Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Rising human capital but constant inequality: the education composition effect in Brazil

Abstracts

This paper examines the impact of the education composition of the workforce and of the changing returns to schooling on the dispersion of male labor earnings in Brazil in the last twenty years. It applies a quantile regression approach to a polynomial on age, time and interactions, using repeated cross-sections of a large Brazilian annual household survey. Counterfactual results indicate that the rise in the schooling level of the Brazilian labor force failed to bring inequality down because the changes in education composition reinforced inequality. Simulations suggest that the education composition of the workforce will contribute to a substantial downward trend in overall inequality in the near future.

Economic; Development; Wage Inequality; Education


Este artigo examina o impacto da composição educacional da força de trabalho e dos retornos à educação sobre a dispersão dos salários dos homens no Brasil nos últimos 20 anos. Ele aplica uma regressão quantílica sobre um polinômio de idade, tendência e interações usando dados das PNADs entre 1977 e 1997. Os resultados indicam que o aumento da escolaridade da população brasileira não provocou uma queda da desigualdade porque as mudanças na composição educacional contribuiram para um aumento da desigualdade. As simulações indicam que o efeito de composição vai contribuir para uma queda substancial da desigualdade no futuro próximo.


Rising human capital but constant inequality: the education composition effect in Brazil* * IBMEC-SP. Rua Quatas, 300, 04546-042, São Paulo-SP. We would like thank Renata Narita for excellent research assistance and Amanda Gosling, John Van Reenen, audience members at the Latin American Economic and Econometric Society meetings for useful comments.

Naercio Aquino Menezes-FilhoI; Reynaldo FernandesII; Paulo PicchettiIII

IIBMEC e FEA-USP

IIFEA-RP-USP

IIIFEA-USP

ABSTRACT

This paper examines the impact of the education composition of the workforce and of the changing returns to schooling on the dispersion of male labor earnings in Brazil in the last twenty years. It applies a quantile regression approach to a polynomial on age, time and interactions, using repeated cross-sections of a large Brazilian annual household survey. Counterfactual results indicate that the rise in the schooling level of the Brazilian labor force failed to bring inequality down because the changes in education composition reinforced inequality. Simulations suggest that the education composition of the workforce will contribute to a substantial downward trend in overall inequality in the near future.

Keywords: Economic; Development; Wage Inequality; Education.

JEL Code: J31; O15.

RESUMO

Este artigo examina o impacto da composição educacional da força de trabalho e dos retornos à educação sobre a dispersão dos salários dos homens no Brasil nos últimos 20 anos. Ele aplica uma regressão quantílica sobre um polinômio de idade, tendência e interações usando dados das PNADs entre 1977 e 1997. Os resultados indicam que o aumento da escolaridade da população brasileira não provocou uma queda da desigualdade porque as mudanças na composição educacional contribuiram para um aumento da desigualdade. As simulações indicam que o efeito de composição vai contribuir para uma queda substancial da desigualdade no futuro próximo.

1. INTRODUCTION

In terms of income distribution, Brazil is one of the most unequal countries in the world. The Human Development Report (UND, 2000), for example, reports that among 86 countries in the world, Brazil is the most unequal. The ratio between the mean income appropriated by the 20% richest families and by the 20% poorest is about 33 in Brazil.1 1 In comparison, this ratio assumes the value of 8 in the U.S., 9 in the UK, 14 in Russia, 4 in Sri lanka and Nepal, 18 in Quenia and 30 in Guatemala (the country with the second highest ratio). Also, Squire and Zou (1998) present data on Gini coefficients which have Brazil on the top of the list with an average (over time) coefficient of 57.8 relative to a sample mean (s.d.) of 36.2 (9.2).

The level and dispersion of wages in a country at a point in time will in general depend on the distribution of characteristics of its workers, such as education, effort, experience, other observed and unobserved skills and on the returns to these characteristics. These returns will, in turn, depend on the distribution of the demand for these characteristics. Institutional factors like trade unions and minimum wages may also affect the wage structure. In Brazil, as well as other less developed countries (LDC), education is often seem as the main source of inequality. Barros et al. (2000), for example, show that the distribution of education and its returns account for about two thirds of the wage inequality from known sources in Brazil.

