Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Investors’ Heterogeneous Preferences for Structured Financial Products in China: The Impact of Demographic Characteristics

Abstract

Purpose

Structured financial products (SPs) have become very popular with retail investors in recent years. Investors’ preferences play a critical role when investing in SPs. The objective of this study is to understand SP investment behavior by investigating Chinese investors’ heterogeneous preferences for choosing wealth management products (WMPs) with certain attributes.

Theoretical framework

Investors with different demographic characteristics show different preferences in their SP investments.

Design/methodology/approach

We employ the choice experiment (CE) method and examine preference heterogeneity using the multinomial logit (MNL) and the mixed logit (MXL) models.

Findings

(i) The attributes of small bank, minimum amount, non-guaranteed floating return and guaranteed floating return significantly affect the choice when purchasing WMPs. (ii) There are significant heterogeneous preferences for minimum amount. (iii) These four characters are the sources of heterogeneous preferences for minimum amount.

Practical & social implications of research

This information can contribute to understanding the heterogeneous preferences of investors, which can help in designing marketable WMPs to target different kinds of investors.

Originality/value

The main contribution of the research is it examines investors’ heterogeneous preferences for SPs. The study provides empirical evidence of which attributes of structured products significantly affect investor preferences. It also reveals which characteristics of investors affect their heterogeneous preferences.

Keywords:
Structured financial products; heterogeneous preferences; choice experiments; mixed logit model; behavior

Resumo

Objetivo

Os produtos financeiros estruturados (SPs) tornaram-se muito populares entre os investidores de varejo nos últimos anos. A preferência dos investidores desempenha um papel crítico para investir em SPs. O objetivo deste estudo é entender o comportamento de investimento nos SPs investigando as preferências heterogêneas dos investidores chineses para a escolha de WMPs com determinados atributos.

Referencial teórico

Os investidores com diferentes características demográficas apresentam diferentes preferências em seus investimentos em SPs.

Metodologia

Empregamos o método de experimentos de escolha (CE) e examinamos a heterogeneidade de preferência usando os modelos logit multinomial (MNL) e logit misto (MXL).

Resultados

(i) Os atributos “banco pequeno”, “valor mínimo”, “retorno variável não garantido” e “retorno variável garantido” afetam significativamente a escolha de compra dos WMPs. (ii) Existem preferências heterogêneas significativas por valor mínimo. (iii) Esses quatro elementos são as fontes de preferência heterogênea por valor mínimo.

Implicações práticas e sociais da pesquisa

A pesquisa oferece informações que podem contribuir para a compreensão das preferências heterogêneas das características dos investidores, o que pode ajudar a desenvolver WMPs comercializáveis para atingir diferentes tipos de investidores.

Contribuições

A principal contribuição da pesquisa é examinar as preferências heterogêneas dos investidores por SPs. O estudo fornece evidências empíricas de quais atributos de produtos estruturados afetam significativamente as preferências dos investidores. Também revela quais características dos investidores afetam suas preferências heterogêneas.

Palavras-chave:
Produtos financeiros estruturados; preferências heterogêneas; experimentos de escolha; modelo logit misto; comportamento

1 Introduction

Structured financial products (SPs) are a class of financial products that pay on maturity a return that depends in a predefined way on the trajectory of one or more underlying assets (Rieger, 2012Rieger, M. O. (2012). Why do investors buy bad financial products? Probability misestimation and preferences in financial investment decision. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 13(2), 108-118. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012.680991.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012....
). In recent years, SPs have become very popular with retail investors, especially in Europe and East Asia. In China, the most popular type of SP are wealth management products (WMPs). WMPs are investment vehicles marketed to retail and corporate investors, which are sold by both banks and non-bank financial institutions (NBFIs), sometimes with explicit principal or interest guarantees (Perry and Weltewitz, 2015Perry, E., & Weltewitz, F. (2015). Wealth management products in China (RBA Bulletin). Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia. https://www.rba.gov.au/publications/bulletin/2015/jun/pdf/bu-0615-7.pdf
https://www.rba.gov.au/publications/bull...
). WMPs are a type of SP that can be constructed by combining a call option with a fixed interest investment. They have some of the characteristics of structured investment vehicles (SIVs) as well as collateralized debt obligations (CDOs), which were used by U.S. banks before 2008 to keep loans off balance sheets (Chancellor and Monnelly, 2013Chancellor, E., & Monnelly, M. (2013). Feeding the dragon: Why China’s credit system looks vulnerable. Lexington: Advisor Perspectives. https://www.advisorperspectives.com/commentaries/2013/01/25/feeding-the-dragon-why-china-s-credit-system-looks-vulnerable
https://www.advisorperspectives.com/comm...
). This paper takes WMPs as the object of study and analyzes the investment behavior of investors in SPs.

Wealth management products in China have shown significant growth. Before 2016, the growth rate in the issuance of WMPs was rapid, with the annual average growth rate remaining at about 50%. In 2016 and 2017, the growth rate decreased but the estimated outstanding stock exceeded 29 trillion CNY (about 4.2 trillion USD) (China Banking Wealth Management Registration & Depository Center, 2018China Banking Wealth Management Registration & Depository Center. (2018). China Banking Sector Wealth Management Product Market Report. Beijing: CBRC. http://www.cbrc.gov.cn/chinese/files/2018/529E627CE8324461BD37CE152929E9BE.pdf
http://www.cbrc.gov.cn/chinese/files/201...
). The reason for the rapid growth is that WMPs can offer advantages to both banks and investors.

For investors, WMPs provide access to investments where returns significantly exceed regulated deposit rates. For banks, WMPs provide funding sources that allows them to compete for capital, while keeping the WMPs off their balance sheets and avoiding regulatory requirements.

But now, banks face a new situation where the WMP growth rate is not as high as in previous years. Thus, the probability of attracting more money flows by retailing more WMPs is decreasing. Lower growth rates create more competition between banks. If a bank retails more WMPs, the other banks’ retailing becomes lower. To be viable, financial products must appeal to a sufficiently large clientele and WMPs need to satisfy customers’ preferences (Allen & Gale, 1988Allen, F., & Gale, D. (1988). Optimal security design. Review of Financial Studies, 1(3), 229-263. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/1.3.229.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/1.3.229...
; Mada & Soubra, 1991Mada, D., & Soubra, B. (1991). Design and marketing of financial products. Review of Financial Studies, 4(2), 361-384. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/4.2.361.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/4.2.361...
; Shefrin & Statman, 1993Shefrin, H., & Statman, M. (1993). Behavioral aspects of the design and marketing of financial products. Financial Management, 22(2), 123-134. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3665864.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3665864...
).

