the commitment is binding, the supply curve satisfies (11), which is no longer a horizontal line. This implies that every deviation of his announcement has gain (or cost) in terms of welfare. In fact, any policy deviation makes the analysis of section 3 the most suitable, as we have seen. Nevertheless, the shape of the indifference curves of the naive central banker seems to indicate that small deviations might cause little changes in LN(π,y), given that the slope of (11) would change little as well. The next section studies the gain of the deviation and compares the results of the naive central banker with our benchmark case.

5. THE GAIN OF DEVIATION UNDER COMMITMENT

As we have seen, the shape of indifference curves of the naive central banker seems to indicate that small deviations from the commitment π = π* causes small changes in his welfare. However, it is necessary to use our benchmark case in order to define what we are calling “small changes”. In this section we use two measures to evaluate the incentives that both policymakers face to cheat the public. The first one is the optimal deviation: how much the central banker would deviate from the inflation target, once he has assumed the commitment of pursuing it, if he made his choice by maximizing his welfare.

Let di = π − π* be the deviation from the inflation target under commitment for i = S,N. Observe that we can write Li in terms of d, which gives us the following expression for the stabilizer:

This quadratic function reaches its minimum when dS = aλ[(y*]/(1 + λa2), the same value of πCS − π* . In other words, the optimal deviation for the stabilizer central banker is just the value of the inflationary bias yielded when he adopts πSC. Similarly, for the naive one we have LN (d)= max{|d|, Φ|y* + ad + |}, which reaches its minimum when dN = Φ[(y*]/(1 + Φa). Once again, the optimal deviation is given by the bias obtained when the policymaker adopts his optimal policy under (non-binding) commitment, πNC.) − ) −

There is no novelty in the above analysis: the naive central banker will choose an inflation which yields a higher deviation (bias) than one adopted by the stabilizer if and only if Φ − λa > 0. We have already obtained such a result in section 3, which may make us to think that, whenever the mentioned condition is satisfied, the naive central banker has more incentive to deviate than the stabilizer. However, this measure accounts for the absolute magnitude of the central bankers’ welfare. As the functional forms of the loss functions are different from each other, it is not possible to compare the values of LS with LN. We need a measure which considers welfare but not in absolute terms.

We can use the idea of elasticity in order to overcome the aforementioned difficult. We must answer the following question: under (non-binding) commitment, what is the percentage change in the central banker’s welfare if inflation increases one percent? When we evaluate this elasticity at the point π = π*, we have a measure of the incentive to deviate from the inflation target, independent of the absolute magnitude of the central banker’s loss. Then, define

as the elasticity, for i = S,N. Recall that the derivative is evaluated in πe = π* and πCi is given by either (4) or (8).

Our results indicate that the stabilizer central banker has a welfare improvement higher than the naive one for the same 1% deviation from the inflation target:

Observe that the magnitude of the ηi is primarily determined by a and π*: the more elastic the output to inflation surprise, the higher ηi is; similarly, the higher the inflation target, the higher ηi is. Furthermore, one can see that those elasticities do not depend on the conservativeness of the policymakers.

The conclusion of this section confirms what the graphical analysis of section 4 suggests, namely that the incentives for the naive central banker deviates from the commitment are lower than those of the stabilizer one. In fact, the result obtained here is even stronger: it states that, for the same 1% of deviation, the response (in percentage) of the welfare of the former is twice higher than the response of the latter. Moreover, this finding is independent of how conservative both policymakers are. Once again, the main reason for such a difference is on the nature of the naive behavior, since that it does not substitute price by output stabilization, which implies in low gains of creating inflation surprise.

6. CONCLUDING REMARKS

There is a case for a naive central banker. Whenever the supply curve’s slope is large enough, the naive policymaker delivers both expected inflation and inflation variance lower than the stabilizer one. If both types present the same level of conservativeness (Φ/λ = 1), for example, such a condition is just that the output be inelastic with respect to inflation surprise. In order to have more economic intuiton, we must then analyse what are the determinants of this elasticity. Given that we adopt the Lucas supply curve, the underlying framework of our model is based on the assumption of information rigidity. Therefore, the more rigid the information, the slower the adjust process in the economy, and the more inelastic the output with respect to inflation surprise (the higher the supply curve’s slope). Therefore, the case for the naive central banker requires that the economy presents enough information rigidity. In addition, we conjecture that this result does not change when one adopts assumption of price or wage stickiness.

Because rigidity is a relatively common feature of many modern economies, a natural conclusion would be that many central banks should be headed by a naive individual. Yet, there is no empirical evidence of this fact. In fact, it is only possible to find few researchers and politicians which recommend such an option. Our conjecture for this absence is that a naive central banker will in general be more populist than the stabilizer one. The reason is on the nature of the naive behavior, described in section 3, which is more subject to political pressures. Then, the more populist (the less conservative) the naive relative to the stabilizer, the more rigid the economy must be for the naive central banker delivers inflation lower than the stabilizer one. For example, as we have seen, if Φ/λ = 1, then the condition is a 1, but if Φ/λ = 4, then the output should be four times more inelastic than the previous case. In short, the more populist the naive central banker, the “weaker” the case for him.