With respect to the role of education in shaping the evolution of wage inequality, however, the issues are more controversial. Despite the traditional view that rising human capital should provoke a drop in inequality, various authors have noted that education expansion could actually produce a rise in wage dispersion in LDC's, depending on the initial level and dispersion of education and on the relationship between schooling and earnings (see Chiswick 1971 and Fields 1980).2 2 The relationship between development and inequality started with Kuznets (1955).

Some studies attempted to clarify the issue empirically. Ram (1990) uses cross-country data to find that the relationship between the level and the dispersion of education is non-linear, with education inequality increasing up to a mean of seven years of schooling and decreasing afterwards. This could be bad news for LDC's, as education expansion from low levels could bring more inequality of education and of earnings with it.3 3 The Brazilian labor force had 4.33 years of schooling on average in 1977 and 6.33 years in 1997. However, Knight and Salbot (1983) use data from Kenya and Tanzania to show that, although the education composition effect acted to raise inequality in these countries, this was outweighed by the compression effect, i.e. the decline in returns to education associated with rising education levels. In Brazil, Ferreira and de Barros (1999) find that the decline in average returns counterweighted the increase in educational endowments to leave inequality basically unaltered between 1976 and 1996.

This paper attempts to investigate the relationship between the dynamics of education and earnings inequality in Brazil. The Brazilian case is important for, apart from its exceptionally high levels of wage inequality, education has expanded considerably over the last two decades, especially elementary education, but wage dispersion has remained roughly unaltered (see below). We make use of repeated cross-sections of a very large Brazilian individual level data set to group the data by narrowly defined education levels and apply quantile regressions to a specification containing age, trends and macroeconomic effects, as in MaCurdy and Mroz (1995) and Gosling et al. (1999). With this framework, we will be able to reconstruct the evolution of the entire wage distribution over time and use variance decomposition techniques and counterfactuals to examine the separate impacts of the composition and of the economic returns to each educational level on wage dispersion, conditionally on cyclical and demographic effects.

Finally, it is important to note that the impact of education supply on earnings has also been recently and extensively examined in the context of developed economies, in order to explain the different patterns of the rise in wage inequality across countries. One such study is Gottschalk and Joyce (1998) that finds that most of the differences in the returns to skill across countires can be explained by differences in supply shifts.

2. DATA DESCRIPTION

In this paper we use a particularly rich data set, consisting of repeated cross-sections of an annual household survey (PNAD), conducted each September by the Brazilian Census Bureau (IBGE). Each cross-section is a representative sample of the Brazilian population and contains about 100,000 observations on households, from which around 330,000 individuals are interviewed. From the original data we kept only males (to avoid the usual composition problems associated with changes in female participation), with positive hours worked in the reference week, positive monetary remuneration and between 24 and 56 years of age.4 4 We prefered to keep in the sample the self-employed and agricultural workers and those working in the informal sector of the economy. We split the sample into six education groups: illiterates (0 years of schooling), incomplete elementary (1 to 3), complete elementary (4 to 5), (at least some) secondary (6 to 8), (at least some) high school (9 to 11) and (at least some) college (higher than 12). Within each education group we further group the data into 693 cells (33 age groups and 21 years). The sample period ranges from 1977 to 1997 and the final sample sizes are set out in Table 1.5 5 It is important to note that PNAD was not conducted in 1991 (census year) nor in 1994 (for budget reasons). We therefore interpolated the wage figures for these years within each education and age group using the adjacent years.

The main variable used in this analysis is real hourly wage, defined as normal labor income in the main job in the reference month normalized by normal weekly working hours. The last column of Table 1 presents the median wage for each education group in 1996. As the numbers are approximately equivalent to American dollars,6 6 The Brazilian Currency is the Real (R$). In October 1996, 1R$ @ 1US$, so that the figures can be interpreted as the hourly wage in dollars. one can note, first of all, the low wage levels prevailing in the Brazilian economy. In 1996, for example, about 75% of all Brazilian workers we earning less than the American minimum wage (U$4.76). Moreover, the difference in wages across educational levels seems remarkable as well, since the median college educated worker earns about 11 times more than the median illiterate and about two and a half times more than the median high school worker.

