Acessibilidade / Reportar erro
This document is related to:

Policy-making or rewards: political appointments in Brazilian municipal governments

Abstract

Brazil has 5,570 municipalities, and each local government has a stock of appointed positions. This study adopted descriptive and inferential statistics to observe the variations in the political strategies adopted when filling these positions. The research identified (1) different political appointment strategies, from those based on reward (high scope/low education level) to strategies based on policy-making (reduced scope/high education level), (2) a robust relationship between HDI and political appointments with a policy-making profile inferring lower coordination costs and informational asymmetries for principals/voters, and (3) party and electoral competition variables showed modest results as potential explanatory factors to adopting reward-based strategies. Also, the adoption of reward-based strategies - cases where municipalities’ employees presented a higher proportion of appointees with lower education levels - did not affect the odds ratios of incumbents in the next municipal elections.

Keywords:
policy; rewards; appointments; governments; municipalities

Resumo

O Brasil possui 5.570 municípios e em cada um deles governos eleitos dispõem de um estoque de cargos em comissão disponíveis para nomeação discricionária. É possível observar variações nas estratégias políticas adotadas para essas indicações? Os principais achados deste trabalho permitidos através do uso de estatística descritiva e inferencial foram (1) identificação de diferentes estratégias de nomeação política entre recompensa (escopo elevado/escolaridade baixa) e policy-making (escopo reduzido/escolaridade alta) (2) robusta relação entre IDH e nomeações políticas com perfil de policy-making inferindo menores custos de coordenação e assimetrias informacionais para principais/eleitores e, (3) variáveis partidárias e de competição eleitoral apresentaram resultados modestos como candidatas a explicar a adoção de estratégias de recompensa, da mesma forma que estratégias de recompensa - maior proporção de CCs e menor escolaridade destes - não afetaram as razões de chance de incumbentes nas eleições municipais seguintes.

Palavras-chave:
policy; recompensas; nomeações; governos; municípios

Resumen

Brasil tiene 5.570 municipios y en cada uno de ellos los gobiernos elegidos electos tienen un stock de puestos en comisión disponibles para su nombramiento discrecional. ¿Es posible observar variaciones en las estrategias políticas adoptadas para estas candidaturas? Los principales hallazgos de este trabajo obtenidos mediante el uso de estadísticas descriptivas e inferenciales fueron (1) identificación de diferentes estrategias de nombramiento político entre recompensa (alcance alto/educación baja) y formulación de políticas (alcance reducido/educación alta); (2) relación sólida entre el IDH y los nombramientos políticos con un perfil de hacedor de políticas que infiere menores costos de coordinación y asimetrías de información para los principales/votantes y, (3) las variables de competencia electoral y partidaria mostraron resultados modestos como candidatas para explicar la adopción de estrategias de recompensa, de la misma manera que las estrategias de recompensa -mayor proporción de CC y menor escolaridad de estos- no afectaron las razones de probabilidad de los titulares en las siguientes elecciones municipales.

Palabras clave:
políticas públicas; recompensas; nombramientos; gobiernos; municipios

1. INTRODUCTION

Brazil has 5,570 municipalities, and, in each of them, elected governments have a stock of commissioned positions available for discretionary appointment. Is it possible to observe changes in the political strategies for these appointments? Are there significant variations between municipalities in the proportion and education levels of holders of commissioned positions? What factors can contribute to explain the adoption of strategies oriented to achieve higher efficiency in providing public policies or to reward allies and political support?

The more conventional approach found in the literature usually reduces political appointments to patronage, public office sharing, and administrative inefficiency (Grindle, 2012Grindle, M. (2012). Jobs for the boys: patronage and the state in comparative perspective. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Prress.). However, representative governments have solved delegation problems with the implementation of preferences on public spending through the appointment of political cadres for top government positions (Rouban, 2001Rouban, L. (2001). Politicization of the civil service. In G. Peters, & J. Pierre (Eds.), Handbook of public administration (pp. 380-391). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage). Understanding the relevance and implications of public service “politicization” requires a more refined analytical treatment, which does not consider occupants of free appointment positions as a homogeneous set but considers the proportion of these positions in the public administration and the capacity of their occupants.

Regarding the Federal Government, there are papers that analyze the positions of trust by considering their recruitment, party affiliation, and turnover (Lopez, 2015Lopez, F., & Praça, S. (2015). Critérios e lógicas de nomeação para o alto escalão da burocracia federal brasileira. In F. Lopez (Org.), Cargos de confiança no presidencialismo de coalizão brasileiro. Brasília, DF: Ipea.; Lopez & Moreira, 2019Lopez, F., & Silva, T. (2019). Filiações partidárias e nomeações para cargos da burocracia federal (1999-2018). Revista de Administração Pública, 53(4), 711-731. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220180387
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-76122018038...
; Lopez & Silva, 2019Lopez, F., & Silva, T. (2019). Filiações partidárias e nomeações para cargos da burocracia federal (1999-2018). Revista de Administração Pública, 53(4), 711-731. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220180387
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-76122018038...
). There is still a gap in investigations on political appointments in subnational governments. This paper follows this direction and contributes to the analysis of the scale and capacity of nominees for positions of trust in Brazilian municipalities.

To achieve this goal, the text is organized as follows: in addition to this introduction, the second section reviews the national and international literature that addresses political appointments, seeking especially to distinguish the different analytical categories employed in this effort, and explains the research hypotheses. The third section presents the indicators, sources, and analytical procedures adopted. The four section shows the results, based on the use of descriptive and inferential statistics. Finally, the conclusion highlights the contributions of the study to the topic.

2. POLICITIZATION, POLITICAL APPOINTMENTS, AND PATRONAGE

Representative governments are challenged by the trade-off between being responsive to the major preferences of the electorate and being effective in the provision of public goods. Political parties and government bureaucracies were the responses built to address this challenge. Voters delegate prerogatives for politicians to implement their preferences, and they transfer responsibilities to bureaucrats for executing public programs and services. In democracies, this process has shady zones with high coordination costs - due to the main agents of these processes -, oligopolistic supply, and information asymmetry in favor of the respective agents. There is an extensive literature, both on delegation losses in the voters/politicians’ circuit (Manin, 1995Manin, B. (1995). Principes du gouvernement représentatif. Paris, France: Calmann-Lévy. ; Przeworski, Stokes, & Manin, 1999Przeworski, A., Stokes, S., & Manin, B. (1999). Democracy, accountability, and representation. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.) and on politicians/bureaucrats relationship (Fiorina, 1981Fiorina, M. (1981). Congressional control of the bureaucracy: a mismatch of capabilities and incentives. In L. Dodd, & B. Oppenheimer (Eds.), Congress reconsidered (pp. 332-348). Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.; McCubbins & Schwartz, 1984McCubbins, M., & Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: police patrols versus fire alarms. American Journal of Political Science, 28(1), 165-179. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/2110792
https://doi.org/10.2307/2110792...
; McCubbins, Weingast, & Noll, 1989McCubbins, M., Noll, R., & Weingast, B. (1989). Structure and process, politics and policy: administrative arrangements and the political control of agencies. Virginia Law Review, 75(2), 431-482. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/1073179
https://doi.org/10.2307/1073179...
; Moe, 1989Moe, T. (1989). The politics of bureaucratic structure. In J. Chubb, & P. Peterson (Eds.), Can the government govern? Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.; Weingast, 1984Weingast, B. (1984). The congressional-bureaucratic system: a principal agent perspective. Public Choice, 44(1), 147-191. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00124821
https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00124821...
).

How to limit the discretion of professional bureaucracies, by subjecting them to preferences dictated by political and electoral competition, has been a puzzle in the agenda of comparative studies on political institutions, over the last century. For Weber (1984Weber, M. (1984). Economia y Sociedad. México, DC: Fondo de Cultura Económica.), its solution would lie in well-established hierarchical chains and exhaustive and written rules as protocols for submitting the decisions of civil servants.