Numerous scholars have studied the pricing of SPs in different markets. Henderson and Pearson (2011)Henderson, B., & Pearson, N. (2011). The dark side of financial innovation: A case study of the pricing of a retail financial product. Journal of Financial Economics, 11(2), 227-247. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.12.006.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
analyzed the products from the U.S. market. Stoimenov and Wilkens (2005)Stoimenov, P. A., & Wilkens, S. (2005). Are structured products ‘fairly’ priced? An analysis of the German market for equity-linked instruments. Journal of Banking & Finance, 29(12), 2971-2993. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2004.11.001.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
assessed the products from the German market, while Wallmeier and Diethelm (2009)Wallmeier, M., & Diethelm, M. (2009). Market pricing of exotic structured products: The case of multi-asset barrier reverse convertibles in Switzerland. Journal of Derivatives, 17(2), 59-72. http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/JOD.2009.17.2.059.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/JOD.2009.17.2....
studied the Swiss market. All of these authors found that the SPs were overpriced at the time of issuance. Investing in such products is a bad idea but it nevertheless remains very popular (Rieger, 2012Rieger, M. O. (2012). Why do investors buy bad financial products? Probability misestimation and preferences in financial investment decision. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 13(2), 108-118. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012.680991.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012....
). Henderson and Pearson (2011)Henderson, B., & Pearson, N. (2011). The dark side of financial innovation: A case study of the pricing of a retail financial product. Journal of Financial Economics, 11(2), 227-247. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.12.006.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
call this phenomenon the dark side of financial innovation.

In fact, in a standard model of portfolio choice, securities with expected returns that are lower than the riskless rate are rationally purchased by investors only if their returns covary positively with the investor’s marginal utility (Merton, 1982Merton, R. (1982). On the microeconomic theory of investment under uncertainty. In K. Arrow & M. Intriligator (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics (Vol. II, pp. 601-669). Amsterdam: North-Holland.). Nevertheless, investors continue to buy the overpriced SPs. Hence, understanding SP buying behavior is an important topic of inquiry.

The objective of this study is to understand SP investment behavior by investigating Chinese investors’ heterogeneous preferences for choosing WMPs with certain attributes. Specifically, we employ the choice experiment (CE) method and examine preference heterogeneity by using the multinomial logit (MNL) and the mixed logit (MXL) models. This study contributes to the existing literature by examining investors’ heterogeneous preferences for SPs using the CE method. In doing so, we provide empirical evidence on which attributes of structured products significantly affect investor preferences. We also reveal which investor characteristics affect their heterogeneous preferences.

Our paper is organized as follows. Section 2 reviews the existing literature on SP buying behavior. In Section 3, we summarize the CE method and the research, MNL, and MXL models. We also propose three hypotheses to be tested. Section 4 outlines the CE survey used to ascertain investors’ preferences, and we describe the MNL and MXL models used to analyze the data obtained from the CE survey. Section 5 concludes and offers suggestions for further study.

2 Literature review

Most existing studies outline the buying behavior for other financial products, but not SPs. Sahi et al. (2012)Sahi, S. K., Dhameja, N., & Arora, A. P. (2012). Predictors of preference for financial investment products using CART analysis. Journal of Indian Business Research, 4(1), 61-86. https://doi.org/10.1108/17554191211206807.
https://doi.org/10.1108/1755419121120680...
identified three factors that influence investor preferences, namely demographic, socio-economic, and psychographic variables. Psychographic variables are the most important predictors for higher risk investment products, and demographic and socio-economic variables are the most important predictors for lower risk products.

Numerous scholars have also focused on the reasons for buying SPs. Some studies focus on irrational decision-making and behavioral biases. Ofir and Wiener (2016)Ofir, M., & Wiener, Z. (2016). Individuals investment in financial structured products from rational and behavioral choice perspectives: Where do investors' biases come from? In I. Venezia (Ed.), Behavioral finance (pp. 33-65). Singapore: World Scientific Publishing. argue that retail investors that favor SP investments tend to be affected by behavioral biases, including loss aversion, disposition effects, herd behavior, the ostrich effect, and hindsight bias. Henderson and Pearson (2011)Henderson, B., & Pearson, N. (2011). The dark side of financial innovation: A case study of the pricing of a retail financial product. Journal of Financial Economics, 11(2), 227-247. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.12.006.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
provide an uncomplicated analysis of investor misunderstanding of financial markets. The authors outline the cognitive biases in evaluating probabilistic information, as well as the framing effects. Rieger (2012)Rieger, M. O. (2012). Why do investors buy bad financial products? Probability misestimation and preferences in financial investment decision. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 13(2), 108-118. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012.680991.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012....
found that behavioral biases increase the subjective attractiveness of SPs.

Many other studies attribute SP attractiveness to the demographic characteristics of investors. Döbeli and Vanini (2010)Döbeli, B., & Vanini, P. (2010). Stated and revealed investment decisions concerning retail structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(6), 1400-1411. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.007.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
controlled for gender differences in SP investments. Chang et al. (2010) Chang, E. C. C., Zhang, M., & Tang, D. Y., (2010). Financial literacy and household investments in structured financial products. Social Science Electronic Publishing. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1572339.found that individual financial literacy, education, and IQ are statistically significant explanatory variables, and that investors that were more financially literate formed reasonable expectations about stocks and bought less. Yang (2013)Yang, A. (2013). Decision making for individual investors: A measurement of latent difficulties. Journal of Financial Services Research, 44(3), 303-329. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-0144-0.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-014...
revealed that investors’ decision making is affected by their confidence and information gathering abilities, which are significantly influenced by income, age, and gender.

Other studies consider external factors. Döbeli and Vanini (2010)Döbeli, B., & Vanini, P. (2010). Stated and revealed investment decisions concerning retail structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(6), 1400-1411. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.007.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
found that when a structured product is described with simple words it strongly motivates people to invest in the product for the first time. Schroff (2015)Schroff, S. (2015). Investor behavior in the market for bank-issued structured products (Studienreihe der Stiftung Kreditwirtschaft-Verlag Wissenschaft und Praxis). Berlin: Wissenschaft & Praxis. http://dx.doi.org/10.3790/978-3-89644-696-4.
http://dx.doi.org/10.3790/978-3-89644-69...
revealed that the informational efficiency of retail investor trading in structured products is limited and that their trading behavior exhibits various behavioral biases.

Another stream of literature emphasizes the attributes of products as the elements influencing investor behavior. Abreu and Mendes (2018)Abreu, M., & Mendes, V. (2018). The investor in structured retail products: Advice driven or gambling oriented?. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 17, 1-9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.001.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.0...
provide evidence for investor preferences for SPs, which allow investors to access segments otherwise not available to them. Jørgensen et al. (2011)Jørgensen, P., Nørholm, H., & Skovmand, D. (2011). Overpricing and hidden costs of structured products for retail investors: Evidence from the danish market for principal protected notes (SSRN Working Paper). Rochester: SSRN. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1863854.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1863854...
argue that there are hidden costs that are not disclosed to investors and thereby affect their decisions. The attributes of the products can also influence the preference for one kind of SP over another. Jørgensen et al. (2011)Jørgensen, P., Nørholm, H., & Skovmand, D. (2011). Overpricing and hidden costs of structured products for retail investors: Evidence from the danish market for principal protected notes (SSRN Working Paper). Rochester: SSRN. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1863854.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1863854...
found that the factors contributing to the hidden costs are related to the products’ time to maturity, arranger and issuer size, and complexity, which are the main determinants of product costs and the degree of overpricing. Choosing between alternatives is a process by which customers collect and evaluate relevant information regarding products’ attributes according to their preferences (Hawkins and Mothersbaugh, 2010Hawkins, D., & Mothersbaugh, D. (2010). Consumer behaviour: Building marketing strategy (11th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.). The preferences for the attributes of SPs are very intuitive and critical in understanding SP investment behavior, so they deserve more research. This study contributes to the existing literature by identifying the attributes influencing investors’ preferences. We specifically analyzed heterogeneous investors’ preferences for these attributes, combined with the demographic characteristics of investors.