Figure 1 and 2 describe the evolution of the education composition of the Brazilian workforce, by plotting the percentage of each education group in the labor force across cohorts and over time. It is clear that meaningful changes across cohorts are taking place, that are reflected in the composition of the workforce over the sample period. Figure 1 depicts the big decline in the percentage of workers with no schooling (ed1), that represented 40% of the individuals born in 1923 and only about 8% of the 1971 cohort. The group with only basic reading and writing skills (ed2) also fell from 28% of the workforce to about 14% in the newest generation. The participation of the group with complete primary education has remained roughly constant, whereas a continuous increase was observed in the proportion of workers with secondary (ed4) and with high school education (ed5), these two groups jointly accounting for about 50% of the 1971 cohort composition. Interestingly, the proportion of workers with college education was increasing at the same rate of the high school group until the 1947 cohort, when it suddenly stopped growing. Figure 2 shows that these movements across generations are smoothed when plotted over time, since the different cohorts coexist at a point in time.



The differentials in mean (log) wage between each two successive education groups are plotted in figure 3.7 7 It is important to emphasize that we are not going to try and explain either the behaviour of the wage differentials or the composition of the labor force over time, as this would take this paper beyond its aim. We take both the composition and the wage differentials as given and try and understand their implications for the behaviour of wage inequality. It seems that the price or ''compression'' effects were not as important as one might have expected, given the compositional changes described above. The most pronounced changes took place with the wage differential between the complete and incomplete elementary education (ed4-ed3), that fell markedly over the sample period and with the college wage differential (ed6-ed5), that rose continuously. It is important to note that, because the majority of the workers have 8 years or less of schooling in 1977 (72%), the workforce as a whole was much more affected by the drop in the complete elementary premium (ed4-ed3) than by the rise in college differential (ed6-ed5), which meant that average returns to education fell from 0.17 in 1977 to 0.14 in 1997.


To what extent have these changes in composition and in returns to education have impacted the evolution of the wage inequality in Brazil? In the next few sections, we will use econometric techniques to try and isolate the effects of education from cyclical, macroeconomic and experience effects.

3. ECONOMETRIC METHODOLOGY

The evolution of wage inequality over time can be described by a framework that includes time, experience and cohort effects. The time (or macro) effects include changes in economic environment, such as institutional factors, inflation and unemployment rates that affect the workforce as a whole. Experience effects capture, for example, the impact of a wage dispersion that is increasing over the life-cycle, together with an aging population. Cohort effects reflect permanent changes in the composition of the population, due to differences in the characteristics of new entrants vis-a-vis leavers in the labor market (such as the size of the cohort and the level, quality and inequality of schooling).

Unfortunately, it is impossible to disentangle their separate effects, due to a fundamental identification problem. As Heckman and Robb (1985) point out, birth cohort (c) is completely determined by age (a) and a time trend (t):

We try to model the wage equation in a parsimonious way, following MaCurdy and Mroz (1995), with functions of time, age and cohorts:

where the functions R are included to try and capture interactions between age, time and cohorts, like changing returns to experience over time. When exploring a fourth order polynomial on cohort, time, age and possible interactions between the three, we know that, because of the identification problem, out of the 30 coefficients associated with fourth order terms, only 14 linear combinations can be identified. We therefore chose as the equation to be taken to the data:

Hence, when interpreting the results of the regressions, it must be kept in mind that the cohort effects are present in the estimated coefficients. The error term in (3.3) include common time effects:

that are constructed to be orthogonal to the age and trend functions, that is, include no trends. All trends in the data will be reflected in the age and trend variables.8 8 See MaCurdy and Mroz (1995).

In the empirical investigation, we apply quantile regression techniques (Koenker and Basset, 1978). This allows us to model the evolution of the entire distribution of wages and not just the conditional mean. If all percentiles within a group evolve in the same way (apart form an intercept shift), then the changing dispersion of wages can be explained by changing prices and/or composition of observed skill characteristics. Otherwise, unbsorved effects are also important. The median defines the location of the distribution and the percentiles around it describe the changes in dispersion. We therefore have:

The set of functions Tq(t) for each quantile measures the trends in wages over time. Differences in these functions between the top and bottom of the distribution capture drifts on wage dispersion within-groups. Differences in the estimated coefficients across education groups for the same quantile measure changes in the returns to education over time at specific points of the distribution. The functions Aq(a) measure describe the wage evolution as each education group gets older. Differences in the median age coefficient across education groups capture interactions between experience and education, whereas differences in the estimated age coefficients across quantiles would mean that the variance of wages increases with age, perhaps because of differential rates of learning by doing (see Gosling et al. 1999). Common macroeconomic shocks to the wage distribution are assumed to be the same for each educational group, regardless of age.

