Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Do inflation-linked bonds contain information about future inflation?

Abstracts

There is a widespread belief that inflation-linked bonds are a direct source of information about inflation expectations. In this paper we address this issue by analyzing the relationship between break-even inflation (the difference between nominal and real yields) and future inflation. The dataset is extracted from Brazilian Treasury bonds covering the period from April 2005 to April 2011. We find that break-even inflation is an unbiased forecast only of the 3-month and 6-month ahead inflation. For medium horizons (12 and 18 months), break-even inflation has weak explanatory power of future inflation. Over long horizons (24 and 30 months), we report a significant, but counterintuitive, negative relationship between the break-even and realized inflation rates.

Inflation-Linked Bonds; Real and Nominal Yields; Term Premia; Break-Even Inflation


Há uma crença generalizada de que títulos indexados a inflação são uma fonte de informação sobre a inflação futura. Neste artigo, nós estudamos essa questão analisando a relação entre a break-even inflation (diferença entre as taxas nominai e reais) e a inflação futura. A base de dados é extraída de títulos do tesouro brasileiro cobrindo o período de Abril de 2005 até Julho de 2010. Nós mostramos que a break-even inflation é um estimador não viesado da inflação somente para os horizontes de 3 e 6 meses. Para os horizontes médios (12 e 18 meses), a break-even inflation tem fraco poder explanatório da inflação futura. Para horizontes longos (24 e 30 meses), nós reportamos uma relação significante, porém negativa entre a a break-even inflation e a inflação realizada.


Do inflation-linked bonds contain information about future inflation?* * The first author thanks CNPq-Brazil for financial support. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Central Bank of Brazil.

José Valentim Machado VicenteI; Osmani Teixeira de Carvalho GuillenII

IBanco Central do Brasil and Ibmec. E-mail: jose.valentim@bcb.gov.br

IIBanco Central do Brasil and Ibmec. E-mail: osmani.guillen@bcb.gov.br

ABSTRACT

There is a widespread belief that inflation-linked bonds are a direct source of information about inflation expectations. In this paper we address this issue by analyzing the relationship between break-even inflation (the difference between nominal and real yields) and future inflation. The dataset is extracted from Brazilian Treasury bonds covering the period from April 2005 to April 2011. We find that break-even inflation is an unbiased forecast only of the 3-month and 6-month ahead inflation. For medium horizons (12 and 18 months), break-even inflation has weak explanatory power of future inflation. Over long horizons (24 and 30 months), we report a significant, but counterintuitive, negative relationship between the break-even and realized inflation rates.

Keywords: Inflation-Linked Bonds, Real and Nominal Yields, Term Premia, Break-Even Inflation.

JEL Code: E31, E43, G12.

RESUMO

Há uma crença generalizada de que títulos indexados a inflação são uma fonte de informação sobre a inflação futura. Neste artigo, nós estudamos essa questão analisando a relação entre a break-even inflation (diferença entre as taxas nominai e reais) e a inflação futura. A base de dados é extraída de títulos do tesouro brasileiro cobrindo o período de Abril de 2005 até Julho de 2010. Nós mostramos que a break-even inflation é um estimador não viesado da inflação somente para os horizontes de 3 e 6 meses. Para os horizontes médios (12 e 18 meses), a break-even inflation tem fraco poder explanatório da inflação futura. Para horizontes longos (24 e 30 meses), nós reportamos uma relação significante, porém negativa entre a a break-even inflation e a inflação realizada.

1. INTRODUCTION

Market participants and policymakers interpret break-even inflation (the spread between nominal and real yields) as the main indicator of expected inflation. According to the current Federal Reserve chairman, inflation-linked bonds appear to be the most important source of future inflation expectations (Bernanke, 2004). However, it is well known that the break-even inflation rate (BEIR) can be decomposed as an inflation expectation plus a risk premium term. This leads to the following questions: Does the BEIR efficiently predict future inflation? In other words, is the inflation risk premium negligible? A more general formulation of these issues can be stated as: Do inflation-linked bonds contain information about future prices? In this paper we shed light on these questions through a model-free procedure using data on Brazilian Treasury yields.