Because some attributes of SPs make the product look more attractive, investors prefer them because they receive high utility, which will change their terminal wealth. Many scholars draw on utilitarian thought to study investment behavior. Breuer and Perst (2007)Breuer, W., & Perst, A. (2007). Retail banking and behavioral financial engineering: The case of structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 31(3), 827-844. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.06.011.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
drew on expected utility theory to study the demand for SPs, while Hens and Rieger (2014)Hens, T., & Rieger, M. (2014). Can utility optimization explain the demand for structured investment products?Quantitative Finance, 14(4), 673-681. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14697688.2013.823512.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14697688.2013....
used prospect theory. Bernard, Boyle, and Tian (2007)Bernard, C., Boyle, P., & Tian, W. (2007). Optimal design of structured products and the role of capital protection (Working Paper). Ontario: University of Waterloo. http://2015.eurofidai.org/Bernard_854.pdf
http://2015.eurofidai.org/Bernard_854.pd...
studied the characteristics of optimal capital-protected products for various investor preferences. Döbeli and Vanini (2010)Döbeli, B., & Vanini, P. (2010). Stated and revealed investment decisions concerning retail structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(6), 1400-1411. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.007.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
used the utility function to analyze investment preferences. Therefore, we can also study investors’ preference for WMPs from the perspective of investor utility.

Methodologically, preceding studies have mainly used three methods to collect data on SP investors’ behavior. These include questionnaires (Döbeli and Vanini, 2010Döbeli, B., & Vanini, P. (2010). Stated and revealed investment decisions concerning retail structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(6), 1400-1411. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.007.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
; Yang, 2010), real market data (Abreu and Mendes, 2018Abreu, M., & Mendes, V. (2018). The investor in structured retail products: Advice driven or gambling oriented?. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 17, 1-9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.001.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.0...
; Henderson & Pearson 2011Henderson, B., & Pearson, N. (2011). The dark side of financial innovation: A case study of the pricing of a retail financial product. Journal of Financial Economics, 11(2), 227-247. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.12.006.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
; Jørgensen et al., 2011Jørgensen, P., Nørholm, H., & Skovmand, D. (2011). Overpricing and hidden costs of structured products for retail investors: Evidence from the danish market for principal protected notes (SSRN Working Paper). Rochester: SSRN. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1863854.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1863854...
), and experiments (Rieger, 2012Rieger, M. O. (2012). Why do investors buy bad financial products? Probability misestimation and preferences in financial investment decision. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 13(2), 108-118. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012.680991.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012....
; Ofir & Wiener, 2016Ofir, M., & Wiener, Z. (2016). Individuals investment in financial structured products from rational and behavioral choice perspectives: Where do investors' biases come from? In I. Venezia (Ed.), Behavioral finance (pp. 33-65). Singapore: World Scientific Publishing.). Our study combines discrete choice models with the choice experiment (CE) approach to analyze preferences when investors purchase WMPs, a kind of SP. These CEs are consistent with Lancaster’s theory of utility maximization (Lancaster, 1966Lancaster, K. (1966). A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74(2), 132-157. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/259131.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/259131...
), and with the discrete choice modeling developed by McFadden (1973)McFadden, D. (1973). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice be. In P. Zarembka (Ed.), Frontiers in econometrics (pp. 105-142). New York: Academic Press.. Lancaster (1966)Lancaster, K. (1966). A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74(2), 132-157. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/259131.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/259131...
proposed that a good in itself does not provide utility to the consumer. Rather, a good possesses characteristics, and these characteristics give rise to utility. Following Lancaster and McFadden, CEs are widely used to elicit consumer valuations of non-market goods and marketable goods with novel attributes or characteristics. Similarly, an investment instrument possesses characteristics, and these characteristics give rise to utility, which will change the terminal wealth of the investor. Thus, the CE method is suitable for conducting research on investors’ behavior. However, few studies exist about the application of this method to investors’ behavior. Our study seeks to contribute to the literature on SP market forecasting through the application of the CE method in analyzing investor’s preferences and behavior.

3 Methods

3.1 Research methods

Choice experiments closely simulate real-world purchasing decisions, where a respondent has to select a product from a set of options. We use CEs to elicit investors’ preferences for WMPs with certain attributes that can have a large impact on their choice decisions. We identified the following four attributes for the WMPs in constructing the choice sets: bank, term, minimum amount, and type. “Bank” is the issuer. “Term” is the time to maturity of the WMPs. “Minimum amount” is the threshold to purchase a certain kind of WMP. “Type” means the return type of the WMPs. Table 1 describes these attributes and how each level of attribute is defined. To make the alternatives more realistic, we used the names of three real banks, namely the Industrial and Commercial Bank of China (ICBC), CITIC Bank (CITIC), and Bank of Weifang, to represent the three levels of the bank attribute.

Table 1
Descriptions and levels of the chosen attributes

The four attributes have the levels 3, 4, 4, and 3, respectively, for a total combination of 144 (32 × 42) choice sets. However, because too many choice sets may hinder the consumers’ ability to make more rational decisions in a short time (Gao et al., 2010Gao, Z., House, L., & Yu, X. (2010). Using choice experiments to estimate consumer valuation: The role of experimental design and attribute information loads. Agricultural Economics, 41(6), 555-565. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2010.00470.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.20...
), a full factorial design encompassing all possible combinations of attribute levels would not be feasible. For that reason, we selected a subset of these choices by employing the orthogonal main effects design, which can adhere to CE design principles to maximize design efficiency. This includes displaying i) orthogonality, which ensures that differences in the levels of each attribute vary independently over choice sets, and ii) balance, to confirm that all levels appear with equal frequency in the questionnaire (Johnson et al., 2013Johnson, F. R., Lancsar, E., Marshall, D., Kilambi, V., Mühlbacher, A., Regier, D., Bresnahan, B., Kanninen, B., & Bridges, J. (2013). Constructing experimental designs for discrete-choice experiments: report of the ispor conjoint analysis experimental design good research practices task force. Value in Health, 16(1), 3-13. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2012.08.2223.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2012.08.2...
). We implemented the orthogonal main effects design using SAS 9.4. As a result, we obtained 11 choice sets. Every choice set includes two alternative preference options and one option for neither if the respondent does not prefer either of the two alternative preferences. Table 2 presents an example of the choice set that was used. Each respondent was presented with 11 choice sets and was asked to choose one of three options: alternative 1, alternative 2, or neither. ‘Neither’ is an opt-out option, which was presented to match the real-life decision context.

