Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Grants and Marginal Cost of Public Funding: Empirical Evidence for Local Governments in Brazil

Abstract

This paper documents empirical evidence on price-effect caused by lumpsum grants for local governments in Brazil between 2006 to 2010. Dahlby (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
demonstrates theoretically that lump-sum grants can reduce the cost of public goods provision (price-effect), in addition to the traditional income effect. Our contributions are threefold. First we estimated semielasticity of the effects of tax rate changes on tax base (−0.016). Second, we calculate the MCF of the local tax imposed on the supply of services (ISS) for Brazilian municipalities (average of 0.04). Finally, we estimate the priceeffect estimation for ISS tax. Our results suggests that for the entire sample, that an increase in R$ 1.00 in per capita unconditional transfers reduces the local price effect (MCF) around 0.07%, but this result is not consistently estimated across all subsamples.

Keywords
Price effect; income effect; transfers; taxes; fiscal federalism

Resumo

Este documento documenta evidências empíricas sobre o efeito-preço causado por subsídios de montante fixo para governos locais no Brasil entre 2006 e 2010. Dahlby (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
demonstra teoricamente que subsídios de quantia fixa podem reduzir o custo da provisão de bens públicos (efeitopreço), além do tradicional efeito renda. Nossas contribuições são triplas. Primeiro, estimamos a semi-elasticidade dos efeitos das alterações nas alíquotas de impostos na base de cálculo (0,016). Segundo, calculamos o MCF do imposto local imposto sobre a prestação de serviços (ISS) para os municípios brasileiros (média de 0,04). Finalmente, estimamos a estimativa de preço-efeito para o imposto ISS. Nossos resultados sugerem que, para toda a amostra, um aumento de R$ 1,00 nas transferências incondicionais per capita reduz o efeito de preço local (MCF) em torno de 0,07%, mas esse resultado não é consistentemente estimado em todas as subamostras.

1. Introduction

An important topic in the Public Finance literature is the discussion about the cost of raising additional resources from private sector to fund public provision. As discussed in the tax burden literature, in a true non-distortionary tax system, tax revenue is distributed directly from the private to the public sector, in such a manner that the income loss for the private sector is equivalent to the income earning for the public sector (Hakonsen, 1998Hakonsen, L. (1998). An investigation into alternative representations of the marginal cost of public funds. International Tax and Public Finance, 5(3), 329-343. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1008686227749
http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:100868622774...
). In this scenario, the marginal dead weight loss from taxation is null.

In a different formulation, Dahlby (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
, following Hamilton (1986)Hamilton, J. H. (1986). The flypaper effect and the deadweight loss from taxation. Journal of Urban Economics, 19(2), 148-155. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(86)90036-7
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(86)9...
, approaches tax burden in a model in which local governments are financed by distortive taxes. Under this scenario, the marginal loss caused to society by a tax rate increase is captured by the idea of marginal cost of public fund (MCF). The MCF can be stated as the ratio between the social marginal value of a monetary unit (i.e. $1 Real) raised by the government and its counterpart in the private sector (the social marginal value of a monetary unit in the private sector). According to Jacobs (2018)Jacobs, B. (2018). The marginal cost of public funds is one at the optimal tax system. International Tax and Public Finance, 25(4), 883-912. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-017-9481-0
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-017-948...
, the MCF is a measure of the scarcity of the public resouces in society.

In fact, the MCF aims to measure the distortion in the allocation of resources in an economy resulting from a response to a non lump-sum tax, such as the labor supply, consumption, and investment decisions. Beyond tax distortion, additional resources from intergovernamental grants can also affect the cost of public funds. In the Dahlby’s (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
model, lump-sum intergovernmental grants have both an income effect, which is widely reported in the “flypaper” literature (Gramlich, 1977Gramlich, E. (1977). Intergovernmental grants: A review of the empirical literature. In W.E. Oates (Ed.), The political economy of fiscal federalism. Lexington Press.; Fisher, 1982Fisher, R. C. (1982). Income and grants effects on local expenditure: The flypaper effect and other difficulties. Journal of Public Economics, 17(3), 324-345. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(82)90021-3
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(82)9...
; Wyckoff, 1991Wyckoff, P. G. (1991). The elusive flypaper effect. Journal of Urban Economics, 30(3), 293-305. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(91)90052-9
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(91)9...
; Inman, 2008Inman, R. P. (2008, December). The flypaper effect (Working Paper No. 14579). National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w14579
http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w14579...
), and a price effect. The mechanism that such price-effect works is via a decrease in the marginal cost of public fund.