Weberian optimism did not captivate authors affiliated to the theory of public choice, for whom the power of bureaucrats would lead, inexorably, to the satisfaction of self-interest and servants’ careers (Tullock, 1965Tullock, G. (1965). The politics of bureaucracy. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.), inefficiency and capture (Downs, 1967Downs, A. (1967). Inside bureaucracy. Boston, MA: Little.), and maximization of public agencies’ budget (Niskanen, 1971Niskanen, W. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago, IL: Aldine.). More recently, the New Public Management journal has replicated skepticism in more moderate doses, suggesting more flexible models of recruitment and public careers, in addition to the replacement of ex-ante by ex-post controls, through performance evaluations (J. Denhardt & R. Denhardt, 2007Denhardt, J., & Denhardt, R. (2007). The new public service: serving, not steering. New York, NY: M. E. Sharpe.; Ferraz, 2020Ferraz, D. (2020). Administração (a)política? O retrato e os fatores de seleção do dirigente público. Revista de Administração Pública, 54(5), 1166-1187. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190417
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-76122019041...
).

The strategy of politicizing the administration (Rouban, 2001Rouban, L. (2001). Politicization of the civil service. In G. Peters, & J. Pierre (Eds.), Handbook of public administration (pp. 380-391). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage) was an alternative to address problems stemming from the discretion of officials not subject to ballot and to temporary mandates. Although on a much smaller scale, compared to the spoil system of the 19th century, by blurring the rigid boundaries between politics and administration projected by Weber (1984Weber, M. (1984). Economia y Sociedad. México, DC: Fondo de Cultura Económica.) and Woodrow Wilson (1955Wilson, W. (1955). Study of public administration. Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press. ), appointment to high-level positions in the public administration provided a resource for politicians to re-establish hierarchical chains of command in contemporary civil service. Parties in contemporary polyarchies have not developed isomorphic attributes, thus distinguishing themselves as vote-seekers, policy-seekers, or office-seekers (Muller & Strom, 1999Muller, W., & Strom, K. (1999). Policy, office or votes? How political parties in Western Europe make hard decisions. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.). However, even when guided by the maximization of control over political appointments, it would be possible to distinguish intrinsic strategies from instrumental ones, the latter aimed at occupying positions in order to extend their influence in public policy formulation (Budge & Laver, 1986Budge, I., & Laver, M. (1986). Office seeking and policy pursuit in coalition theory. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 11(4), 485-506. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/439930
https://doi.org/10.2307/439930...
).

The practice of patronage has a long history in studies on comparative politics (Bearfield, 2009Bearfield, D. (2009). What is patronage? A critical reexamination. Public Administration Review, 69(1), 64-76. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6210.2008.01941.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6210.2008...
; Doherty, Lewis, & Limbocker, 2019Doherty, K., Lewis, D., & Limbocker, S. (2019). Presidential control and turnover in regulatory personnel. Administration & Society, 51(10), 1606-1630. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0095399719875458
https://doi.org/10.1177/0095399719875458...
; Bach, Hammerschmid, & Löfflerl, 2020Bach, T., Hammerschmid, G., & Löfflerl, L. (2020). More delegation, more political control? Politicization of senior-level appointments in 18 European countries. Public Policy and Administration, 35(1), 3-23. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0952076718776356
https://doi.org/10.1177/0952076718776356...
). Under the lens of modernization theory, patronage has been related to social, economic, and political underdevelopment and to categories such as clientelism, pork barrel, and corruption (Eisenstadt & Roniger, 1980Eisenstadt, S., & Roninger, L. (1980). Patron-client relations as a model of structuring social exchange. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 22(1), 42-77. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1017/S0010417500009154
https://doi.org/10.1017/S001041750000915...
; Scott, 1969Scott, J. (1969). Corruption, machine politics, and political change. American Political Science Review, 63(4), 1142-1158. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/1955076
https://doi.org/10.2307/1955076...
; Weingrod, 1968Weingrod, A. (1968). Patrons, patronage, and political parties. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 10(4), 377-400. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1017/S0010417500005004
https://doi.org/10.1017/S001041750000500...
). It would also represent residues of traditional societies, an anachronism doomed to be displaced by modern mass parties endowed with ideological programs and grounded in class, religious, or territorial cleavages (Neumann, 1956Neumann, S. (1956). Modern political parties: approaches to comparative politics. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.), as opposed to individual incentives offered by patronage-based organizations (Shefter, 1977Shefter, M. (1977). Party and patronage: Germany, England, and Italy. Politics & Society, 7(4), 403-451. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0032 32927700700402
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032 32927700700...
). Also frequent is the interchangeable use of the analytical categories patronage, clientelism, and pork barrel (Kitschelt & Wilkinson, 2007Kitschelt, H., & Wilkinson, S. I. (2007). Patrons, clients, and policies: patterns of democratic accountability and political competition. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.).

We find a distinct perspective in Kopecky et al. (2016Kopecky, P., Meyer-Sahling, J., Panizza, F., Scherlis, G., Schuster, C., & Spirova, M. (2016). Party patronage in contemporary democracies: results from an expert survey in twenty-two countries from five regions. European Journal of Political Research, 55(2), 416-431. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12135
https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12135...
), Kopecky and Mair (2011)Kopecky, P., & Mair, P. (2011, junho). Party patronage in contemporary Europe: principles and practices (Working Paper, n. 41). San Domenico di Fiesole, FI: European University Institute., and Kopecky and Scherlis (2008). Here we find an effort to dissect the concept and distinguish it from allegedly anachronistic particularisms by modernization: different from clientelism (selective allocation of public resources), pork barrel (allocation of government funds to specific constituencies), and corruption (illegal use of public resources for private gains), patronage should be considered ‘power of parties to appoint people to positions in public and semi-public life’ (Kopecky & Mair, 2011Kopecky, P., & Mair, P. (2011, junho). Party patronage in contemporary Europe: principles and practices (Working Paper, n. 41). San Domenico di Fiesole, FI: European University Institute., p. 3).

Similar concern in delimiting the phenomenon of politicization of public service can be observed in Lopez and Silva (2019Lopez, F., & Silva, T. (2019). Filiações partidárias e nomeações para cargos da burocracia federal (1999-2018). Revista de Administração Pública, 53(4), 711-731. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220180387
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-76122018038...
). However, for the authors, discretionary choices are conceived as politicization; discretion based on party affiliation would be equivalent to partisanship, and, finally, discretionary choices in exchange for sinecures would correspond to patronage.

However, even politicization does not seem to be a simple and self-explanatory concept. For Rouban (2001Rouban, L. (2001). Politicization of the civil service. In G. Peters, & J. Pierre (Eds.), Handbook of public administration (pp. 380-391). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage), the concept may refer to three distinct phenomena: i) participation of civil servants in decision-making; ii) political engagement of civil servants; and iii) party control of appointments to public positions. Considering only the last possibility, it is still necessary to distinguish politicization as party control over the administration and provision of public policies, from its use as a resource for rewarding political loyalties.

In a the same direction, we find the distinction proposed by Kopecky and Scherlis (2008Kopecky, P., & Scherlis, G. (2008). Party patronage in contemporary Europe. European Review, 16(3), 355-371. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1017/S1062798708000306
https://doi.org/10.1017/S106279870800030...
, p. 362) for the motivations for political appointments as control over public policy or reward for followers, in addition to the proportion of political appointments in public administration. Looking for nuances of the phenomenon, Meyer-Sahling and Veen (2012Meyer-Sahling, J. H., & Veen, T. (2012). Governing the post-communist state: government alternation and senior civil service politicization in Central and Eastern Europe. East European Politics, 28(1), 4-22. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1080/13523279.2011.635651
https://doi.org/10.1080/13523279.2011.63...
) distinguish between party and embedded politicization, the latter characterized by appointments based on career servers.