Our analysis is based on a series of regressions between the realized inflation (dependent variable) and the BEIR (independent variable) for the horizons of 3, 6, 12, 18, 24 and 30 months. The significance of the parameters and R2 provide a way to test the predictive ability and explanatory power of the BEIR. To avoid specification problems such as autocorrelations and endogeneity, we run these regressions using different approaches. First, we consider an OLS procedure. Next, we employ instrumental variables, estimating the model by TSLS and GMM techniques, with the covariance matrix computed according to Newey e West (1987).1 1 TSLS and GMM stand for Two-Step Least Squares and Generalized Method of Moments, respectively. The use of instrumental variables aims to keep consistency when the regressor is correlated with the error term, while the Newey-West method overcomes autocorrelation in the residuals.

Many other studies have investigated the inflation risk premium and consequently the relationship between break-even and realized inflations using real and nominal interest rates. Among others, we can cite D'Amico et alii (2008), Hördahl (2008), García e Werner (2010), Joyce et alii (2010), and Grishchenko e Huang (2010). The first four papers work in an affine arbitrage-free framework. D'Amico et alii (2008) show that although the U.S. inflation-linked bond yields contain a liquidity premium and timevarying inflation risk premium, the Treasury Inflation-Protected Security (TIPS) rates are a useful proxy for inflation expectations. García e Werner (2010) apply a model similar to that used by D'Amico et alii (2008) in the euro area. They find that the term structure of inflation risk premia is upward sloping and varies from 7 to 25 basis points. Hördahl (2008) uses a structural macroeconomic model to estimate inflation risk premia in the United States and the euro area. He shows that inflation risk premia have an increasing pattern with respect to maturity for the euro area and a flatter one for the United States. Joyce et alii (2010) estimate a joint model of UK nominal and real term structures. They find that the Bank of England's independence to set interest rates in May 1997 decreased the inflation risk premium and the inflation expectation embodied in the term structure. The article of Grishchenko e Huang (2010) computes the inflation risk premium as the difference between the TIPS break-even inflation and an estimation of future inflation. They show that the inflation risk premium is time-varying with negative values from 2000 to 2004 and positive from 2004 to 2008.

However, none of the above studies use the methodology proposed in this work. Our procedure to assess the information content in the BEIR has previously been applied in other contexts. For example, Campbell e Shiller (1991) test whether the slope of the term structure predicts changes in interest rates. To this end, they run regressions of future yields on forward yields. Christensen e Prabhala (1998) regress the realized volatility on the implied volatility of the S&P 500 to evaluate the relationship between these two volatilities. Our strategy is close in spirit to that of Campbell e Shiller (1991) and Christensen e Prabhala (1998), except we replace yields and volatility by inflation. That is an innovation of this paper: a model-free approach to measure the explanatory power of the BEIR. To the best of our knowledge, there is no study using this procedure to addresses this question.

Some countries have issued real return government securities. For example, the United Kingdom has issued index-linked bonds since 1981. On the other hand, the United States made its first issue in 1997, so the trading history is more recent. Although we could carry out this study based on data from these countries, we opt to use a Brazilian database for two reasons. First, Brazil is one of the most important emerging economies. Together with Russia, India and China, Brazil forms the so-called BRICs, a group of the most promising emerging markets. However, there are no studies about BEIR applied to an important emerging country. Second, unlike other markets, the indexation lag of Brazilian real bonds is very small (only a half month). Moreover, Brazilian real bonds do not have protection against deflation.2 2 The TIPS indexation lag is three months. Grishchenko e Huang (2010) point out that ignoring the indexation lag results in an underestimate of the inflation risk premium.

Our main findings can be summarized as follows. First, the BEIR is an unbiased estimate only of the 3-month and 6-month ahead inflation. Second, for the horizons of 12 and 18 months, the BEIR has weak explanatory power for future inflation. On the other hand, the 24-month and 30-month break-even inflations explain future inflation. However, for these two long horizons, we obtain a counterintuitive result: the relationship between the break-even and realized inflations is negative. Of course, these findings are not a puzzle. They can be easily explained by a time-varying inflation risk premium, which is not captured by our linear model. In other words, this suggests that the expectations hypothesis fails for medium-and long-term bonds. Finally, our results are robust to a number of alternative econometric methods to estimate the model.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses the methodology used in this work, while Section 3 presents the data and some stylized facts. Section 4 details the results and Section 5 concludes.