Table 2
A sample choice set used in this study

In addition, in the WMP market, issuers disclose information on expected yields to maturity (YTM) as a reference. But the fluctuations of real YTM are an uncertainty in the market, and issuers also state the benchmark return, but not the guaranteed return rate. In order to reflect the real market, we added expected yields to maturity as a reference for the respondents. Because four attributes are correlated with risk, we set the expected YTM as an item reflecting the difference of risks based on the difference of attributes rather than as the independent attribute.

The survey questionnaire comprised two sections. The first part asked about the personal characteristics of the respondents, such as income, age, gender, and education, to analyze the effect of characteristics on preferences. The second part contained questions for the CE analysis that were designed to record the respondents’ preferences for choosing WMPs.

The survey was carried out in Weifang, China, from April 13 to 19, 2018. Weifang is a medium-sized city with an urban population of 1.28 million. It is representative of a medium-sized city in China. A total of 156 people participated in the survey.

3.2 Hypotheses

As we pointed out earlier, numerous studies have analyzed the effects of SP attributes on investors’ behavior from the perspective of the financial products themselves. For example, Abreu and Mendes (2018)Abreu, M., & Mendes, V. (2018). The investor in structured retail products: Advice driven or gambling oriented?. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 17, 1-9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.001.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.0...
argue that the reason why investors show a preference for SPs is that they allow investors to access segments. However, these characteristics are not intuitive enough and they are not convenient for investors to compare. In this study, we selected four obvious and intuitive attributes to study, which we believe are likely to affect investors’ behavior.

According to Yang (2013)Yang, A. (2013). Decision making for individual investors: A measurement of latent difficulties. Journal of Financial Services Research, 44(3), 303-329. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-0144-0.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-014...
, investors’ ability to gather information influences their decision-making regarding investment preferences. The attributes of SPs can intuitively show information describing the financial products. Döbeli and Vanini (2010)Döbeli, B., & Vanini, P. (2010). Stated and revealed investment decisions concerning retail structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(6), 1400-1411. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.007.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
found that a product described in simple words strongly motivates people to invest in SPs for the first time. Descriptions of SP attributes can intuitively show more information to investors. Thus, our first hypothesis is as follows:

  • H1: the attributes of SPs can influence investors’ behavior.

Among the four attributes selected in this study, “minimum amount” and “term” are numerical variables, so their exact value can be used directly for the regression. “Minimum amount” is the threshold to purchase certain kinds of WMPs. Usually, a higher threshold keeps smaller investors out. Therefore, we propose that the “minimum amount” attribute can negatively influence investors’ preferences (H1a).

“Term” is the duration until maturity of WMPs, which will affect the yields. According to liquidity premium theory (Mishkin, 2015Mishkin, F. (2015). The economics of money, banking and financial markets, global edition (11th ed.). New York: Pearson Education.), a term premium typically rises with maturity in the bond market. But in the SP market, Henderson and Pearson (2011)Henderson, B., & Pearson, N. (2011). The dark side of financial innovation: A case study of the pricing of a retail financial product. Journal of Financial Economics, 11(2), 227-247. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.12.006.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
found that the premium shows a slow decay within 140 days and a modest increase after 140 days. “Term” can show information about yield and risk. From the perspective of risk aversion, we propose that this attribute can negatively influence the investors’ preferences (H1b).

“Bank” and “type” are the categorical variables and they each have three levels. We employed dummy coding to obtain six dummy variables: “large bank,” “medium bank,” “small bank,” “non-guaranteed floating return,” “guaranteed floating return,” and “fixed return.”

“Type” refers to the return type of the WMP (i.e., floating return or fixed return) and intuitively shows the risk associated with WMPs. We set “fixed return” as the base, according to the risk aversion of investors, and we propose that the attribute “non-guaranteed floating return” and “guaranteed floating return” can negatively influence investors’ preferences (H1c, H1d).

“Bank” shows the issuer size, implying the information about brand and risk. We set “large bank” as the base, again according to the risk aversion of investors. We propose that the “medium bank” and “small bank” attributes can negatively influence the investors’ preferences (H1e, H1f).

Investors’ preferences may be either homogeneous or heterogeneous. Heterogeneous preferences mean that different types of investors show different preferences, which has been researched in many studies. For example, Yang (2013)Yang, A. (2013). Decision making for individual investors: A measurement of latent difficulties. Journal of Financial Services Research, 44(3), 303-329. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-0144-0.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-014...
analyzed the heterogeneous types of investors based on their income, gender, and maturity, etc. Döbeli and Vanini (2010)Döbeli, B., & Vanini, P. (2010). Stated and revealed investment decisions concerning retail structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(6), 1400-1411. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.007.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
also controlled for gender differences in investment behavior. We propose the following second hypothesis H2 to test whether investors’ preferences for the four attributes of SPs are heterogeneous.

  • H2: Investors’ preferences for these four attributes are heterogeneous.

For the categorization of heterogeneous investors, some studies focus on the differences in risk preference and cognitive ability (Coleman, 2003 Coleman, S. (2003). Risk tolerance and the investment behavior of Black and Hispanic heads of household. Journal of Financial Counseling and Planning, 14(2), 43-52.; Dorn & Huberman, 2010 Dorn, D., & Huberman, G. (2010). Preferred risk habitat of individual investors.Journal of Financial Economics, 97(1), 155-173. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.03.013.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.0...
).

Sadi et al. (2011)Sadi, R., Asl, H. G., Rostami, M. R., Gholipour, A., & Gholipour, F. (2011). Behavioral finance:the explanation of investors’ personality and perceptual biases effects on financial decisions. International Journal of Economics and Finance, 3(5), 421-428. http://dx.doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v3n5p234.
http://dx.doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v3n5p234...
confirmed that demographic factors play a significant role in determining the behavior and decisions of investors. Accordingly, some studies have looked at the differences in demographic factors among investors (Mak & Ip, 2017Mak, M. K., & Ip, W. H. (2017). An exploratory study of investment behaviour of investors.International Journal of Engineering Business Management, 9, 1-12. https://doi.org/10.1177/1847979017711520.
https://doi.org/10.1177/1847979017711520...
; Yang, 2013Yang, A. (2013). Decision making for individual investors: A measurement of latent difficulties. Journal of Financial Services Research, 44(3), 303-329. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-0144-0.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-014...
).

Correspondingly, we identify whether investors have heterogeneous preferences for some SP attributes based on the test results for H2. Then, we propose the following third hypothesis to test whether the demographic characteristics are the predictors of preference heterogeneity, which can explain the transmission mechanism of heterogeneous preferences.

  • H3: Demographic factors are the predictors of heterogeneous preferences for SP attributes.