Political appointments have been analyzed mainly in national research on federal agencies (Abbers & Oliveira, 2015Abbers, R., & Oliveira, M. (2015). Nomeações políticas no Ministério do Meio Ambiente (2003-2013): interconexões entre ONGs, partidos e governos. Opinião Pública, 21(2), 336-364. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912015212336
https://doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912015212...
; Albrecht, 2021Albrecht, N. (2021). Reflexões sobre nomeações a cargos públicos no Brasil: a experiência de três secretarias entre 2011 e 2018. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política, 36, e246012. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-3352.2021.36.246012
https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-3352.2021.3...
; Batista & Lopez, 2021Batista, M., & Lopez, F. (2021). Ministerial typology and political appointments: where and how do presidents politicize the bureaucracy? Brazilian Political Science Review, 15(1), e0004. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1981-3821202100010004
https://doi.org/10.1590/1981-38212021000...
; Lima, 2018Lima, I. (2018). O impacto do arranjo institucional brasileiro no controle político sobre a burocracia. Cadernos EBAPE.BR, 16(4), 656-666. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1679-395165820
https://doi.org/10.1590/1679-395165820...
; Lopez & Moreira, 2022Lopez, F., & Moreira, T. (2022). O carrossel burocrático dos cargos de confiança: análise de sobrevivência dos cargos de direção (DAS) do Executivo Federal brasileiro (1999-2017). Dados, 65(2), e20200157. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/dados.2022.65.2.263
https://doi.org/10.1590/dados.2022.65.2....
; Lopez & Praça, 2015Lopez, F., & Praça, S. (2015). Critérios e lógicas de nomeação para o alto escalão da burocracia federal brasileira. In F. Lopez (Org.), Cargos de confiança no presidencialismo de coalizão brasileiro. Brasília, DF: Ipea.; Lopez & Silva, 2019Lopez, F., & Silva, T. (2019). Filiações partidárias e nomeações para cargos da burocracia federal (1999-2018). Revista de Administração Pública, 53(4), 711-731. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220180387
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-76122018038...
; Olivieri, 2007Olivieri, C., Martinelli, B., Massucatto, P., & Silva, C. (2018). Gestão municipal e corrupção na implementação de programas educacionais federais. Revista de Administração Pública, 52(1), 169-179. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612171081
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612171081...
; Palotti & Cavalcante, 2018Palotti, P., & Cavalcante, P. (2018). Does one size fit all? An analysis of portfolio allocation in the Brazilian multiparty presidential system. Opinião Pública, 24(2), 427-455. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912018242427
https://doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912018242...
). Lopez and Praça (2015)Lopez, F., & Praça, S. (2015). Critérios e lógicas de nomeação para o alto escalão da burocracia federal brasileira. In F. Lopez (Org.), Cargos de confiança no presidencialismo de coalizão brasileiro. Brasília, DF: Ipea. identified patterns in appointments to the top echelon of the Brazilian federal bureaucracy: islands of excellence together with greater party influence in areas responsible for social policies and infrastructure, as well as ordering expenses, regulating and directing state-owned companies; the higher the position, the more centralized the choice decision; preservation of regional criteria in occupying positions. Santos (2009Santos, L. (2009). Burocracia profissional e a livre nomeação para cargos de confiança no Brasil e nos EUA. Revista do Serviço Público, 60(1), 5-28. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v60i1.8
https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v60i1.8...
) compared positions of free appointment in Brazil and the United States.

If studies on discretionary appointments to positions in the federal administration have increased the knowledge on their dynamics, studies on this phenomenon in subnational governments in Brazil are still rare. Borges (2010Borges, A. (2010). Dinâmica político-eleitoral, burocracia e gasto social estadual. Caderno CRH, 23(58), 91-109. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-49792010000100007
https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-4979201000...
) and Gomes, Lacerda, and Silva (2020Gomes, S., Lacerda, A., & Silva, A. (2020). Critérios técnicos, políticos e dinâmica regional na nomeação de secretários estaduais: um estudo de caso do Rio Grande do Norte. Revista de Sociologia e Política, 28(76), e005. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987320287605
https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-98732028760...
) found political appointments in state governments. Marin (2016Marin, P. (2016). Sistemas de gestão para resultados no setor público: intersecções entre política, governança e desempenho nas prefeituras de Rio de Janeiro e São Paulo (Tese de Doutorado). Fundação Getulio Vargas, São Paulo, SP.) noticed the complexity in implementing management by results programs in municipal administrations in São Paulo and Rio de Janeiro, and the need to consider the dimensions of performance, governance, and politics. Avellaneda and Gomes (2017Avellaneda, C., & Gomes, R. (2017). Capacidade gerencial dos prefeitos e o desempenho de municípios brasileiros. Organizações & Sociedade, 24(83), 555-579. Recuperado de http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1984-9240831
https://doi.org/10.1590/1984-9240831...
) assessed the effects of mayors’ management capacity (schooling and public experience) on performance, measured by IPTU [urban real estate tax] collection. The results showed low explanatory power of mayors’ individual attributes and higher potential of political factors, such as support in the City Council and electoral cycles, which seems to indicate the relevance of political appointments as a resource for imposing local government preferences. Although focusing on clientelism and using the categories ‘legislator’, ‘fundraiser’ and ‘assistentialist’, Lopez and Almeida (2017Lopez, F., & Almeida, A. (2017). Legisladores, captadores e assistencialistas: a representação política no nível local. Revista de Sociologia e Política, 25(62), 157-181. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987317256207
https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-98731725620...
) revealed that the probability that councilmen prioritize meeting particular demands increases with electoral competition, but decreases in large municipalities and with higher electoral volatility. Cardoso and Marenco (2020Cardoso, A., & Marenco, A. (2020). Nomeações políticas nos governos municipais e performance burocrática: avaliando o desempenho. Revista de Administração Pública, 54(3), 360-380. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190020
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-76122019002...
) studied the relationships between political appointments and municipal performance, and showed the need to develop cut-offs to better capture these links. Several papers have already considered schooling as one of the dimensions to explain municipal and state capacity (Batista, 2015Batista, M. (2015). Burocracia local e qualidade da implementação de políticas descentralizadas: uma análise da gestão de recursos federais pelos municípios brasileiros. Revista do Serviço Público, 66(3), 345-370. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v66i3.571
https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v66i3.571...
; Batista, Rocha, & Santos, 2020Batista, M., & Lopez, F. (2021). Ministerial typology and political appointments: where and how do presidents politicize the bureaucracy? Brazilian Political Science Review, 15(1), e0004. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1981-3821202100010004
https://doi.org/10.1590/1981-38212021000...
; Cardoso & Marenco, 2019Cardoso, A., & Marenco, A. (2019). Qualidade burocrática e performance estatal: desvendando a caixa-preta do município. Administração Pública e Gestão Social, 11(4), 1-21. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.21118/apgs.v4i11.6318
https://doi.org/10.21118/apgs.v4i11.6318...
; Marenco, 2017Marenco, A. (2017). Burocracias profissionais ampliam capacidade estatal para implementar políticas? Governos, burocratas e legislação em municípios brasileiros. Dados, 60(4), 1025-1058. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/001152582017141
https://doi.org/10.1590/001152582017141...
; Marenco & Strohschoen, 2018Marenco, A., & Strohschoen, M. (2018). Abrindo a caixa-preta da gestão municipal: variações no perfil de burocracias governamentais locais. In A. Marenco, & M. I. Noll (Orgs.), A política, as políticas e os controles. Como são governadas as cidades brasileiras (pp. 49-64). Porto Alegre, RS: Tomo Editorial.; Marenco, Stroeschen, & Joner, 2017Marenco, A., Strohschoen, M., & Joner, W. (2017). Capacidade estatal, burocracia e tributação nos municípios brasileiros. Revista de Sociologia e Política, 25(64), 3-21. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987317256401
https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-98731725640...
).

At this point, the challenge consists in seeking an analytical modeling capable of unraveling the adoption of different strategies in the use of the resource of political appointments. On the one side, we can connect Barbara Geddes’s (1994Geddes, B. (1994). Politician’s dilemma. Building state capacity in Latin America. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.) politician’s dilemma, which argues that public policies potentially capable of producing economic development and quality of public services would be public goods endowed with high future discount rates, since their medium and long- term effects contrast with the political instability and short electoral cycles that can threaten the continuity of political careers. Hence, it would be safer for certain politicians to seek short-term rewards through patronage:

Politicians who might otherwise consider offering reforms as a strategy for attracting support, will not be able to afford the cost in lost political resources as long as they compete with others able to use such resources in the struggle for votes. This is the politician’s dilemma. A politician might in some circumstances, however, be willing to give up this resource if everyone else were also willing (Geddes, 1994Geddes, B. (1994). Politician’s dilemma. Building state capacity in Latin America. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press., p. 42).

Although maximizing efficiency in public policy delivery, through a meritocratic public service, might be the optimal choice for elected politicians, the disadvantage in a competition where patronage is a relevant currency would encourage balance-oriented strategies around the spoil system, which can be transposed to the game theory matrix:

Box 1
Politicians’ dilemma - rewards or policies

Policy offering may represent higher pay offs for politicians when it is the strategic choice for both, but the worst when adopted unilaterally. Otherwise, the reward decision should be the best answer for all players, regardless of the others’ choice, generating a Nash equilibrium around the spoil system.