As the remainder literature on inflationary bias, our model can be extended by considering that the central banker chooses inflation indirectly through his instruments (money supply, for instance). This extension would improve the discussion about rules and discretion in monetary policy, virtually absent in our analysis. A richer modification in our original framework would allow us to build our results on a New Keynesian approach. By adopting such an alternative, we would be able to study the behavior of interest rate, inflation and output simultaneously. In addition, if the chosen model were a DSGE, one would be possible to consider long run effects as well as impacts of other shocks on the naive behavior. However, we believe that the main contribution of adopting such models is to overcome the limitation imposed by the lack of dynamics. By using the New Keynesian framework, it is possible to study reputation issues and how penalizations can affect the behavior of the naive central banker over time. We conjecture that this modification would make the results of both types of central bankers (naive and stabilizer) even more similar, because the effects of reputation incentives. Yet, this extension may not be so direct, given the non-smoothness of the loss function, but it would add realism on the monetary policy analysis and would make the results closer to the state of the art in monetary theory. Finally, our results would be enriched if we added issues concerning to labor market, for example, like those studies of Guzzo & Velasco (1999)Guzzo, V., & Velasco, A. (1999). The case for a populist central banker. European Economic Review, 43(7), 1317-1344.; Jerger (2002)Jerger, J. (2002). How strong is the case for a populist central banker? A note. European Economic Review, 46(3), 623-632.; Lippi (2002)Lippi, F. (2002). Revisiting the case for a populist central banker. European Economic Review, 46(3), 601-612..

  • 1
    Observe that the trend we have mentioned is different from the controversy about the adoption of NGDP targeting versus price level targeting. While we are referring to a increase in the central bank’s functions-pursuing both targets, for instance-, this controversy is about choosing one of the two regimes.
  • 2
    For more on central banking and its evolution throughout history, see Blinder (2008Blinder, A. S. (2008). The quiet revolution: Central banking goes modern. Yale University Press., 2010)Blinder, A. S. (2010). How central should the central bank be? Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 123-133.; Capie, Fischer, Goodhart, & Schnadt (1995)Capie, F., Fischer, S., Goodhart, C., & Schnadt, N. (1995). The future of central banking. Cambridge Books.; Goodhart (2011)Goodhart, C. A. E. (2011). The changing role of central banks. Financial History Review, 18(02), 135-154..
  • 3
    Our results may be easily generalized to choice sets of any finite dimension. For example, they may apply to a central banker with preferences over inflation, output and exchange rate.
  • 4
    More on preferences that can be representad by a Leontief utility function, see Voorneveld (2014)Voorneveld, M. (2014). From preferences to Leontief utility. Economic Theory Bulletin, 1-8..
  • 5
    There is no closed form for . By doing so, we have . However, given that the absolute value is a convex function, we can apply the Jensen inequality and obtain a lower bound for . Thus,
  • 6
    To be more precise, the behavior of a = 0 and Figure D-1c, for example, we have the case of two different real roots (Φ/λ = 1 and Φ/λ< 1) and the case of complex roots (Φ/λ > 1). depends on the values of all parameters in the model. In fact, , such that its roots are which can be either real (either a single or two differents) or complex. In

APPENDIX A. THE STABILIZER CENTRAL BANKER’S OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

Discretion

The loss function of the stabilizer central banker as a function only of inflation is given by

which yields the following first order condition (FOC):

By rearranging the terms of (A-1) and using the fact of πe = π we have

By substituing (A-2) into (1) we have the economy’s output:

Commitment

We have already seen that when the commitment is binding e = π*. Then, we have, which yields y = . On the other hand, when the commitment is not binding, the central banker’s optimization problem yields (A-1) as its FOC, but now π+∈,

By substituing (A-3) into the supply curve (1),

The gain of the deviation under commitment

Let us calculate the elasticity ηS:

APPENDIX B. THE NAIVE CENTRAL BANKER’S OPTIMAL MONETARY POLICY

The steps of the results of commitment and discretion are shown in the text.

The gain of the deviation under commitment

By using Proposition 2, one can see that π* is lower than πCN, such that it is in decreasing part of LN (see (10)). Thus, ∂LN=∂π = -aΦ and LN(π) = Φ|CN - π*) + ∈ - y*, which yields + a(π

where we use the fact of y* > and assume that ϵ is small, since it is a shock.

APPENDIX C. OMMITED PROOFS

Proof. Proposition 1

(i)

(ii)

which implies (C-4) and then (C-5).

(iii)

such that a sufficient condition is Φ - λa ≥ 0, that is, a ≤ Φ/λ.