If a certain attribute is the predictor of heterogeneous preference, it shows that heterogeneous investors have different investment behaviors due to their preference for this attribute. In this paper, we tested for seven demographic characteristics, including age, annual family income, education, monthly expenditure, gender, profession, and mortgage or not.

3.3 Research model

The utility function is used to explain individual choices when choosing from the available alternatives. The utility function for each respondent n, who chooses alternative j from the choice set, can be expressed as (Equation 1):

U n j = V n j + ε n j (1)

The utility Unj can be decomposed into two parts: the deterministic utility Vnj, and the stochastic utility εnj. The stochastic utility represents the unobservable influence on individual n’s choice of alternative j. Therefore, the choice probability can be used to reflect the utility of decision makers. Pni is the probability if individual n selecting alternative j.

P n i = P r o b U n i > U n j , j i = P r o b V n i + ε n i > V n j + ε n j , j i
= P r o b ε n j ε n i < V n i V n j , j i (2)

According to the different assumptions of εnj, Equation 2 can be broken down into different discrete choice models. The multinomial logit model (MNL) is a prevailing model used to estimate respondent preferences in CEs, where εnj is assumed to have an identical independent Gumbel distribution (McFadden, 1974McFadden, D. (1974). The measurement of urban travel demand. Journal of Public Economics, 3(4), 303-328. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(74)90003-6.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(74)9...
). The probability of individual n choosing alternative j can be expressed as (Equation 3):

P n i = e V n i j C e V n j (3)

where Vni=βxni, and xni are the attributes of the alternative i that individual n chooses. We can include four attributes in the utility function to obtain the Equation 4,

V n j = A S C + β 1 Bank + β 2 Minimumamount + β 3 Term + β 4 Type (4)

where ASC is the alternative-specific constant to model the impact of an opt-out option.

However, the MNL model restrictively assumes that the functional form of utility is common among individuals, including homogenous preferences and independence of irrelevant alternatives (IIA). It does not allow for unobserved preference heterogeneity, which means that β is fixed. That is, it does not reflect the actual situation. In the mixed logit model proposed by McFadden and Train (2000)McFadden, D., & Train, K. (2000). Mixed MNL models for discrete response. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15(5), 447-470. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/1099-1255(200009/10)15:5<447::AID-JAE570>3.0.CO;2-1.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/1099-1255(2000...
, these assumptions are relaxed and β is assumed to follow a certain distribution. Thus, the probability if individual n choosing alternative j can be expressed as (Equation 5):

P n i = e V n i j C e V n j f ( β | θ ) d β (5)

where f(β|θ) is the probability density function of β, and θ represents the parameters of the density function.

The parameters of the MXL model can be estimated using maximum simulated likelihood (MSL), as proposed by Train (2009)Train, K. (2009). Discrete choice methods with simulation. New York: Cambridge University Press.. In order to consider heterogeneous preferences, we employed the MXL model to derive the utility function as

V n j = A S C + ( β 1 + σ ) X 1 + β 2 X 2 (6)

where X1 are some attributes set as random parameters, and X2 are some attributes set as fixed parameters.

To determine the reason for the heterogeneous preferences, we can add cross items to test the interaction effect among the characteristics of the respondents and their preferences:

V n j = A S C + β 1 B a n k + β 2 M i n i m u m a m o u n t + β 3 T e r m + β 4 T y p e + β 5 a t t r i b u t e * g e n d e r + β 6 a t t r i b u t e * a g e + β 7 a t t r i b u t e * p r o f e s s i o n + β 8 a t t r i b u t e * f a m i l y r e v e n u e + β 9 a t t r i b u t e * e d u c a t i o n + β 10 a t t r i b u t e * exp e n d i t u r e p e r m o n t h + β 11 a t t r i b u t e * m o r t g a g e (7)

where attribute is one of the four attributes. We test them when they are significant as the random parameters.

4 Data and analysis

In the questionnaire, the first part contained questions about respondent characteristics, which included the seven variables presented in Table 3. The table also includes the mean and standard deviation for each variable. 50.64% of the survey respondents were males. The mean age was 3.44, which means that the average age is an interval between the ages of 26 and 40. The mean annual family income was 3.05, where the average annual family income was between 50 and 100 thousand RMB. The mean education was 3.4, indicating an average educational level between a junior college degree and an undergraduate degree. The average expenditure per month was between 1000 and 5000 RMB. Also, 42.3% of the respondents still had a mortgage.

Table 3
Characteristic variables and survey results summary

The objective of this study is to evaluate the effect of the respondent characteristics on their attribute preferences, which we estimated through Equation 6. Before that, we estimated the MNL model and the MXL model. In the regression analysis, we used the exact numerical value of the numerical attribute variables, such as “minimum amount” and “term.” Categorical variables, however, were coded using dummy coding. We included three dummy variables according to the attributes “bank” and “type,” respectively. In order to avoid multicollinearity, we chose “large bank” as the base category for “bank” and selected “fixed return” as the base category of “type.”

4.1 Regression results of the MNL model

First, we estimated the MNL model to investigate investors’ preferences for certain attributes. The results are presented in Table 4, which shows the coefficients of four attributes affecting the respondents’ choice, and the significance of the coefficients. Significance levels were determined using the t-test, where one star represents the 10% level, two stars the 5% level, and three stars the 1% level.

Table 4
Estimated MNL results of the preference for attributes

It is apparent from Table 4 that the coefficients of “small bank,” “minimum amount,” “non-guaranteed floating return,” and “ASC” (alternative-specific constant) are statistically significant at the 1% level. The coefficient for “guaranteed floating return” is statistically significant at the 10% level, while the coefficients for “medium bank” and “term” are not statistically significant. The results indicate that the “small bank,” “minimum amount,” “non-guaranteed floating return,” and “guaranteed floating return” attributes significantly affect the respondents’ choice to purchase the WMPs.

The results also show how attributes affect respondents’ preferences when they buy WMPs. The effect of “small bank” on the preference for the WMPs was positive, meaning that this factor negatively influences investors’ behavior. Thus, H1f is not confirmed. In contrast, it is positive. Ofir and Wiener (2016)Ofir, M., & Wiener, Z. (2016). Individuals investment in financial structured products from rational and behavioral choice perspectives: Where do investors' biases come from? In I. Venezia (Ed.), Behavioral finance (pp. 33-65). Singapore: World Scientific Publishing. argued that issuing banks with competitive advantages raise their profit margins, so small banks can increase market competition to enlarge the consumer surplus. Therefore, investors prefer purchasing WMPs from smaller banks rather than from larger ones. The coefficient for “medium bank” was insignificant, meaning that investors do not have an obvious preference for medium banks. As such, the influence of a medium bank size on investors’ behavior (H1e) cannot be confirmed.