Hence, the more unequal the distribution of government positions, the more likely would be patronage resilience. Geddes (1994Geddes, B. (1994). Politician’s dilemma. Building state capacity in Latin America. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.) assumes that the uncertainty promoted by electoral competition and change of government would represent the disjunctives to explain preferences for policy-making strategies: greater competition/alternation would equal higher political risk and preference for suboptimal choices, prioritizing less generous pay offs, but with less risk of giving spoil resources to the opponent. The blind spot seems to lie in the ambiguous function exercised by greater competition: cooperation around the suboptimal choice or a decision to minimize risk - regardless of the rival strategy - by fostering spoil?

A second problem in Geddes’s (1994Geddes, B. (1994). Politician’s dilemma. Building state capacity in Latin America. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.) model regards the exclusivity assigned to the political supply side. Here, the blind spot in this equation seems to be located in the absence of a term related to the potential of voters for monitoring the provision of public services and conditioning choices that maximize public policies. It is about considering a contextual rationality or, in Falleti and Lynch’s terms, ‘the same mechanism operating in different contexts may lead to different outcomes’ (Falleti & Lynch, 2009Falleti, T., & Lynch, J. (2009). Context and causal mechanisms in political analysis. Comparative Political Studies, 42(9), 1143-1166. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414009331724
https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414009331724...
, p. 1151).

Several papers have examined the action of police patrols as monitoring mechanisms for municipal governments (Batista et al., 2020Batista, M., Rocha, V., & Santos, J. (2020). Transparência, corrupção e má gestão: uma análise dos municípios brasileiros. Revista de Administração Pública, 54(5), 1382-1401. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190290
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-76122019029...
; Campos, Castelar, & Soares, 2018Campos, F., Castelar, I., & Soares, R. (2018). Fatores associados à corrupção municipal em transferências de recursos da União. Nova Economia, 28(3), 879-911. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-6351/3050
https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-6351/3050...
; Grangeia, Carvalhães, & Coelho, 2021Grangeia, M., Carvalhães, F., & Coelho, R. (2021). Alcance e limites do ativismo do Ministério Público como fiscal da educação. Dilemas: Revista de Estudos de Conflito e Controle Social, 14(1), 289-317. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.17648/dilemas.v14n1.32661
https://doi.org/10.17648/dilemas.v14n1.3...
; Olivieri, Martinelli, Massucatto, & Silva, 2018Olivieri, C., Martinelli, B., Massucatto, P., & Silva, C. (2018). Gestão municipal e corrupção na implementação de programas educacionais federais. Revista de Administração Pública, 52(1), 169-179. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612171081
https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612171081...
). A less examined angle consists in identifying fire alarms as inducers of preferences to be followed by elected representatives.

In this direction, alternative causal inference can be found in Cortazar, Lafuente, and Sanginés (2014Cortazar, J., Lafuente, M., & Sanginés, M. (2014). Serving citizens: a decade of civil service reforms in Latin America (2004-13). Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.). In this case, a factor that affects the choice of political appointments would lie in social coordination costs of potential beneficiaries for gains in the quality of public goods supply. While the latter have high costs to coordinate their action, due to high N and information asymmetry, political elites would have lower costs for collective action and the exercise of political veto power over changes.

Here it does not seem too heterodox to resort to tools from modernization theory: a pluralistic social order (Dahl, 1997Dahl, R. (1997). Poliarquia: participação e oposição. São Paulo, SP: Edusp., p. 86), translated into social development, urbanization, and schooling, leverages resources for voters to monitor representatives, while population size, social development, and lower levels of inequality should reduce the relative value of credit claiming (Mayhew, 1974Mayhew, D. (1974). Congress: the electoral connection. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.) in the electoral contest.

The analytical perspective adopted in this paper, on the one hand, follows Kopeky and Scherlis (2008)Kopecky, P., & Scherlis, G. (2008). Party patronage in contemporary Europe. European Review, 16(3), 355-371. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1017/S1062798708000306
https://doi.org/10.1017/S106279870800030...
and Rouban (2003), in delimiting patronage to discretionary political appointments, just as it seeks to distinguish analytically between strategies for efficiency and control of public policies or rewards for followers, as guiding elements of distinct party orientations. Moreover, as Kopeky and Scherlis (2008)Kopecky, P., & Scherlis, G. (2008). Party patronage in contemporary Europe. European Review, 16(3), 355-371. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1017/S1062798708000306
https://doi.org/10.1017/S106279870800030...
observe, it is necessary to measure the scope of political appointments, in order to infer distinct party utilities according to the extent of the use of discretionary political appointments. At the same time, they consider that elements to explain the different strategies adopted should be sought more in the factors responsible for reducing coordination costs and information asymmetry in favor of voters, than in the ambiguous influence of electoral competition on the process.

Therefore, we extracted the following hypotheses:

Box 2
Research hypotheses

3. MATERIALS AND PROCEDURES

In this paper, we shed light on positions of cargos em comissão or political discretionary appointments (CCs) in the Brazilian municipal administration. Thus, the purposes of the research were: a) to estimate the proportion of political appointments; b) to distinguish analytically political appointments as public policy control or rewards for supporters; and c) to identify the causes for choosing these strategies.

Data and information, regarding the 5,570 Brazilian municipalities, came from the Munic/IBGE database, in addition to electoral records from the Superior Electoral Court (TSE). The size of the task, determined by the number and heterogeneity of municipalities, as well as the resulting complexity for distinguishing strategies, brought obvious difficulties.

Following the literature examined in section 2, we chose to use two indicators as proxies for control versus reward: 1) the proportion of CCs in relation to the total number of public servants in the direct municipal administration; and 2) the level of education of those appointed to commissioned positions.

A higher proportion of people with college degree among CCs and their smaller number should indicate selectivity and control in choosing qualified managers, suggesting a preference for policy delivery as currency in the local electoral contest. In contrast, a lower proportion of CCs with higher education would assign lower value to profile and technical capability, in favor of party or electoral loyalties. Therefore, lower schooling in CCs composition, combined with a higher proportion of them in the municipal staff, suggests a preference for maximizing political loyalties, through the distribution of positions and increase in their available stock.

We knew the risk of bias arising from the local supply of graduates, due to demographic factors (population size, development, proximity to higher education institutions). This problem is further addressed, through analytical procedures that measure it. One of the anonymous reviewers made a relevant and timely suggestion, for considering internal recruitment (of public servants) of those appointed to CCs in the municipalities. However, different from the federal level (Atlas of the Brazilian State, IPEA), the Munic/IBGE database does not provide this information. We should also consider that for the categories used in the text (policy-making and rewards), schooling matters more than the internal recruitment of CC nominees.

Analytical procedures had two stages: first, through descriptive statistics, we brought information on the size and composition of the civil service, the proportion of political appointments, and the education level of public office holders in Brazilian municipalities. Next, we used inferential statistics to isolate explanatory factors for the patterns found, by testing the association between the control and reward models with variables of electoral competition (party; ideology; alignment to federal and state governments; electoral competition; incumbency) and contextual variables (population size; HDI-M; Gini index).

4. RESULTS

According to data from the 2018 Munic/IBGE survey, the number of civil servants in the direct administration of Brazilian municipalities was just over 6 million, representing a growth of 198.7% since the enactment of the 1988 Federal Constitution, which transferred resources and responsibilities to municipal governments (Marenco, 2019Marenco, A. (2019). Local governments, Brazil. In A. Farazmand (Ed.), Global encyclopedia of public administration, public policy, and governance (pp. 1-6). Basel, Switzerland: Springer International Publishing.). In a smaller time span, between 2005 and 2018, the increase was 36.7%.

A first observation concerns the number of servants in relation to the municipal population. The classification adopted corresponds to that used by Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE). The average values, according to the different categories of population size, are presented in Graph 1:

Graph 1
Proportion of civil servants in relation to the population, according to municipality size (2018)

Considering the averages by population size, we observe a curve very close to the linear relationship between the relative dimension of the municipal civil service and the municipality size, measured by an R², which equals 0.955, suggesting a higher relative participation of civil servants in small municipalities. However, this information may lead to a distorted perception of an alleged internal homogeneity in each population cluster. The internal dispersion of each cluster can be measured by its respective standard deviation: 1.21 (100 to 500 thousand) to 2.39 (less than 5 thousand), indicating high variability. Similarly, when data are disaggregated, considering the correlation between the proportion of civil servants and the number of inhabitants per municipality, we reach a negative Pearson coefficient, statistically significant, but very modest (p = -.195, sig at 0.01). The relationship between the worst indicators of development and well-being - here measured by municipal HDI - and the greater dependence on public employment neither provides a more promising explanatory power (p = -.206, sig at 0.01). In other words, there is a propensity for increasing the size of municipal public service in smaller and less developed cities, but it is a weak relation, requiring other factors for a better explanation.