2. MODEL

Let (τ) and (τ) be the continuously compounded yields for nominal and real yields at t with time to maturity τ . The break-even inflation rate (BEIR) is defined as:

where it(τ) is the BEIR for period t and horizon τ .

Denote by ht(1) the continuously compounded annual rate of change between two observations of a price index (from t to t +1). Then, the accumulated inflation rate between t and t + τ is given by

The information content of the BEIR can be assessed by estimating a regression of the form3 3 In fact, we should write and . However, we omit the superscript τ for brevity.

Using Eq. (1), we can test if the BEIR contains some information about future inflation. If c1 is nonzero, the answer to this question is positive. Moreover, we can verify if the BEIR is an unbiased forecast of realized inflation. In this case, we should find that c1 =1 and c2 =0.

The BEIR can be decomposed as the sum of the expected inflation rate plus a risk premium and a convexity term (see Grishchenko e Huang, 2010):

where Et (∙) denotes the mathematical expectation conditional on information available at time t. The risk premium component compensates investors for the inflation uncertainty. The convexity term (also denominated Jensen's correction) is just a mathematical phenomenon due to the fact that the price of a bond is a convex function of interest rates.

The Fisher equation neglects the last two terms of the right-hand side of Eq. (2). However, if these terms are not zero, we cannot directly read the expected inflation rate from the BEIR. Our main goal in this study is to test whether the risk premium and the Jensen's correction are worthless.

As pointed out by Ang et alii (2008), the effect of convexity is of second order importance,4 4 We do not know of any study that evaluates the inflation convexity with Brazilian data. However, as shown by Joyce et alii (2010), the Jensen correction is given by V art( ht(τ)). Assuming that the monthly inflation rate is i.i.d., we have Convexity = . From Table (1) we conclude that the Brazilin inflation convexity is around 4 b.p., which is very small when compared with the level of Brazilian rates (nominal or real). then we can ignore it and rewrite Eq. (2) in a more compact way as5 5 The simplification given by Eq. (3) allows some nice interpretations and facilitates computation of the inflation risk premium. However, regarding our results, it does not matter since as stated above our main aim is to assess the connection between inflation expectation and BEIR. Possible failures in this respect are not addressed here.

The expectation hypothesis states that the term premium is constant over time but possibly maturitydependent, that is, IRPt(τ) does not depend on t. Under this hypothesis and using a further assumption of rational expectations, the econometric specification of (3) is given by (1). Therefore, Eq. (1) can also be used to test a BEIR version of the expectation hypothesis.

3. DATA AND STYLIZED FACTS

Our sample consists of a monthly series of Brazilian real and nominal yields from April 2005 to April 2011. This dataset is provided by the Brazilian Financial and Capital Markets Association (ANBIMA).6 6 ANBIMA is an association of Brazilian financial service providers. For more information about ANBIMA, see the website http://investors.anbima.com.br/Pages/Home.aspx. The term structure of nominal rates is extracted from plain vanilla (NTN-F) and zero-coupon (LTN) Brazilian Treasury bonds using the Svensson interpolation model (see Svensson, 1994). The face value of the NTN-F is R$ 1,000.00 (one thousand Brazilian Reais) and it pays a bi-annual interest coupon of R$ 48.81.7 7 The Brazilian Real/US Dollar exchange rate was around 1.65 in April 2011. LTN is a zero coupon bond with face value of R$ 1,000.00. The term structure of real rates is also constructed by the Svensson model, but the curve is fitted using NTN-B bonds, the leading inflationprotected security issued by the Brazilian Treasury. The yield of the NTN-B is linked to the IPCA, a consumer price index adopted in the inflation targeting regime of the Central Bank of Brazil.8 8 For more information about IPCA, see the website of Brazil's statistical bureau (IBGE), http://www.ibge.gov.br/english/. NTN-B does not have the indexation lag problem present in the TIPS market, since interest is paid based on the current level of the IPCA.9 9 Evans (1998) warns that the presence of a reporting lag in the price index can make index-linked bond yields imperfect measures of real yields. The IPCA is available with a maximum delay of 15 days. On average it is released in 7 days. IBGE also produces an advance version of the IPCA (IPCA-15), which contributes to a better forecast of the index price and consequently allows obtaining more accurate estimates of the real term structure. Although the NTN-B bonds have been issued since 2001, we start our sample in April 2005 to avoid liquidity problems in the NTN-B market between 2001 and 2005.