The effect of “minimum amount” on investors’ preference for WMPs was negative, meaning that “minimum amount” has a negative influence on investors’ behavior. Thus, H1a is confirmed. This suggests that investors are more likely to buy WMPs with a lower threshold. Few studies have focused on the influence of the purchase amount threshold on investors’ behavior. However, some studies focusing on the influence of the free-shipping threshold on purchase behavior found that it had a significant influence on purchase quantity (Becerril-Arreola et al., 2013Becerril-Arreola, R., Leng, M., & Parlar, M. (2013). Online retailers’ promotional pricing, free-shipping threshold, and inventory decisions: A simulation-based analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 230(2), 272-283. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2013.04.006.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2013.04...
; Zhou et al., 2009Zhou, B., Katehakis, M., & Zhao, Y. (2009). Managing stochastic inventory systems with free shipping option. European Journal of Operational Research, 196(1), 186-197. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2008.01.042.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2008.01...
). Their findings can support our result to a certain extent. At the same time, the effect is slight because the coefficient (-0.007) is small. This means that the threshold can have an evident impact only when it is adjusted to be very large.

The coefficient for “term” is also insignificant, meaning that investors’ preference for time to maturity is not obvious. As such, the influence of “term” on investors’ behavior (H1b) cannot be confirmed. A similar conclusion was obtained by Henderson and Pearson (2011)Henderson, B., & Pearson, N. (2011). The dark side of financial innovation: A case study of the pricing of a retail financial product. Journal of Financial Economics, 11(2), 227-247. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.12.006.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
, who found that the premium showed a slow decay within 140 days and a modest increase after 140 days in the SP market.

The effects of “non-guaranteed floating return” and “guaranteed floating return” on the preference for WMPs were negative, indicating that both H1c and H1d are confirmed. This means that investors prefer purchasing WMPs with fixed returns instead of floating returns. The probability of purchasing WMPs with non-guaranteed floating returns is lower than that of purchasing WMPs with guaranteed floating returns. This result indicates that investors purchasing WMPs are risk averse and prefer WMPs with lower risks, because their decisions are influenced by the bias of loss aversion (Ofir and Wiener, 2016Ofir, M., & Wiener, Z. (2016). Individuals investment in financial structured products from rational and behavioral choice perspectives: Where do investors' biases come from? In I. Venezia (Ed.), Behavioral finance (pp. 33-65). Singapore: World Scientific Publishing.).

4.2 Regression results of the MXL model

The MNL model imposes restrictive assumptions of IIA on choice behaviors with homogenous preferences. Hence, the MXL model is employed to capture preference heterogeneity. Thus, we estimated a MXL model to investigate the heterogeneous preferences for the different attributes. In the process, we set all attributes as the random parameter variable, which is assumed to follow a normal distribution. Based on the significance levels of random parameters in the results, we kept the significant random parameters and set the insignificant random parameters as fixed parameters. The results obtained are displayed in Table 5. It is obvious that the results estimated with the MXL were better than the ones estimated with the MNL model, according to the increasing levels of goodness-of-fit measured with the adjusted Estrella R2, the McFadden LRI R2, and the log likelihood.

Table 5
Estimated MXL results of the preference for attributes

In Table 5, we can see that the attributes with statistically significant coefficients are the same as in the results of Table 4. This includes the coefficients for “small bank,” “minimum amount,” “non-guaranteed floating return,” “guaranteed floating return,” and “ASC.” Meanwhile, the coefficients of “medium bank” and “term” are not statistically significant. Moreover, the statistically significant attributes have the same direction of influence in Tables 4 and 5. This confirms that the conclusions drawn from the MNL model are robust.

In the MXL model, the “minimum amount” was set as a random parameter variable following a normal distribution. As we can see in Table 5, the mean and standard deviation are both significant at the 1% level, and the minimum amount follows a normal distribution, Z~N0.014,0.0202. We can draw three conclusions: (1) the “minimum amount” threshold significantly affects the utility level when investors purchase WMPs, and the higher the minimum amount, the smaller the utility; (2) because the results follow a normal distributionZ~N0.014,0.0202, when the minimum amount increases by one unit (10 thousand RMB), 75.80% of the investors will have a lower probability of choosing the choice set, and 24.20% of the investors will have an increased probability; (3) because “minimum amount” is the random parameter variable following a normal distribution, there are significant heterogeneous preferences for “minimum amount” among all respondents, and there are homogeneous preferences for the other attributes.

As a result, H2, which postulates that investors’ preferences for these four attributes are heterogeneous, is partly confirmed. Only the “minimum amount” attribute is heterogeneous, but the other three attributes are not.

4.3 Regression results of the MXL model with cross items

The conclusion is that there are significant heterogeneous preferences for “minimum amount” among all respondents. This means that different investors have different preferences. We need to recognize the predictors of heterogeneity. Based on Equation 7, we added the cross items to the MXL model. The cross items are combined based on the random parameter and characteristic variables. Table 6 presents the regression results of the MXL model with cross items. According to the increasing levels of goodness-of-fit measured by the adjusted Estrella R2, the McFadden LRI R2, and the log likelihood, the estimated results are better.

Table 6
Estimated MXL results with cross items

As Table 6 shows, the attributes with significant and insignificant coefficients are almost the same as the results in Tables 4 and 5. The only difference is that the attribute for “non-guaranteed floating return” is not significant. The random parameter variable is set in the same way as in Table 5, and the mean and standard deviation results are also significant. They all reconfirm that the conclusions drawn from the MNL and MXL models are robust.

The purpose of this section is to recognize the sources of heterogeneity. We therefore proceeded to analyze the cross items in Table 6.

There are seven cross items in Table 6. As we can see, the coefficients of four of the seven items are significant at the 1% or 5% level. These include age, annual family income, education, and monthly expenditure. This means that these four characteristics are the predictors of heterogeneous preference for the “minimum amount” attribute. Investors with differences in terms of age, annual family income, educational level, and monthly expenditure, have different preferences regarding the minimum amount threshold for purchasing WMPs. Therefore, it can be concluded that demographic factors are the predictors of heterogeneous preferences for the SP attributes (H3). The other three characteristics – gender, profession, and mortgage or not – are not significant, which means they are not predictors of heterogeneity.

Based on the “optional life-cycle investing” idea of the life-cycle theory, people take a long position in their human capital, and a short position in their pre-committed consumption stream. If income is pro-cyclical, human capital will be a substitute for cash, and financial investments should involve more bonds and less cash (Munk & Sørensen, 2010Munk, C., & Sørensen, C. (2010). Dynamic asset allocation with stochastic income and interest rates. Journal of Financial Economics, 96(3), 433-462. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.01.004.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
; Bick et al., 2013Bick, B., Kraft, H., & Munk, C. (2013). Solving constrained consumption-investment problems by simulation of artificial market strategies. Management Science, 59(2), 485-503. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1623.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1623...
). This means that people prefer to invest in high-risk assets as their labor income increases but prefer to invest in low risk assets when their pre-committed consumption stream increases.