If we consider the hiring regime, the public service in municipal administrations must be disaggregated into statutory, ‘celetists’, non-permanent, commissioned, and trainee employees. Statutory servants (EST) are those hired under the Unified Legal Regime, through public tender, and achieving stability after three years; ‘celetists’ are employees hired by the municipality under the Brazilian Consolidation of Labor Laws (CLT) regime; non-permanent (SVP) are employees who provide services, without an employment relationship and a signed work permit, also including freelancers, interns, volunteers, and those assigned by other administrations; Commissioned positions (CC) are of free appointment and dismissal, intended for direction, management, and advisory services, and includes both individuals not connected to the administration, or civil servants and public employees (Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística [IBGE], 2018).

Graph 2 shows the distribution of links in the municipal administration, in two different periods:

Graph 2
Composition of the direct administration in Brazilian municipalities, according to the link, in % (2005 and 2018)

Data show stability in the participation of statutory employees and CCs. About three-fifths of the civil servants in Brazilian municipal administrations entered through public tenders and gained job stability after three years in the civil service. On the other hand, there was a decrease in the relative number of servants under the CLT regime, along with an increase in the number of non-permanent employees. Maybe the growth of non-permanent employees was driven by the greater flexibility of these contracts, especially given the demands and pressures for public service efficiency (Marconi, 2010Marconi, N. (2010). Uma radiografia do emprego público no Brasil: análise e sugestões de políticas. In M. Loureiro, F. Abrucio, & R. Pacheco (Orgs.), Burocracia e política no Brasil: desafios para o estado democrático no século XXI. (pp. 219-275). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Fundação Getulio Vargas. ).

Disaggregating the information on the proportion of commissioned positions, according to the population size of the 5,570 Brazilian municipalities, we observed discrepancies in political appointments according to the size of the municipalities. Graph 3 presents this information:

Graph 3
Ratio of CCs in relation to the total direct administration, according to population size (2018)

The share of commissioned positions in the direct administration workforce decreases according to the size of municipal population: while it represents 11.1% of the median value in cities with up to 5 thousand inhabitants, it accounts for only 4.3% in cities with more than 500 thousand inhabitants. However, once again, we need caution to handle central tendency indicators. As the boxplot Graph 3 suggests, the dispersion in all population clusters is significant, which can be measured by the standard deviation: decreasing in municipalities in the interval between less than 5 thousand (9.11) and 100 thousand inhabitants (5.99), and increasing again in those between 100 and 500 thousand (7.99) and over 500 thousand inhabitants (10.1).

Considering the party of the mayor elected in 2016, we found significant differences only in micro-parties, where the reduced number of municipal governments represents a distortion in the central behavior measures (Graph 4).

Graph 4
Ratio of CCs in relation to the total direct administration, according to median party values (2018)

At this point, a doubt remains - if variations in the proportion of political appointments would correspond to a path dependent pattern or, conversely, could be the product of each management’s discretion, increasing or decreasing the stock of commissioned positions. Trying to answer this question, we tested the correlation measured by Pearson coefficient between the proportional share of commissioned positions in 2005, 2008, 2014, and 2018. The results indicate that the association increases as time span decreases, with p = .327** (2005), p = .492** (2008), and p = .733** (2014), all significant at 1%.

Comparing data series for 2014 and 2018, in 49% of Brazilian municipalities there was an increase in the share of CCs in relation to the total number of direct administration employees. Unfortunately, the Munic database does not provide these data for all years, which hindered defining if the increase occurred at the end of the 2013/16 term or at the beginning of the 2017/20 term.

The second relevant dimension for examining strategies to maximize efficiency or reward political support consisted in checking the participation of cadres with higher education (undergraduate and graduate) in the group of those holding commissioned positions in municipal administrations. Initially, we sought to compare CCs with other types of relationships, such as statutory, ‘celetists’, and non-permanent employees. Graph 5 shows their distribution.

Graph 5
Proportion of municipal servers with undergraduate degree, by link (2018)

The median value referring to the percentage of occupants of commissioned positions with a college degree in municipal governments is 35.5%, below the proportion of statutory (38.5%) and non-permanent (38.3) employees, but above the ‘celetists’ (27.1%). The greater discrepancy of the latter may be related to age factors and their residual character as a contract. We should also consider the dispersion observed among those holding commissioned positions, with a standard deviation of 24 and an interquartile range of 32.4.

Would the variation in the proportional share of higher education graduates among municipal CCs be related to population size? Graph 6 offers clues to answer this question, showing the distribution of CCs with undergraduate degree, according to municipality size.

Graph 6
Proportion of higher education graduates among CCs, by population size (2018)

In the various population groups, until municipalities with up to 100 thousand inhabitants, there is little variation in the share of higher education graduates, ranging from 34% (fewer than 5 thousand) to 37.4% (50 to 100 thousand), although the corresponding standard deviations, always higher than 23, showed a marked dispersion within each cluster. The most significant increase of CCs with higher education occurs in municipalities with 100 to 500 thousand inhabitants (43.6%), and in those with over 500 thousand (58.9%). Similarly, standard deviations remain above 23, highlighting a high dispersion, even in these population groups.

Next, we tried to combine the two axes (proportion and schooling), to identify clearer patterns. Box 3 combines proportion (reduced/extended) and education (low/high). The respective medians were used as a cutoff criterion for the categories in the two dimensions:

Box 3
Political appointments in municipal governments, according to proportion and higher education graduates, in % (2018)

Here, we infer that political appointments for commissioned positions, guided by strategies to reward electoral support, correspond to the combination extended proportion/low schooling, which indicates municipalities with the highest proportion of CCs in relation to the number of servants, and with the lowest proportion of higher education among the occupants of commissioned positions. Conversely, high schooling with reduced proportion may indicate strategies for maximizing performance in the implementation of public policies. Together, the two consistent combinations represent 62% of Brazilian municipalities. However, in 38.1% of local governments we observe the combinations reduced proportion/low schooling or extended proportion/high schooling, suggesting mixed strategies, or even the weight of administrative legacies.

An issue in the agenda of studies (Batista, 2013Batista, M. (2013). Incentivos da dinâmica política sobre a corrupção: reeleição, competitividade e coalizões nos municípios brasileiros. Revista Brasileira de Ciências Sociais, 28(82), 87-106. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0102-69092013000200006
https://doi.org/10.1590/S0102-6909201300...
; Brambor & Ceneviva, 2012Brambor, T., & Ceneviva, R. (2012). Reeleição e continuísmo nos municípios brasileiros. Novos Estudos CEBRAP, 93, 9-21. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0101-33002012000200002
https://doi.org/10.1590/S0101-3300201200...
; Carneiro & Almeida, 2008Carneiro, L. P., & Almeida, M. H. T. (2008). Definindo a arena política local: sistemas partidários municipais na federação brasileira. Dados, 51( 2), 403-432. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0011-52582008000200006
https://doi.org/10.1590/S0011-5258200800...
; Cervi & Borba, 2019Cervi, E. & Borba, F. (2019). Os diretórios partidários municipais e o perfil sociodemográfico dos seus membros. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política, 28, 65-92. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-335220192803
https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-33522019280...
; Peixoto & Goulart, 2014Peixoto, V., & Goulart, N. (2014). Evolução da competição eleitoral municipal no Brasil (1996 a 2012). Teoria & Pesquisa, 23(2), 41-63. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.4322/tp.2014.012
https://doi.org/10.4322/tp.2014.012...
) asks if parties matter in the municipal arena. Thus, the next challenge was to locate parties, according to the coordinates of proportion and schooling, in political appointments to commissioned positions at municipal administrations. Graph 7 identifies party patterns in occupying political positions. We only considered parties with 100 or more city halls:

Graph 7
Party patterns of political appointments considering schooling and proportion (2018)

The result of this procedure revealed a counterintuitive picture: PPS, DEM, PTB, and PSDB are situated in the quadrant that indicates the predominance of fewer appointments with higher schooling, while PT presents the lowest proportion of higher education among the occupants of commissioned positions in municipal governments run by the party, being located in the median of the distribution, in the axis corresponding to the proportion of CCs. Low schooling in PT governments corresponds to the pattern found in all population groups, with college degrees ranging from 23.5% (between 50 and 100 thousand inhabitants) to 46.3% (5 to 10 thousand inhabitants).