The Brazilian inflation-linked securities market is one of the largest in the world, with over US$ 250 billion of NTN-B bonds outstanding.10 10 For comparison purposes, the TIPS market has US$ 600 billion outstanding. The average term to maturity of NTN-B bonds is nearly seven years. The Brazilian fixed-rate market is also significant. The LTN and NTN-F bonds have around US$

250 billion and US$ 160 billion in bonds outstanding, with average terms to maturity of 12 and 30 months, respectively.11 11 These data are for April 2011. For more information about the Brazilian Treasury bond market, see the website of the Central Bank of Brazil, http://www.bcb.gov.br/?english.

Table 1 presents some descriptive statistics of the BEIR and IPCA. The averages of the IPCA and BEIR for all horizons are around 5%. Both the BEIR and the realized inflation are leptokurtic with a positive skewness (long right tail). The Jarque-Bera statistic indicates that the 3-month and 6-month BEIR and the IPCA appear to be normally distributed. This is a sign that the BEIR can better explain realized inflation over a short horizon than a long horizon. This sign will be confirmed in the empirical exercise presented in Section 4. The correlation coefficients between the BEIR and realized inflation (the bottom row of Table 1) are positive for the horizons of 3, 6 and 12 months and negative for the horizons of 18, 24, and 30 months. Figure 1 depicts the time evolution of the BEIR and the rate of change of the IPCA from April 2005 to April 2011. Note that the BEIR term structure is almost everywhere upward sloping. Moreover, the BEIR and IPCA exhibit no trend.12 12 We opt to calculate the descriptive statistics presented in Table 1 only with the data used in the estimation of Eq. (1). Thus, the number of observations decreases with the maturity of the BEIR. On the other hand, in Figure 1 we use the full sample.


4. EMPIRICAL RESULTS

In order to provide robust results, we estimate Eq. (1) using three different methods. First we adopt an OLS procedure. Next, we introduce instrumental variables to control for endogeneity. In this case, the model is estimated using TSLS and GMM with the variance-covariance matrix computed as suggested by Newey e West (1987). The instrument specification is it-1(τ) for TSLS and it-1(τ), it-2(τ) and it-3(τ) for GMM (τ =3, 6, 12, 18, 24, 30). Tables 2, 3 and 4 report the estimates of c1 and c2, the standard deviations, the corrected R2, and the F -statistic of the joint hypothesis c1 =1 and c2 =0 for the OLS, TSLS and GMM methods, respectively.13 13 To check the consistency of OLS estimators, we perform the Durbin-Wu-Hausman test (see Ruud, 1984). We find no significant difference among OLS, TSLS and GMM. Nevertheless, we opt to report the TSLS and GMM estimations in order to provide robust results.

Note first that the estimates are very similar across the different estimation strategies, which indicates that our results are robust. The slope ctsub is significant for the horizons of 3, 6, 24 and 30 months.14 14 Apart from the estimate of c 1 for the 24-, 30-month horizons calculated by GMM. Hence, in the short and long term, the BEIR contains some information about future inflation. However, moving from the short to the long horizon, we can easily observe a distinct link between the BEIR and future inflation. For the horizons of 3 and 6 months, the F -statistic of the joint hypothesis c1 =1 and c2 =0 shows that the BEIR is an unbiased estimator of future inflation. In other words, we cannot reject the BEIR version of the expectation hypothesis.15 15 The BEIR version of the expectation hypothesis states that the inflation risk premium is constant over time. On the other hand, for the horizons of 24 and 30 months, the relationship between the BEIR and future inflation is negative.

For medium horizons, the coefficient c1 is not significant and R2 is very low. Moreover, the F statistic rejects the joint hypothesis c1 =1 and c2 =0. This means that the BEIR does not have information about the 12-and 18-month ahead inflation. We have difficulties to interpret the constant c2 as an inflation risk premium when c1 is statistically different from 1. Nevertheless, since c2 is significant, ranging between 400 to 700 basis points for medium and long horizons, we can conjecture that investors require a high reward to hold inflation-linked bonds with maturities greater than one year.