The procedure is as follows: the raw data is split into education, year and age cells, using the fact that the variables of interest are all discrete, and we choose within each cell a population characteristic of interest. We then estimated it with the corresponding sample characteristic (using the weights provided by the household surveys). We estimate the 1st, 5th,10th,15th,..., 90th, 95th and 99th percentiles for each age, year and education cell. This is equivalent to using the full sample to regress each wage percentile on all possible education year and age interactions. The percentiles are asymptotically normally distributed (see Koenker and Portnoy, 1996). The variance of each of these estimated order statistic (q) is given by:

We estimate f(q) (the conditional density) using a Gaussian Kernel with bandwith equal to half the standard deviation of wages for each cell.

We then try to impose some structure on the wage distribution by means of a minimum distance estimator. The minimum distance procedure chooses b such as to minimize:

( - Zb)V ()-1 ( - Zb)

where is the estimated order statistic and Z is a set of linear restrictions9 9 See Rothenberg (1971) and Chamberlain (1993). . In our case, the restrictions imply that the age, trend and (orthogonal) time dummies can explain the behavior of each estimated order statistic across cells and over time. Imposing the restrictions means estimating weighted least squares regressions on the grouped data, for each quantile and education group separately. This procedure will give us consistent estimates of b.10 10 We estimate each quantile separately, which is not efficient but avoids that measurement errors in a percentile contaminate the estimation of other percentiles. Under the null hypothesis that the restrictions are valid, the minimized value follows a chi-squared distribution with degrees of freedom equal to the number of restrictions. All we have to do to construct the test statistic is sum the weighted squared residuals, i.e. the empirical percentiles minus the age and trend effects, minus the orthogonal time effects.

4. RESULTS

Tables 2 to 4 present the results of the median, 25th and 75th percentile regressions, respectively. One can note that the chi-square tests perform reasonably well in the median regressions, specially given the large degrees of freedom associated with the test. They fail to reject the restrictions in the median regression for the first, fourth and fifth educational level, while rejecting for the other three education groups.

The behavior of evolution of the 25th and 75th percentile are harder to predict, given that the restrictions were rejected in the majority of cases. It seems therefore that the functions (3.5) are best regarded as a convenient approximation to a more complex regression function (as in Chamberlain (1993), but see also the figures below).

Inspection of the estimated coefficients in Table 2 reveal some interesting features.11 11 The figures illustrating the estimated effects are available from the authors upon request. First of all, there are meaningful differences in the estimated trend and experience effects across all the educational groups, revealing that returns to education were indeed changing in Brazil over the sample period and that returns to experience vary substantially across education levels. Additionally, the interactions between trend and age are significant, which could mean that returns to experience are changing over time and/or that cohort effects are important in Brazil.12 12 For analysis of the role of cohort effects in the wage distribution, see MaCurdy and Mroz (1995) for the US, Gosling et al. (1999) for theUK and Green (1997) for Canada.

It is interesting to note that the differences in the coefficients across education levels also hold true for the other quantiles, as Tables 3 and 4 reveal. Moreover, there are marked differences between the estimated parameters across percentiles for the same education level, which indicates that important changes in the wage distribution within the education groups are taking place over time and over the life cycle in Brazil.

4.1 Fit of the Model

Besides the statistical tests, another procedure to evaluate the fit of the model and perform counter-factual experiments is to compare the observed unconditional wage distribution with the one predicted by the restricted model. In order to construct the predicted wage distribution we proceed as in Gosling et al. (1999). We first construct the conditional wage distribution, by choosing a fixed number wq (within the observed unconditional sample wage distribution ) and computing for each age/education/year cell (j):

using the predicted wages. To construct the predicted wage distribution, we use the twenty predicted percentiles for each cell and a linear interpolation between them. We do so for a number of wq's, until we have a rich description of the distribution. We then compute the unconditional distribution for each year:

where fj is the observed cell frequency in the population.

With the unconditional wage distribution we can compute any inequality measure we need. In this paper we chose to work with the variance of (log) wages which, besides being much used in the literature, is one of the decomposable measures of inequality.13 13 We also used the 90/10 wage differential and the results were very similar to the ones presented here. Figure 4 shows, firstly, that the wage dispersion has remained basically stable over the last two decades, despite the fact that this was a period of very volatile macroeconomic conditions, especially between 1986 and 1992 when inflation accelerated to unprecedented levels. It also shows that the variance of labor earnings computed with the grouped data is permanently lower than the one calculated using the individual level information, a result that is expected since grouping eliminates some of the within-cell variability. More importantly however, is the fact that the variance computed using the restricted specification follows very closely the variance of the observed wages, so that the loss in precision occurs mainly from grouping.