(iv) By applying the L’Hôpital rule in (4), (5), (6), (8), (9), and (10) we can obtain

Proof. Proposition 2

Let π1 and π2 be the solutions of π - π* = Φ[* + a(π-πe)+∈] and π - π*=-Φ[* + a(π-πe)+∈], respectively. For given π*, y*, a, Φ and πe, it suffices to show that |π1 - π*|>|π2 - π*|, because |πi - π*|= Φ|yi - y*| for i = 1,2. We already computed π2 when we solved the model with discretion, such that π2 = πD, given by (11). For π1, we have - y-y

When one solves for π1, one obtains

Then, by subtracting π* of both sides and taking the absolute value, it results in

For π2, observe that we can once again subtract π* in both sides of (11) and then take the absolute value, such that

Now, given that |x|=|-x| for all x, the numerators of (C-6) and (C-7) are equal. Still, recall that Φa>0, such that |1-Φa|<|1+Φa|. Therefore, |π2*|<|π1*|, which implies that L(π2;y2)<L1;y1).

Proof. Proposition 3

(i)

(ii)

APPENDIX D. GRAPHICS

Figure D-1
Gráficos.

REFERENCES

  • Backus, D., & Driffill, J. (1985). Inflation and reputation. American Economic Review, 75(3), 530-538.
  • Ball, L. (1995). Time consistent inflation policy and persistent changes in inflation. Journal of Monetary Economics, 36(2), 329-350.
  • Barro, R., & Gordon, D. (1983a). A positive theory of monetary policy in a natural rate model. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 589-610.
  • Barro, R., & Gordon, D. (1983b). Rules, discretion, and reputation in a model of monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economy, 12, 101-121.
  • Blinder, A. S. (2008). The quiet revolution: Central banking goes modern Yale University Press.
  • Blinder, A. S. (2010). How central should the central bank be? Journal of Economic Literature, 48(1), 123-133.
  • Canzoneri, M. (1985). Monetary policy games and the role of private information. American Economic Review, 75(4), 1056-1070.
  • Capie, F., Fischer, S., Goodhart, C., & Schnadt, N. (1995). The future of central banking. Cambridge Books
  • Chari, V., & Kehoe, P. (1990). Sustainable plans. Journal of Political Economy, 98(4), 783-802.
  • Clarida, R., Galí, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). The science of monetary policy: A new keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, 37, 1661-1707.
  • Cukierman, A., & Liviatan, N. (1991). Optimal accommodation by strong policymakers under incomplete information. Journal of Monetary Economics, 27(1), 99-127.
  • Damjanovic, T., Damjanovic, V., & Nolan, C. (2008). Unconditionally optimal monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(3), 491-500.
  • Epstein, G. (2005). Central banks as agents of economic development. PERI Working Papers, 103.
  • Goodhart, C. A. E. (2011). The changing role of central banks. Financial History Review, 18(02), 135-154.
  • Griebeler, M. d. C. (2015). On the existence of loss function for some useful classes of central bankers. International Journal of Monetary Economics and Finance, forthcoming
  • Guzzo, V., & Velasco, A. (1999). The case for a populist central banker. European Economic Review, 43(7), 1317-1344.
  • Herrendorf, B., & Lockwood, B. (1997). Rogoff 's "conservative" central banker restored. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 476-495.
  • Jerger, J. (2002). How strong is the case for a populist central banker? A note. European Economic Review, 46(3), 623-632.
  • Jonsson, G. (1997). Monetary politics and unemployment persistence. Journal of Monetary Economics, 39(2), 303-325.
  • Kydland, F. E., & Prescott, E. C. (1977). Rules rather than discretion: The inconsistency of optimal plans. The Journal of Political Economy, 473-491.
  • Lippi, F. (2002). Revisiting the case for a populist central banker. European Economic Review, 46(3), 601-612.
  • Nobay, A., & Peel, D. (2003). Optimal discretionary monetary policy in a model of asymmetric central bank preferences. The Economic Journal, 113, 657-665.
  • Orphanides, A. (2012). New paradigms in central banking? Chapters in SUERF Studies, 13-32.
  • Rogoff, K. (1985). The optimal commitment to an intermediate monetary target. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100(4), 1169-1189.
  • Ruge-Murcia, F. (2003). Inflation targeting under asymmetric preferences. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 35(5), 763-785.
  • Sauer, S. (2010). When discretion is better: Initial conditions and the timeless perspective. Economics Letters, 107(2), 128-130.
  • Voorneveld, M. (2014). From preferences to Leontief utility. Economic Theory Bulletin, 1-8.
  • Walsh, C. (2010). Monetary theory and policy (3rd ed.). Cambridge: MIT Press.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Apr-Jun 2015
Fundação Getúlio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 11º andar, 22253-900 Rio de Janeiro RJ Brazil, Tel.: +55 21 3799-5831 , Fax: +55 21 2553-8821 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: rbe@fgv.br