Finally, PP and MDB local governments seem to fit the pattern of using positions to promote rewards: extended proportion/higher education lower than the median.

Cervi and Borba (2019Cervi, E. & Borba, F. (2019). Os diretórios partidários municipais e o perfil sociodemográfico dos seus membros. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política, 28, 65-92. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-335220192803
https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-33522019280...
) analyzed the political and social profile of local party leaders with a mandate in effect in 2016, who ran for elective office in the 2016, 2014, or 2012 elections. The results showed mostly male members of municipal party boards, with a high-school degree, an average age of 48 years old, and low political professionalization. Matching Cervi and Borba’s results with information on the education of local CCs provides an additional angle for identifying party strategies for political appointments. Graph 8 presents this result:

Graph 8
Schooling of CCs and of members of municipal party directories in %

We would expect to observe a correspondence in party averages for schooling, since members of municipal directories (DMs) comprise a potential reserve for recruiting cadres occupying municipal commissioned positions. However, we only saw that for PP and PR (lower college education in CCs and DMs), PSB and PSDB (higher college education in both). More suggestive were the observed discrepant patterns:

  • • PPS, PTB, and DEM: CCs with higher college education, supposedly recruited from outside party cadres;

  • • PT, PMDB, and PSD: leaders with higher schooling than CCs.

An established interpretation for explaining the adoption of strategies oriented to reward allies or maximize public policies is based on the association between competition and incentives to remove legacies of the administrative spoil system. Thus, Silberman (1993Silberman, B. (1993). Cages of reason: the rise of the rational state in France, Japan, the United States, and Great Britain. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.) pointed to uncertainty as a causal mechanism for reforms that produced greater administrative rationalization, while Geddes (1994Geddes, B. (1994). Politician’s dilemma. Building state capacity in Latin America. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.) stated that the removal of patronage is less likely under a structure of opportunities, characterized by less competition, alternation, and political balance.

The next step was to test the effect of competition on the probability of increasing political appointment strategies as a reward, and their impact on incumbents’ chances of success. In the first test, we used the dummy variable reward and assigned value 1 for the combination extended proportion/low schooling, which indicates municipalities with a higher proportion of CCs in relation to the set of servers with a reduced proportion of higher education. We chose the independent variables based on indicators capable of pointing the lowest electoral competition, such as the incumbency status of the mayor, alignment with federal and state governments, having been elected in 2016 with over 75% of the votes, right-wing party affiliation, and municipalities with less than 50,000 inhabitants.

In parallel, we ran a test to observe the effect of the strategy of rewarding allies for the success of mayors seeking re-election in 2020. Municipalities with re-elected mayors were ranked as 1. To identify candidates with better chances, we considered the reward pattern in appointments to commissioned positions (recomp), federal alignment (alignFed), having achieved more than 75% of the votes in the previous election (over75%2016), variation in the proportion between 2018 and 2014, suggesting expansion of CC positions (varescop1814), and population size (popless50), as shown in Table 1:

Table 1
Logistic regression, reward (2016/2020), and incumbent re-election (2020)

The explanatory power of modeling electoral competition as a factor for reward strategies was very small. Only the variables popless50 and alignEst generated statistically significant coefficients, and the population size of small or medium-sized cities (below 50 thousand inhabitants) was a robust explanation for the preference for increasing the number of CCs and distributing them to less educated occupants. Party continuity in municipal government, less competition in the previous election, and right-wing party showed extremely modest coefficients; federal alignment showed a negative relationship, although very small.

On the other hand, rewarding allies or expanding the number of commissioned positions did not increase incumbents’ chances of re-election, as well as alignment with the Federal Government or disputes in small/medium cities. In this case, only when the mayor had been elected in 2016 with more than 75% of the local votes, we observed a moderate and statistically significant coefficient for his/her chances of re-election.

Are coordination costs and voters’ information asymmetry linear or context-dependent? What conditions could reduce asymmetries between voters and politicians and allow lower coordination costs for citizens? Trying to answer this question, we made a new logistic regression, now having as dependent variable a proxy for policy-making, represented by high median values for education, and low for the proportion of political appointments. We repeated the variables that measure electoral competition, now increased with indicators of the local context, such as the Human Development Index-Municipal (HDI-M) and the Gini index of inequality. HDI-M is a composite indicator that considers population longevity, per capita income, and education (Programa das Nações Unidas para o Desenvolvimento [PNUD], 2010Programa das Nações Unidas para o Desenvolvimento. (2010). Índice de Desenvolvimento Humano Municipal. Recuperado de https://www.br.undp.org/content/brazil/pt/home/idh0/conceitos/o-que-e-o-idhm.html
https://www.br.undp.org/content/brazil/p...
). The Gini index measures the degree of income concentration in a given population, through the difference between the earnings of the poorest and the richest. Its scale is from 0 to 1, 0 representing the situation of maximum equality, and 1 the situation where a single person holds all the wealth. The expectation is that welfare and lower income concentration may create conditions that provide more resources for social monitoring of elected representatives. Similarly, the test was replicated with the dependent variable reward. The results are shown in Table 2:

Table 2
Logistic regression, policy-making, and reward (2016/2020)

Competition variables, which had shown modest results for the relationship with reward, replicated their limited performance when addressing policy-making. Incumbency showed a negative association, significant at 10%, but not very robust; federal and state alignment was not statistically significant and pointed conflicting directions; previous reduced electoral competition, measured by electoral majorities over 75%, showed a negative relationship, but again, neither significant nor robust; municipalities with less than 50 thousand inhabitants had a significant (at 5%), moderate, and negative relationship; Gini showed a more robust, negative, but not significant coefficient; finally, HDI revealed a very strong and significant association at 1%. In parallel, for reward, among political competition factors, only alignment to state government remained significant - but not very strong - with the introduction of contextual variables such as HDI and Gini. The Human Development Index showed a negative and very strong association with the pattern of reward in appointments to commissioned positions.

The clue offered by HDI allows us to resume the counterintuitive information in Graph 6: PPS, PTB, and DEM show a policy-making pattern in their municipal governments; PT, a reward pattern. To what extent can these results be explained by the demographic profile of the corresponding city halls of these parties? To try this possibility, two tests were generated with logistic regression. In the first, PPS, PTB, and DEM were coded as 1, and the others as 0; in the second, PT received the dummy variable 1, while the others were 0. In addition to HDI, Gini and population size, we used proxies for electoral competition. Table 3 shows the results:

Table 3
Logistic regression, PPS/PTB/DEM and PT (2016/2020)

The municipal governments of parties that showed a clearer policy-making pattern are located in cities with more than 50 thousand inhabitants and high HDI. Inversely, the city halls won by PT - with the lowest proportion of higher education and median scope - showed a positive association with incumbency, negative with Gini and HDI, all of these with robust coefficients. How can we interpret these results? Party patterns of policy-making seem to reflect contexts of higher development, where, despite the configuration of political competition and local alternation (strong/weak), they provide social conditions that allow better monitoring of the fire alarm type. Similarly, the appointment strategy for commissioned positions in PT governments may be influenced by local contexts that are socially more homogeneous, but less developed.

Hosmer and Lemeshow tests for overall fit indicated no statistically significant difference between the observed and predicted ratings for all models. Chi-square values were non-significant, indicating good fit of the models.

5. CONCLUSIONS

In conventional wisdom and in newspaper columns, political appointments are associated with pathologies such as clientelism, pork barrel, and corruption. The first objective of this paper was to rebuild a more nuanced picture of this phenomenon, interpreting it as an alternative to face problems of delegation between politicians and bureaucracy. To this end, we sought to distinguish the appointment strategies, considering their proportion (reduced/extended) and the schooling (high/low) of the nominees for commissioned positions in Brazilian municipal administrations.

The proportion of commissioned positions and their occupants’ schooling are related to population size, by negative and positive relationships, respectively (although, in both cases, the dispersion in each population group was significant).