The evolution of the three measures of wage dispersion over time, measured as changes from the variance of wages in 1977, is described in Figure 5. The figure shows that the variance calculated from the restricted model closely mimics the behavior of the true variance, despite a period of short misalignment between 1989 and 1995. This means that we can use the predicted variance to construct counter-factuals and describe, for example, how inequality would look like had the returns to education remained at the 1977 level.


4.2 Variance Decomposition

We now use the predicted wage distribution to perform the usual variance decomposition with log wages(w):

where:

The empirical probability mass function g(wq) was calculated using:

where:

G(wq) = Pr(w < wq) = q

The first term on the right-hand-side of (4.3) refers to the within-groups dispersion and the second to the dispersion between groups. Figure 6 depicts this variance decomposition analysis using our sample. It shows that the short term behavior of the overall wage dispersion accompanied the dispersion within groups, while the behavior between groups remained basically stable throughout the sample period. In other words, the inequality of labor earnings in Brazil has risen slightly over the last two decades because of the dispersion within groups, that contributed to a fall in inequality in the first part of the 1980s followed by a substantial rise in the 1990s. The pattern of within group inequality closely followed the behavior of the inflation rates in the period and may be related to staggered wage contracts in periods of high inflation.14 14 The Brazilian Census bureau interviews individuals once a year, but in periods of rising inflation, wages are adjusted very frequently and at different times during the year. This may lead to 'artificial' rises in inequality measured at a point in time. What remains to be explained is why the between-group component of inequality failed to fall, despite the massive increase in education, accompanied by the fall in the economic returns to relatively low levels of education.


4.3 Counterfactual Analysis

As we saw above, the behavior of the variance of labor earnings can be decomposed into within-group and between-group components. Both these components are affected by the composition of the workforce, as the presence of (fjt) in equation (4.3) clearly demonstrates. Figure 7 plots the evolution of the within groups component after allowing the age structure within each education group to change, but maintaining the 1977 education configuration. It also depicts the behavior of the overall composition effect, by keeping the age structure constant as well, that is, fixing all frequency weights (fj) in 1977.15 15 The weights are computed using the cell sample size multiplied by the representativeness of each individual worker belonging to the cell in the Brazilian population.


The figure reveals that the within group contribution to overall wage dispersion was predominantly the result of intra-cell dispersion and less due to the increasing importance of cells with higher dispersion.16 16 The importance of the composition effect to the within group dispersion was emphasised by Knight and Salbot (1983). Changes in the composition of the workforce did not contribute very significantly to the cyclical variations in dispersion, but this effect has become more important in recent years. Moreover, the recent rise in importance of the composition effect is mainly due to education, since keeping the age structure also fixed (dotted line) has virtually no additional effect in the within-group component of inequality.

The evolution of the between-group contribution to inequality can be decomposed into a composition effect and a compression effect. The compression effect is evaluated by maintaining the composition of the population constant at its 1977 level, as we did with the within-group component above. Therefore, its behavior reflects the evolution of the difference between the mean wage within each cell and the overall sample mean. However, it is important to note at this point that the frequency weights have two roles in the between-group contribution to the variance of wages. Besides the role of measuring the 'importance' of each cell to the overall effect, they are also used to compute the overall (unconditional) mean wage, as expression (4.6) reveals. Therefore, the compression effect is being driven by the difference between each group mean wage and the overall mean wage that would have prevailed had the structure of the population remained as in 1977.

The composition effect is obtained by maintaining the wage distribution within cells (and therefore their mean wage) at the 1977 level and allowing the frequency weights (fjt) to change. We do this by switching off the trend effects and their interactions with age for each education group, then predicting the conditional wage distribution within each cell and using (4.6) to compute the unconditional distribution. The changes (fjt) also alter the between-groups contribution to inequality in two ways: through changes in the weight of each cell's wage deviation from the mean wage and through changes in the unconditional mean wage as well.