In a nutshell, apart from the short horizon, we present evidence that the BEIR fails to correctly predict subsequent movements in inflation. Although the aim of this work is not to examine the causes of this failure, we can imagine some reasons. First, we have only five years of data. Despite the fact our sample size is compatible with that found in other empirical finance studies of emerging economies (see, for instance, Pan e Singleton, 2008, Almeida e Vicente, 2009), we believe that a larger dataset would provide more accurate results. Second, the Brazilian market can actually be risky, which would imply a high risk premium, explaining the weak relationship between the BEIR and future inflation. Third, the BEIR can be affected by a "clientele effect", which means that the NTN-B may attract investors with preferences for specific maturities and strong aversion to inflation uncertainty.17 17 The clientele effect is modeled within the preferred-habitat theory. Although this theory was proposed more than a half century ago, there are few academic works dealing with it. Nevertheless, Vayanos e Vila (2009) recently revisited the preferred-habitat theory through the lens of no-arbitrage models. Moreover, Garbade e Rutherford (2007) and Greenwood e Vayanos (2010) discuss episodes supporting the preferred-habitat view. The clientele effect would thus cause a distortion in the inflation expectation extracted from inflation-index bonds. In Brazil, the typical buyers of inflation-index bonds are pension funds, for the purpose of hedging their inflation-linked liabilities. In July 2010, pension funds held 33% of NTN-B outstanding and only 5% of LTN and NTN-F outstanding.

5. CONCLUSION

We proposed a model free procedure to assess the relationship between the break-even and future inflations. We showed that the break-even inflation is informative about future inflation over horizons of 3, 6, 24 and 30 months. For the 3-and 6-month horizons, besides being informative, break-even inflation is an unbiased estimator as well. However, over the horizons of 24 and 30 months, the relationship between the break-even and future inflations is negative. On the other hand, for the horizons of 12 and 18 months, break-even inflation has almost no power to explain future inflation. These results indicate that policymakers and market participants should be very careful in using break-even inflation as a proxy for future movements in price indexes.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