Parties do not show relevant differences regarding the proportion of CCs in their administrations. Considering the combinations resulting from the proportion and schooling dimensions, the party described in the literature as policy-seeking (PT) showed low education levels of its nominees for commissioned positions, and a medium scope in the public service of its city halls. In contrast, the legends associated with office seekers, such as DEM, PTB, and PPS, showed a pattern more similar to policy-making strategies, the same found in the case of PSDB.

Electoral competition variables showed very modest results for explaining the adoption of reward strategies, and these strategies (higher proportion of CCs and lower schooling) did not affect the chance ratios of incumbents in the 2020 municipal elections.

Finally, the use of HDI, population size, and Gini coefficient as proxies for coordination costs and voters’ information asymmetries led to more promising clues, especially regarding the strong relationship between HDI and political appointments with a policy-making profile. We can connect this finding with the counterintuitive revelation that this profile of high schooling and reduced proportion was found in parties where this would not be the expected behavior. A new angle emerged when we tested the association between the city halls of those parties and contextual variables (HDI, Gini, population size). Hence, policy-making parties were related to the municipalities with higher HDI; PT, to cities with lower HDI and less inequality. In other words, more than party vocation, the local context seems to present greater predictive power, strengthening the probability found between policy-making and high HDI.

REFERÊNCIAS

  • Abbers, R., & Oliveira, M. (2015). Nomeações políticas no Ministério do Meio Ambiente (2003-2013): interconexões entre ONGs, partidos e governos. Opinião Pública, 21(2), 336-364. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912015212336
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912015212336
  • Albrecht, N. (2021). Reflexões sobre nomeações a cargos públicos no Brasil: a experiência de três secretarias entre 2011 e 2018. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política, 36, e246012. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-3352.2021.36.246012
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-3352.2021.36.246012
  • Avellaneda, C., & Gomes, R. (2017). Capacidade gerencial dos prefeitos e o desempenho de municípios brasileiros. Organizações & Sociedade, 24(83), 555-579. Recuperado de http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1984-9240831
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/1984-9240831
  • Bach, T., Hammerschmid, G., & Löfflerl, L. (2020). More delegation, more political control? Politicization of senior-level appointments in 18 European countries. Public Policy and Administration, 35(1), 3-23. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0952076718776356
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0952076718776356
  • Batista, M. (2013). Incentivos da dinâmica política sobre a corrupção: reeleição, competitividade e coalizões nos municípios brasileiros. Revista Brasileira de Ciências Sociais, 28(82), 87-106. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0102-69092013000200006
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S0102-69092013000200006
  • Batista, M. (2015). Burocracia local e qualidade da implementação de políticas descentralizadas: uma análise da gestão de recursos federais pelos municípios brasileiros. Revista do Serviço Público, 66(3), 345-370. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v66i3.571
    » https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v66i3.571
  • Batista, M., & Lopez, F. (2021). Ministerial typology and political appointments: where and how do presidents politicize the bureaucracy? Brazilian Political Science Review, 15(1), e0004. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1981-3821202100010004
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/1981-3821202100010004
  • Batista, M., Rocha, V., & Santos, J. (2020). Transparência, corrupção e má gestão: uma análise dos municípios brasileiros. Revista de Administração Pública, 54(5), 1382-1401. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190290
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190290
  • Bearfield, D. (2009). What is patronage? A critical reexamination. Public Administration Review, 69(1), 64-76. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6210.2008.01941.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6210.2008.01941.x
  • Borges, A. (2010). Dinâmica político-eleitoral, burocracia e gasto social estadual. Caderno CRH, 23(58), 91-109. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-49792010000100007
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-49792010000100007
  • Brambor, T., & Ceneviva, R. (2012). Reeleição e continuísmo nos municípios brasileiros. Novos Estudos CEBRAP, 93, 9-21. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0101-33002012000200002
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S0101-33002012000200002
  • Budge, I., & Laver, M. (1986). Office seeking and policy pursuit in coalition theory. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 11(4), 485-506. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/439930
    » https://doi.org/10.2307/439930
  • Campos, F., Castelar, I., & Soares, R. (2018). Fatores associados à corrupção municipal em transferências de recursos da União. Nova Economia, 28(3), 879-911. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-6351/3050
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-6351/3050
  • Cardoso, A., & Marenco, A. (2020). Nomeações políticas nos governos municipais e performance burocrática: avaliando o desempenho. Revista de Administração Pública, 54(3), 360-380. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190020
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190020
  • Cardoso, A., & Marenco, A. (2019). Qualidade burocrática e performance estatal: desvendando a caixa-preta do município. Administração Pública e Gestão Social, 11(4), 1-21. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.21118/apgs.v4i11.6318
    » https://doi.org/10.21118/apgs.v4i11.6318
  • Carneiro, L. P., & Almeida, M. H. T. (2008). Definindo a arena política local: sistemas partidários municipais na federação brasileira. Dados, 51( 2), 403-432. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0011-52582008000200006
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S0011-52582008000200006
  • Cervi, E. & Borba, F. (2019). Os diretórios partidários municipais e o perfil sociodemográfico dos seus membros. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política, 28, 65-92. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-335220192803
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0103-335220192803
  • Cortazar, J., Lafuente, M., & Sanginés, M. (2014). Serving citizens: a decade of civil service reforms in Latin America (2004-13) Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
  • Dahl, R. (1997). Poliarquia: participação e oposição São Paulo, SP: Edusp.
  • Denhardt, J., & Denhardt, R. (2007). The new public service: serving, not steering New York, NY: M. E. Sharpe.
  • Doherty, K., Lewis, D., & Limbocker, S. (2019). Presidential control and turnover in regulatory personnel. Administration & Society, 51(10), 1606-1630. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0095399719875458
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0095399719875458
  • Downs, A. (1967). Inside bureaucracy Boston, MA: Little.
  • Eisenstadt, S., & Roninger, L. (1980). Patron-client relations as a model of structuring social exchange. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 22(1), 42-77. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1017/S0010417500009154
    » https://doi.org/10.1017/S0010417500009154
  • Falleti, T., & Lynch, J. (2009). Context and causal mechanisms in political analysis. Comparative Political Studies, 42(9), 1143-1166. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414009331724
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0010414009331724
  • Ferraz, D. (2020). Administração (a)política? O retrato e os fatores de seleção do dirigente público. Revista de Administração Pública, 54(5), 1166-1187. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190417
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220190417
  • Fiorina, M. (1981). Congressional control of the bureaucracy: a mismatch of capabilities and incentives. In L. Dodd, & B. Oppenheimer (Eds.), Congress reconsidered (pp. 332-348). Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Press.
  • Geddes, B. (1994). Politician’s dilemma. Building state capacity in Latin America Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
  • Gomes, S., Lacerda, A., & Silva, A. (2020). Critérios técnicos, políticos e dinâmica regional na nomeação de secretários estaduais: um estudo de caso do Rio Grande do Norte. Revista de Sociologia e Política, 28(76), e005. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987320287605
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987320287605
  • Grangeia, M., Carvalhães, F., & Coelho, R. (2021). Alcance e limites do ativismo do Ministério Público como fiscal da educação. Dilemas: Revista de Estudos de Conflito e Controle Social, 14(1), 289-317. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.17648/dilemas.v14n1.32661
    » https://doi.org/10.17648/dilemas.v14n1.32661
  • Grindle, M. (2012). Jobs for the boys: patronage and the state in comparative perspective Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Prress.
  • Kitschelt, H., & Wilkinson, S. I. (2007). Patrons, clients, and policies: patterns of democratic accountability and political competition New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.
  • Kopecky, P., & Mair, P. (2011, junho). Party patronage in contemporary Europe: principles and practices (Working Paper, n. 41). San Domenico di Fiesole, FI: European University Institute.
  • Kopecky, P., Meyer-Sahling, J., Panizza, F., Scherlis, G., Schuster, C., & Spirova, M. (2016). Party patronage in contemporary democracies: results from an expert survey in twenty-two countries from five regions. European Journal of Political Research, 55(2), 416-431. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12135
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/1475-6765.12135
  • Kopecky, P., & Scherlis, G. (2008). Party patronage in contemporary Europe. European Review, 16(3), 355-371. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1017/S1062798708000306
    » https://doi.org/10.1017/S1062798708000306
  • Lima, I. (2018). O impacto do arranjo institucional brasileiro no controle político sobre a burocracia. Cadernos EBAPE.BR, 16(4), 656-666. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1679-395165820
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/1679-395165820
  • Lopez, F. (2015). Cargos de confiança no presidencialismo de coalizão brasileiro Brasília, DF: Ipea.
  • Lopez, F., & Almeida, A. (2017). Legisladores, captadores e assistencialistas: a representação política no nível local. Revista de Sociologia e Política, 25(62), 157-181. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987317256207
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987317256207
  • Lopez, F., & Moreira, T. (2022). O carrossel burocrático dos cargos de confiança: análise de sobrevivência dos cargos de direção (DAS) do Executivo Federal brasileiro (1999-2017). Dados, 65(2), e20200157. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/dados.2022.65.2.263
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/dados.2022.65.2.263
  • Lopez, F., & Praça, S. (2015). Critérios e lógicas de nomeação para o alto escalão da burocracia federal brasileira. In F. Lopez (Org.), Cargos de confiança no presidencialismo de coalizão brasileiro Brasília, DF: Ipea.
  • Lopez, F., & Silva, T. (2019). Filiações partidárias e nomeações para cargos da burocracia federal (1999-2018). Revista de Administração Pública, 53(4), 711-731. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220180387
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-761220180387
  • McCubbins, M., Noll, R., & Weingast, B. (1989). Structure and process, politics and policy: administrative arrangements and the political control of agencies. Virginia Law Review, 75(2), 431-482. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/1073179
    » https://doi.org/10.2307/1073179
  • McCubbins, M., & Schwartz, T. (1984). Congressional oversight overlooked: police patrols versus fire alarms. American Journal of Political Science, 28(1), 165-179. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/2110792
    » https://doi.org/10.2307/2110792
  • Manin, B. (1995). Principes du gouvernement représentatif Paris, France: Calmann-Lévy.
  • Marconi, N. (2010). Uma radiografia do emprego público no Brasil: análise e sugestões de políticas. In M. Loureiro, F. Abrucio, & R. Pacheco (Orgs.), Burocracia e política no Brasil: desafios para o estado democrático no século XXI (pp. 219-275). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Fundação Getulio Vargas.
  • Marenco, A. (2017). Burocracias profissionais ampliam capacidade estatal para implementar políticas? Governos, burocratas e legislação em municípios brasileiros. Dados, 60(4), 1025-1058. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/001152582017141
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/001152582017141
  • Marenco, A. (2019). Local governments, Brazil. In A. Farazmand (Ed.), Global encyclopedia of public administration, public policy, and governance (pp. 1-6). Basel, Switzerland: Springer International Publishing.
  • Marenco, A., & Strohschoen, M. (2018). Abrindo a caixa-preta da gestão municipal: variações no perfil de burocracias governamentais locais. In A. Marenco, & M. I. Noll (Orgs.), A política, as políticas e os controles. Como são governadas as cidades brasileiras (pp. 49-64). Porto Alegre, RS: Tomo Editorial.
  • Marenco, A., Strohschoen, M., & Joner, W. (2017). Capacidade estatal, burocracia e tributação nos municípios brasileiros. Revista de Sociologia e Política, 25(64), 3-21. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987317256401
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/1678-987317256401
  • Marin, P. (2016). Sistemas de gestão para resultados no setor público: intersecções entre política, governança e desempenho nas prefeituras de Rio de Janeiro e São Paulo (Tese de Doutorado). Fundação Getulio Vargas, São Paulo, SP.
  • Mayhew, D. (1974). Congress: the electoral connection New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
  • Meyer-Sahling, J. H., & Veen, T. (2012). Governing the post-communist state: government alternation and senior civil service politicization in Central and Eastern Europe. East European Politics, 28(1), 4-22. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1080/13523279.2011.635651
    » https://doi.org/10.1080/13523279.2011.635651
  • Moe, T. (1989). The politics of bureaucratic structure. In J. Chubb, & P. Peterson (Eds.), Can the government govern? Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.
  • Muller, W., & Strom, K. (1999). Policy, office or votes? How political parties in Western Europe make hard decisions Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
  • Neumann, S. (1956). Modern political parties: approaches to comparative politics Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
  • Niskanen, W. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government Chicago, IL: Aldine.
  • Olivieri, C., Martinelli, B., Massucatto, P., & Silva, C. (2018). Gestão municipal e corrupção na implementação de programas educacionais federais. Revista de Administração Pública, 52(1), 169-179. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612171081
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0034-7612171081
  • Palotti, P., & Cavalcante, P. (2018). Does one size fit all? An analysis of portfolio allocation in the Brazilian multiparty presidential system. Opinião Pública, 24(2), 427-455. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912018242427
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/1807-01912018242427
  • Peixoto, V., & Goulart, N. (2014). Evolução da competição eleitoral municipal no Brasil (1996 a 2012). Teoria & Pesquisa, 23(2), 41-63. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.4322/tp.2014.012
    » https://doi.org/10.4322/tp.2014.012
  • Programa das Nações Unidas para o Desenvolvimento. (2010). Índice de Desenvolvimento Humano Municipal Recuperado de https://www.br.undp.org/content/brazil/pt/home/idh0/conceitos/o-que-e-o-idhm.html
    » https://www.br.undp.org/content/brazil/pt/home/idh0/conceitos/o-que-e-o-idhm.html
  • Przeworski, A., Stokes, S., & Manin, B. (1999). Democracy, accountability, and representation Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
  • Rouban, L. (2001). Politicization of the civil service. In G. Peters, & J. Pierre (Eds.), Handbook of public administration (pp. 380-391). Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage
  • Santos, L. (2009). Burocracia profissional e a livre nomeação para cargos de confiança no Brasil e nos EUA. Revista do Serviço Público, 60(1), 5-28. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v60i1.8
    » https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v60i1.8
  • Scott, J. (1969). Corruption, machine politics, and political change. American Political Science Review, 63(4), 1142-1158. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/1955076
    » https://doi.org/10.2307/1955076
  • Shefter, M. (1977). Party and patronage: Germany, England, and Italy. Politics & Society, 7(4), 403-451. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0032 32927700700402
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0032 32927700700402
  • Silberman, B. (1993). Cages of reason: the rise of the rational state in France, Japan, the United States, and Great Britain Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
  • Tullock, G. (1965). The politics of bureaucracy Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.
  • Weber, M. (1984). Economia y Sociedad México, DC: Fondo de Cultura Económica.
  • Weingast, B. (1984). The congressional-bureaucratic system: a principal agent perspective. Public Choice, 44(1), 147-191. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00124821
    » https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00124821
  • Weingrod, A. (1968). Patrons, patronage, and political parties. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 10(4), 377-400. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1017/S0010417500005004
    » https://doi.org/10.1017/S0010417500005004
  • Wilson, W. (1955). Study of public administration Washington, DC: Public Affairs Press.
  • [Translated version] Note: All quotes in English translated by this article’s translator.