The evolution of the compression and composition effects over time is depicted in Figure 8, where the two components are shown to contribute very differently to the dispersion between groups. The fall in returns to low levels of education (compression effect) contributed to a significant reduction in between group inequality (of about 6%).17 17 The predicted variance of (log) wages in 1977 was 0.9 (see figure 3). Only a small part of the overall effect is due to age effects, since when we additionally keep the age composition of the workforce constant (dotted line) the behavior of the compression effect does not change very much.


On the other hand, the education composition effect followed in the opposite direction, increasing inequality by about 10%. It was the combination of these two opposite forces that led to the stability of the between-group dispersion, which, were it not for the composition effect, would be falling rapidly over the sample period. The figure also plots the total composition effect, that was obtained when we additionally held the age composition constant at 1977 (dotted lines with circles). The behavior of the two curves were every similar until 1992, when the contribution of the education composition showed a tendency to stabilize, whereas the overall composition effect continued to rise.

4.4 Simulations

From the above analysis, it seems that the education distribution has been impacting the evolution of wage inequality in Brazil in a perverse way. This sub-section examines whether this impact is predicted to change in the future, depending on the evolution of the education composition of the workforce. In order to simulate how this composition will look like in the next 40 years, we simulated the schooling structure of the share of the Brazilian workforce that will be between 24 and 56 years old in 2037. In order to do this, we predicted the education composition of each cohort between the one born 1981 and the one born 2013, based on the recent evolution of education across cohorts (figure 1). For instance, the predicted composition of the 2013 cohort under two alternative scenarios is set out in Table 5:

Based on these scenarios and using the 1997 age structure of the population, we predicted the education distribution of the workforce in 2037 and interpolated its evolution from 1997 to 2037. With these numbers at hand, we simulated how the composition effect would look like for the next 40 years, as figure 9 reveals. The composition effect is predicted to remain stable until 2007 under both scenarios, beginning to fall more rapidly between 2017 and 2017. Between 2017 and 2037 the difference between the two scenarios is more evident, with a substantial reduction in inequality occurring in the optimistic scenario, where inequality is predicted to return to its 1977 level by 2027 and drop even more by 2037. In the pessimistic scenario, inequality will return to the 1977 level by 2037.


One of the drawbacks of the present simulations is that they do not take into account the possibility of interactions between the composition and the compression effects, i.e., that the evolution of the returns to education over time might either accelerate or delay the drop in the between-groups component of wage dispersion. The dotted line in figure 9 depicts the predicted composition effect, under the pessimistic scenario, with the wage distribution fixed in 1997 instead of 1977.18 18 To do this we predicted all the wage percentiles with the trend effects (and their interactions with age) fixed in 1997 and reconstructed the wage distribution with them. It shows that the predicted composition impact is virtually the same with 1997 prices, which means that the prediction is robust to different initial wage distributions.

5. CONCLUSIONS

In this paper we investigated the behavior of the distribution of male wages in Brazil in the 1980s and 1990s. The results showed that overall inequality remained basically unaltered over this period, primarily due to the stability of wage dispersion between groups. Counterfactual experiments showed that this stability was the result of two forces acting in opposite directions. The compression effect (returns to education) induced a reduction in dispersion, whereas the composition effect contributed to a rise in inequality. Simulations using the predicted evolution of the education distribution of the workforce indicated that the composition effect will start contributing to a decline in inequality in about 10 years time. Future work will indicated whether the results obtained here apply solely to the Brazilian case or can be generalized to other less developed countries.