  • Almeida, C. & Vicente, J. (2009). Identifying volatility risk premia from fixed income Asian options. Journal of Banking & Finance, 33:652-661.
  • Ang, A., Bekaert, G., & Wei, M. (2008). The term structure of real rates and expected inflation. Journal of Finance, 63:797-849.
  • Bernanke, B. (2004). What policymakers can learn from asset prices. In Speech Before the Investment Analyst Society of Chicago April 15, available at http://www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/speeches/2004/20040415/default.htm
  • Campbell, J. & Shiller, R. (1991). Yield spreads and interest rate movements: A bird's eye view. Review of Economic Studies, 58:495-514.
  • Christensen, B. J. & Prabhala, N. R. (1998). The relation between implied and realized volatility. Journal of Financial Economics, 50:125-150.
  • D'Amico, S., Kim, D., & Wei, M. (2008). Tips from TIPS: The informational content of Treasury inflation protected security prices. Working Papers 248, BIS.
  • Evans, M. D. (1998). Real rates, expected inflation, and inflation risk premia. Journal of Finance, 53:187-218.
  • Garbade, K. & Rutherford, M. (2007). Buybacks in Treasury cash and debt management. Staff Report 304, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
  • García, J. & Werner, T. (2010). Inflation risks and inflation risk premia. Working Paper 1162, European Central Bank.
  • Greenwood, R. & Vayanos, D. (2010). Price pressure in the bond market. American Economic Review, P&P, 100:585-590.
  • Grishchenko, O. & Huang, J. (2010). Inflation risk premium: Evidence from the TIPS market. Working paper, Penn State. Available at http://www.personal.psu.edu/ovg1/
  • Hördahl, P. (2008). The inflation risk premium in the term structure of interest rates. BIS Quarterly Review, pages 23-38.
  • Joyce, M., Lildholdt, P., & Sorensen, S. (2010). Extracting inflation expectations and inflation risk premia from the term structure: A joint model of the UK nominal and real yield curves. Journal of Banking & Finance, 34:281-294.
  • Newey, W. K. & West, K. D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica, 55:703-708.
  • Pan, J. & Singleton, K. (2008). Default and recovery implicit in the term structure of sovereign CDS spreads. Journal of Finance, 63:2345-2384.
  • Ruud, P. A. (1984). Tests of specification in econometrics. Econometric Reviews, 3:211-242.
  • Svensson, L. (1994). Monetary policy with flexible exchange rates and forward interest rates as indicators. Technical report, Institute for International Economic Studies, Stockholm University.
  • Vayanos, D. & Vila, J. (2009). A preference-habitat model of term structure of interest rates. Working Paper 15487, NBER. Available at http://www.nber.org/papers/w15487.pdf
  • 16
    16 These results are consistent with correlation coefficients shown in Table 1. Though peculiar, this finding simply suggests that the expectation hypothesis fails over long horizons. Therefore, the linear relation of Eq. (1) probably cannot accommodate the link between the BEIR and future inflation. A more general specification is necessary in this case. The assumption of constant risk premium can be relaxed, implying a time-varying inflation risk premium for long horizons. This result is consistent with previous empirical evidence. For example, Grishchenko e Huang (2010) document that although the U.S. 10-year inflation risk premium is around zero on average, it is time-varying.
  • *
    The first author thanks CNPq-Brazil for financial support. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Central Bank of Brazil.
  • 1
    TSLS and GMM stand for Two-Step Least Squares and Generalized Method of Moments, respectively.
  • 2
    The TIPS indexation lag is three months. Grishchenko e Huang (2010) point out that ignoring the indexation lag results in an underestimate of the inflation risk premium.
  • 3
    In fact, we should write
    and
    . However, we omit the superscript τ for brevity.
  • 4
    We do not know of any study that evaluates the inflation convexity with Brazilian data. However, as shown by Joyce et alii (2010), the Jensen correction is given by
    V
    art(
    ht(τ)). Assuming that the monthly inflation rate is i.i.d., we have Convexity =
    . From
    Table (1) we conclude that the Brazilin inflation convexity is around 4 b.p., which is very small when compared with the level of Brazilian rates (nominal or real).
  • 5
    The simplification given by Eq. (3) allows some nice interpretations and facilitates computation of the inflation risk premium. However, regarding our results, it does not matter since as stated above our main aim is to assess the connection between inflation expectation and BEIR. Possible failures in this respect are not addressed here.
  • 6
    ANBIMA is an association of Brazilian financial service providers. For more information about ANBIMA, see the website
  • 7
    The Brazilian Real/US Dollar exchange rate was around 1.65 in April 2011.
  • 8
    For more information about IPCA, see the website of Brazil's statistical bureau (IBGE),
  • 9
    Evans (1998) warns that the presence of a reporting lag in the price index can make index-linked bond yields imperfect measures of real yields. The IPCA is available with a maximum delay of 15 days. On average it is released in 7 days. IBGE also produces an advance version of the IPCA (IPCA-15), which contributes to a better forecast of the index price and consequently allows obtaining more accurate estimates of the real term structure.
  • 10
    For comparison purposes, the TIPS market has US$ 600 billion outstanding.
  • 11
    These data are for April 2011. For more information about the Brazilian Treasury bond market, see the website of the Central Bank of Brazil,
  • 12
    We opt to calculate the descriptive statistics presented in
    Table 1 only with the data used in the estimation of Eq. (1). Thus, the number of observations decreases with the maturity of the BEIR. On the other hand, in
    Figure 1 we use the full sample.
  • 13
    To check the consistency of OLS estimators, we perform the Durbin-Wu-Hausman test (see Ruud, 1984). We find no significant difference among OLS, TSLS and GMM. Nevertheless, we opt to report the TSLS and GMM estimations in order to provide robust results.
  • 14
    Apart from the estimate of
    c
    1 for the 24-, 30-month horizons calculated by GMM.
  • 15
    The BEIR version of the expectation hypothesis states that the inflation risk premium is constant over time.
  • 16
    These results are consistent with correlation coefficients shown in
  • 17
    The clientele effect is modeled within the preferred-habitat theory. Although this theory was proposed more than a half century ago, there are few academic works dealing with it. Nevertheless, Vayanos e Vila (2009) recently revisited the preferred-habitat theory through the lens of no-arbitrage models. Moreover, Garbade e Rutherford (2007) and Greenwood e Vayanos (2010) discuss episodes supporting the preferred-habitat view.
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      09 Aug 2013
    • Date of issue
      June 2013
    Fundação Getúlio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 11º andar, 22253-900 Rio de Janeiro RJ Brazil, Tel.: +55 21 3799-5831 , Fax: +55 21 2553-8821 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
    E-mail: rbe@fgv.br