Reviewers:

  • Sérgio Praça (Fundação Getulio Vargas, Rio de Janeiro / RJ - Brazil) https://orcid.org/0000-0002-9251-8629
  • Tiago Wickstrom Alves (Universidade do Vale do Rio dos Sinos, Leopoldo / RS - Brazil) https://orcid.org/0000-0001-9979-7133
  • Peer review report:

    The peer review report is available at this URL. https://bibliotecadigital.fgv.br/ojs/index.php/rap/article/view/88611/83344
André Marenco - Ph.D. in Science Policy; Full Professor at the Department of Political Science and at the Graduate Program in Public Policies of the Federal University of Rio Grande do Sul (UFRGS). E-mail: amarencoufrg@gmail.com
Editor-in-chief: Alketa Peci (Fundação Getulio Vargas, Rio de Janeiro / RJ - Brazil) https://orcid.org/0000-0002-0488-1744
Associate editor: Sandro Cabral (Insper Instituto de Ensino e Pesquisa, São Paulo / SP - Brazil) https://orcid.org/0000-0002-8663-2441

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    20 Mar 2023
  • Date of issue
    Jan-Feb 2023

History

  • Received
    05 June 2022
  • Accepted
    19 Dec 2022
Fundação Getulio Vargas Fundaçãoo Getulio Vargas, Rua Jornalista Orlando Dantas, 30, CEP: 22231-010 / Rio de Janeiro-RJ Brasil, Tel.: +55 (21) 3083-2731 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: rap@fgv.br