Bibliography

  • (2000). Human Development Report United Nations Development Programe.
  • Barros, R., Henriques, R., & Mendonça, R. (2000). Education and equitable economic development. Economia, 1:111-144.
  • Beaudry, P. & Green, D. (1997). Cohort patterns in canadian earnings: Assessing the role of skil premia in inequality trends. Technical Report 163, National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • Chamberlain, G. (1993). Quantile regressions, censoring and the structure of wages. Advances in Econometrics, 1.
  • Chiswick, B. (1971). Earnings inequality and economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 85:21-39.
  • Ferreira, F. H. G. & de Barros, R. P. (1999). The slippery slope: Explaining the increase in extreme poverty in urban brazil; 1976-1996. Revista de Econometria, 19(2):211-296.
  • Fields, G. (1980). Poverty, Inequality and Development Cambridge University Press, New York.
  • Gosling, A., Machin, S., & Meghir, C. (1999). The changing distribution of male wages in the UK. Technical Report 271, Centre for Economic Performance.
  • Gottschalk, P. & Joyce, M. (1998). Cross-national differences in the rise in earnings inequality: Market and institutional factors. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80:489-502.
  • Heckman, J. & Robb, R. (1985). Using longitudinal data to estimate age, period and cohort effects in earnings equations. In Feinberg & Mason, editors, Analysing Longitudinal Data for Age, Period and Cohort Effects Academic Press, New York.
  • Knight, J. & Salbot, R. (1983). Education expansion and the kuznets effect. American Economic Review, 73:1132-1136.
  • Koenker, R. & Basset, G. (1978). Regression percentiles. Econometrica, 46:33-50.
  • Koenker, R. & Portnoy, S. (1996). Quantile regression. Technical Report 97-0100, University Illinois, Urbana-Champaign.
  • Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality. American Economic Review, 45:1-28.
  • MaCurdy, T. & Mroz, T. (1995). Estimating macro effects from repeated cross-sections. Technical report, University of Standford.
  • Ram, R. (1990). Education expansion and schooling inequality: International evidence and some implications. Review of Economics and Statistics, 72:266-274.
  • Rothenberg, T. (1971). Efficient Estimation with A Priori Information Yale University Press, New Haven.
  • Squire, H. & Zou, H.-F. (1998). Inter-national and intra-national inequality. The Economic Journal, 108:26- 45.
  • *
    IBMEC-SP. Rua Quatas, 300, 04546-042, São Paulo-SP. We would like thank Renata Narita for excellent research assistance and Amanda Gosling, John Van Reenen, audience members at the Latin American Economic and Econometric Society meetings for useful comments.
  • 1
    In comparison, this ratio assumes the value of 8 in the U.S., 9 in the UK, 14 in Russia, 4 in Sri lanka and Nepal, 18 in Quenia and 30 in Guatemala (the country with the second highest ratio).
  • 2
    The relationship between development and inequality started with Kuznets (1955).
  • 3
    The Brazilian labor force had 4.33 years of schooling on average in 1977 and 6.33 years in 1997.
  • 4
    We prefered to keep in the sample the self-employed and agricultural workers and those working in the informal sector of the economy.
  • 5
    It is important to note that PNAD was not conducted in 1991 (census year) nor in 1994 (for budget reasons). We therefore interpolated the wage figures for these years within each education and age group using the adjacent years.
  • 6
    The Brazilian Currency is the Real (R$). In October 1996, 1R$ @ 1US$, so that the figures can be interpreted as the hourly wage in dollars.
  • 7
    It is important to emphasize that we are not going to try and explain either the behaviour of the wage differentials or the composition of the labor force over time, as this would take this paper beyond its aim. We take both the composition and the wage differentials as given and try and understand their implications for the behaviour of wage inequality.
  • 8
    See MaCurdy and Mroz (1995).
  • 9
    See Rothenberg (1971) and Chamberlain (1993).
  • 10
    We estimate each quantile separately, which is not efficient but avoids that measurement errors in a percentile contaminate the estimation of other percentiles.
  • 11
    The figures illustrating the estimated effects are available from the authors upon request.
  • 12
    For analysis of the role of cohort effects in the wage distribution, see MaCurdy and Mroz (1995) for the US, Gosling et al. (1999) for theUK and Green (1997) for Canada.
  • 13
    We also used the 90/10 wage differential and the results were very similar to the ones presented here.
  • 14
    The Brazilian Census bureau interviews individuals once a year, but in periods of rising inflation, wages are adjusted very frequently and at different times during the year. This may lead to 'artificial' rises in inequality measured at a point in time.
  • 15
    The weights are computed using the cell sample size multiplied by the representativeness of each individual worker belonging to the cell in the Brazilian population.
  • 16
    The importance of the composition effect to the within group dispersion was emphasised by Knight and Salbot (1983).
  • 17
    The predicted variance of (log) wages in 1977 was 0.9 (see
  • 18
    To do this we predicted all the wage percentiles with the trend effects (and their interactions with age) fixed in 1997 and reconstructed the wage distribution with them.
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      05 Apr 2007
    • Date of issue
      Dec 2006
    Fundação Getúlio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 11º andar, 22253-900 Rio de Janeiro RJ Brazil, Tel.: +55 21 3799-5831 , Fax: +55 21 2553-8821 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
    E-mail: rbe@fgv.br