The coefficients associated with minimum amount*age and minimum amount*monthly expenditure are negative, showing that older investors have higher monthly expenditure and a greater preference for WMPs with the lower minimum amount. It is easy to understand that older investors are more cautious. Abreu and Mendes (2018)Abreu, M., & Mendes, V. (2018). The investor in structured retail products: Advice driven or gambling oriented?. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 17, 1-9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.001.
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.0...
also found that heavy SP traders are younger. Based on Munk and Sørensen (2010)Munk, C., & Sørensen, C. (2010). Dynamic asset allocation with stochastic income and interest rates. Journal of Financial Economics, 96(3), 433-462. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.01.004.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
, the proportion of investment in risk assets will decrease as age increases. Therefore, they prefer WMPs with lower thresholds, which are considered to be lower risk.

It is a little complicated to understand why investors with higher monthly expenditure prefer the lower minimum amount. In general, WMPs with a low investment threshold are regarded as low risk. According to the “optional life-cycle investing” theory (Munk & Sørensen, 2010Munk, C., & Sørensen, C. (2010). Dynamic asset allocation with stochastic income and interest rates. Journal of Financial Economics, 96(3), 433-462. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.01.004.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
), increased consumption has a negative influence on financial wealth accumulation, and people prefer to invest in low-risk assets. Therefore, the higher the monthly expenditure, the lower the minimum amount preferred.

The other two cross item coefficients associated with minimum amount*education and minimum amount* annual family income are positive. This shows that investors with a higher annual income also have a higher educational level, as well as a greater preference for WMPs with the higher minimum amount, regardless of the purchasing threshold. This finding is consistent with the conclusions of previous studies. According to the “optional life-cycle investing” theory (Munk & Sørensen, 2010Munk, C., & Sørensen, C. (2010). Dynamic asset allocation with stochastic income and interest rates. Journal of Financial Economics, 96(3), 433-462. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.01.004.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
), as income rises, human wealth increases, which results in a preference for investing in risky assets. Accordingly, people prefer to invest in high-risk assets as their labor income increases. The authors also showed that college graduates are more likely to invest in the stock market than investors with a lower educational level because their income increases more rapidly and reaches a considerably higher level. Likewise, Dohmen et al. (2010)Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2010). Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability? The American Economic Review, 100(3), 1238-1260. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.3.1238.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.3.1238...
found that lower cognitive ability is associated with greater risk aversion, and that educational level and family income are positively related to cognitive ability.

In terms of the sensitivity of the estimated interaction coefficients, among the four significant cross items, the absolute value of the coefficient associated with minimum amount*education is the highest. This indicates that investors with different educational levels are most sensitive to the minimum amount, while a different annual family income is the least sensitive to the minimum amount. This implies that, among investors with different household incomes, there are only minor differences in the preferences for WMPs with different investment thresholds.

5 Conclusion

This study examined WMP investors’ behavior and investment choices. We examined the factors influencing the choice to purchase WMPs based on four investor demographic characteristics. We draw the following three conclusions:

(1) The attributes “small bank,” “minimum amount,” “non-guaranteed floating return,” and “guaranteed floating return” significantly affect the respondents’ choice when purchasing WMPs;

(2) There are significant heterogeneous preferences for “minimum amount” for all respondents, and there are homogeneous preferences for the other attributes;

(3) These four characteristics, age, annual family income, education, and monthly expenditure, are the sources of heterogeneous preferences for the “minimum amount” attribute.

The findings offer some behavioral evidence to banks and the SP market. Banks should take into account the heterogeneous preferences of investors according to their characteristics, which can help in designing marketable WMPs to target different kinds of investors.

As a kind of SP, the findings for WMPs can contribute to understanding the principle of investors’ behavior in the SP market.

In our explanation of the sources of heterogeneous preference, we adopted risk aversion as a transmission variable. But in the questionnaire design, we did not take it into account. This limitation requires further study in this area.

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to express their gratitude to EditSprings (https://www.editsprings.com/) for the expert linguistic services provided.

  • How to cite: Han, X., & Liu, W. (2022). Investors’ heterogeneous preferences for structured financial products in China: the impact of demographic characteristics. Revista Brasileira de Gestão de Negócios, 24(3), p. 458-471. https://doi.org/10.7819/rbgn.v24i3.4187
  • Financial support: Research Projects of Shandong Social Science Planning: 21CDCJ16.
  • Conflicts of interest: The authors have no conflict of interest to declare. Copyrights: RBGN owns the copyrights of this published content. Plagiarism analysis: RBGN performs plagiarism analysis on all its articles at the time of submission and after approval of the manuscript using the iThenticate tool. Authors:

Referências

  • Abreu, M., & Mendes, V. (2018). The investor in structured retail products: Advice driven or gambling oriented?. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Finance, 17, 1-9. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.001
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbef.2017.12.001
  • Allen, F., & Gale, D. (1988). Optimal security design. Review of Financial Studies, 1(3), 229-263. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/1.3.229
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/1.3.229
  • Becerril-Arreola, R., Leng, M., & Parlar, M. (2013). Online retailers’ promotional pricing, free-shipping threshold, and inventory decisions: A simulation-based analysis. European Journal of Operational Research, 230(2), 272-283. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2013.04.006
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2013.04.006
  • Bernard, C., Boyle, P., & Tian, W. (2007). Optimal design of structured products and the role of capital protection (Working Paper). Ontario: University of Waterloo. http://2015.eurofidai.org/Bernard_854.pdf
    » http://2015.eurofidai.org/Bernard_854.pdf
  • Bick, B., Kraft, H., & Munk, C. (2013). Solving constrained consumption-investment problems by simulation of artificial market strategies. Management Science, 59(2), 485-503. http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1623
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.1120.1623
  • Breuer, W., & Perst, A. (2007). Retail banking and behavioral financial engineering: The case of structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 31(3), 827-844. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.06.011
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.06.011
  • Chancellor, E., & Monnelly, M. (2013). Feeding the dragon: Why China’s credit system looks vulnerable. Lexington: Advisor Perspectives. https://www.advisorperspectives.com/commentaries/2013/01/25/feeding-the-dragon-why-china-s-credit-system-looks-vulnerable
    » https://www.advisorperspectives.com/commentaries/2013/01/25/feeding-the-dragon-why-china-s-credit-system-looks-vulnerable
  • Chang, E. C. C., Zhang, M., & Tang, D. Y., (2010). Financial literacy and household investments in structured financial products. Social Science Electronic Publishing http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1572339.
  • China Banking Wealth Management Registration & Depository Center. (2018). China Banking Sector Wealth Management Product Market Report. Beijing: CBRC. http://www.cbrc.gov.cn/chinese/files/2018/529E627CE8324461BD37CE152929E9BE.pdf
    » http://www.cbrc.gov.cn/chinese/files/2018/529E627CE8324461BD37CE152929E9BE.pdf
  • Coleman, S. (2003). Risk tolerance and the investment behavior of Black and Hispanic heads of household. Journal of Financial Counseling and Planning, 14(2), 43-52.
  • Döbeli, B., & Vanini, P. (2010). Stated and revealed investment decisions concerning retail structured products. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34(6), 1400-1411. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.007
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2009.12.007
  • Dohmen, T., Falk, A., Huffman, D., & Sunde, U. (2010). Are risk aversion and impatience related to cognitive ability? The American Economic Review, 100(3), 1238-1260. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.3.1238
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.3.1238
  • Dorn, D., & Huberman, G. (2010). Preferred risk habitat of individual investors.Journal of Financial Economics, 97(1), 155-173. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.03.013
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.03.013
  • Gao, Z., House, L., & Yu, X. (2010). Using choice experiments to estimate consumer valuation: The role of experimental design and attribute information loads. Agricultural Economics, 41(6), 555-565. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2010.00470.x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1574-0862.2010.00470.x
  • Hawkins, D., & Mothersbaugh, D. (2010). Consumer behaviour: Building marketing strategy (11th ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.
  • Henderson, B., & Pearson, N. (2011). The dark side of financial innovation: A case study of the pricing of a retail financial product. Journal of Financial Economics, 11(2), 227-247. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.12.006
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.12.006
  • Hens, T., & Rieger, M. (2014). Can utility optimization explain the demand for structured investment products?Quantitative Finance, 14(4), 673-681. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14697688.2013.823512
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14697688.2013.823512
  • Jørgensen, P., Nørholm, H., & Skovmand, D. (2011). Overpricing and hidden costs of structured products for retail investors: Evidence from the danish market for principal protected notes (SSRN Working Paper). Rochester: SSRN. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1863854
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1863854
  • Lancaster, K. (1966). A new approach to consumer theory. Journal of Political Economy, 74(2), 132-157. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/259131
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/259131
  • Mada, D., & Soubra, B. (1991). Design and marketing of financial products. Review of Financial Studies, 4(2), 361-384. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/4.2.361
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/4.2.361
  • Mak, M. K., & Ip, W. H. (2017). An exploratory study of investment behaviour of investors.International Journal of Engineering Business Management, 9, 1-12. https://doi.org/10.1177/1847979017711520
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/1847979017711520
  • McFadden, D. (1973). Conditional logit analysis of qualitative choice be. In P. Zarembka (Ed.), Frontiers in econometrics (pp. 105-142). New York: Academic Press.
  • McFadden, D. (1974). The measurement of urban travel demand. Journal of Public Economics, 3(4), 303-328. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(74)90003-6
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0047-2727(74)90003-6
  • McFadden, D., & Train, K. (2000). Mixed MNL models for discrete response. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15(5), 447-470. http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/1099-1255(200009/10)15:5<447::AID-JAE570>3.0.CO;2-1
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/1099-1255(200009/10)15:5<447::AID-JAE570>3.0.CO;2-1
  • Merton, R. (1982). On the microeconomic theory of investment under uncertainty. In K. Arrow & M. Intriligator (Eds.), Handbook of mathematical economics (Vol. II, pp. 601-669). Amsterdam: North-Holland.
  • Mishkin, F. (2015). The economics of money, banking and financial markets, global edition (11th ed.). New York: Pearson Education.
  • Munk, C., & Sørensen, C. (2010). Dynamic asset allocation with stochastic income and interest rates. Journal of Financial Economics, 96(3), 433-462. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.01.004
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.01.004
  • Ofir, M., & Wiener, Z. (2016). Individuals investment in financial structured products from rational and behavioral choice perspectives: Where do investors' biases come from? In I. Venezia (Ed.), Behavioral finance (pp. 33-65). Singapore: World Scientific Publishing.
  • Perry, E., & Weltewitz, F. (2015). Wealth management products in China (RBA Bulletin). Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia. https://www.rba.gov.au/publications/bulletin/2015/jun/pdf/bu-0615-7.pdf
    » https://www.rba.gov.au/publications/bulletin/2015/jun/pdf/bu-0615-7.pdf
  • Johnson, F. R., Lancsar, E., Marshall, D., Kilambi, V., Mühlbacher, A., Regier, D., Bresnahan, B., Kanninen, B., & Bridges, J. (2013). Constructing experimental designs for discrete-choice experiments: report of the ispor conjoint analysis experimental design good research practices task force. Value in Health, 16(1), 3-13. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2012.08.2223
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jval.2012.08.2223
  • Rieger, M. O. (2012). Why do investors buy bad financial products? Probability misestimation and preferences in financial investment decision. Journal of Behavioral Finance, 13(2), 108-118. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012.680991
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/15427560.2012.680991
  • Sadi, R., Asl, H. G., Rostami, M. R., Gholipour, A., & Gholipour, F. (2011). Behavioral finance:the explanation of investors’ personality and perceptual biases effects on financial decisions. International Journal of Economics and Finance, 3(5), 421-428. http://dx.doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v3n5p234
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v3n5p234
  • Sahi, S. K., Dhameja, N., & Arora, A. P. (2012). Predictors of preference for financial investment products using CART analysis. Journal of Indian Business Research, 4(1), 61-86. https://doi.org/10.1108/17554191211206807
    » https://doi.org/10.1108/17554191211206807
  • Schroff, S. (2015). Investor behavior in the market for bank-issued structured products (Studienreihe der Stiftung Kreditwirtschaft-Verlag Wissenschaft und Praxis). Berlin: Wissenschaft & Praxis. http://dx.doi.org/10.3790/978-3-89644-696-4
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.3790/978-3-89644-696-4
  • Shefrin, H., & Statman, M. (1993). Behavioral aspects of the design and marketing of financial products. Financial Management, 22(2), 123-134. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3665864
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3665864
  • Stoimenov, P. A., & Wilkens, S. (2005). Are structured products ‘fairly’ priced? An analysis of the German market for equity-linked instruments. Journal of Banking & Finance, 29(12), 2971-2993. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2004.11.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2004.11.001
  • Train, K. (2009). Discrete choice methods with simulation New York: Cambridge University Press.
  • Wallmeier, M., & Diethelm, M. (2009). Market pricing of exotic structured products: The case of multi-asset barrier reverse convertibles in Switzerland. Journal of Derivatives, 17(2), 59-72. http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/JOD.2009.17.2.059
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.3905/JOD.2009.17.2.059
  • Yang, A. (2013). Decision making for individual investors: A measurement of latent difficulties. Journal of Financial Services Research, 44(3), 303-329. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-0144-0
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10693-012-0144-0
  • Zhou, B., Katehakis, M., & Zhao, Y. (2009). Managing stochastic inventory systems with free shipping option. European Journal of Operational Research, 196(1), 186-197. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2008.01.042
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ejor.2008.01.042
Responsible editor: Prof. Jose Ruiz Evaluation process: Double Blind Review Reviewers: Pablo Castañeda; Jaime Bastias

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    10 Oct 2022
  • Date of issue
    Jul-Sep 2022

History

  • Received
    05 Aug 2020
  • Accepted
    17 May 2022
Fundação Escola de Comércio Álvares Penteado Fundação Escola de Comércio Álvares Penteado, Av. da Liberdade, 532, 01.502-001 , São Paulo, SP, Brasil , (+55 11) 3272-2340 , (+55 11) 3272-2302, (+55 11) 3272-2302 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: rbgn@fecap.br