This price effect refers to the situation in which additional resources from intergovernamental grants can impact negatively the local cost of public provision, as it allows the local government to decrease the tax rate and still to maintain the same level of public goods. Following this debate, the main objective of this paper is to estimate the price-effect in lump-sum grants using data from 5,173 Brazilian municipalities between 2006 and 2012 (seven years sample). In this article we (i) estimate the effects of tax rate changes on tax base (number of fims); (ii) calculate the MCF of the local business tax imposed on the supply of services for Brazilian municipalities; and (iii) estimate the effect of grants on the estimated MCF.

The fiscal federalism literature has provided considerable attention to the intergovernmental grants schemes, which are important tools for correcting fiscal imbalances caused by disequilibrium of taxation sources between government levels and by differences in local fiscal need.

Lump-sum grants seem to stimulate more the local public spending than increases in local private income, reinforcing the expression “money sticks where it hits”. The idea is that the revenues raised by the public sector remains in that sector. Hines and Thaler (1995)Hines, J. R., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). The flypaper effect. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 217-226. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.9A217
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.9A217...
charactherize as an anomaly the larger propensity of grants to increase public spending compared to private income resources and there seems to have many theoretical explanations for that.1 1 For a detailed survey, see Inman (2008) and Gamkhar and Shah (2007). For Brazil, Siqueira, Nogueira, Souza, and Carvalho (2010) found 0.002 to 2.2 using 27 groups of goods. Lanzer and Porto (2011) estimated the MCF forthe whole Brazilian tax system in between 1.167 and 1.173. See also Cossio (2002) and Cossio and Carvalho (2001). More related to our work, Hamilton (1986)Hamilton, J. H. (1986). The flypaper effect and the deadweight loss from taxation. Journal of Urban Economics, 19(2), 148-155. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(86)90036-7
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(86)9...
claims that the flypaper effect might be due to tax distortion, which is captured by the deadweight loss of taxation (Hakonsen, 1998)Hakonsen, L. (1998). An investigation into alternative representations of the marginal cost of public funds. International Tax and Public Finance, 5(3), 329-343. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1008686227749
http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:100868622774...
, as also by the difference between income and grants effects.

This issue is further explored in Dahlby (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
that argues that grants can reduce the cost of taxation for local governments through a change in the MCF. In particular, the author shows that lump-sum grants allow the recipient government to reduce its tax rate, which in turn, decreases the MCF in order to keep the same level of public service. Whether local MCFs are larger than national average counterpart, additional resources from grants could increase consumer welfare. According to Browning (1987)Browning, E. K. (1987). On the marginal welfare cost of taxation. The American Economic Review, 77(1), 11-23. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1806725
https://www.jstor.org/stable/1806725...
tax-response can produce very disperse estimates (1% increase of a particular tax can trigger a marginal loss in well-being between 9.9 and 300%).2 2 Recently Auriol and Warlters (2012) estimated a mean MCF of 1.21 for 38 African countries using a general equilibrium model, finding that taxes on production factors have higher MCFs than do taxes on imports and domestic goods.

As discussed in Dahlby (2011, p.309)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
, Brazil offers a interesting case to discuss the flypaper effect as also the cost of public fund as the Brazilian system of intergovernmental grants is broad; it accounts for 12% of gross domestic product (GDP) and it corresponds about 70% of local revenue streams in 2008. Thus, it is relevant to use Brazilian data in order to provide empirical evidence of the price-effect of transfers.

Overall, our main results indicate that the tax base (number of firms) reacts negatively to a local tax rate increase. Moreover, we find limited evidence that grants pushes down the marginal cost of public fund. Interestingly, our results suggest that this price effect seems greater for larger cities. We argue that this finding is associated to greater distortionary taxation found in larger municipalities. Considering the entire sample, our estimates suggests that an increase in R$ 1.00 in per capita unconditional transfers reduces the local price effect (MCF) around 0.00003 (0.07% of the average MCF).

In addition to this introduction, this paper is organized in four sections. Section 2 presents a modified version of Dahlby’s (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
model that allows to compare the price effect of grants to the price effect of income. Additionally, section 3 describes the empirical approach and the data used. Section 4 discusses our main findings. Finally, section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Theoretical background

2.1 Marginal Cost od Public Finance (MCF) Model

In this section, in order to develop an empirical approach to obtain the price effect of unconditional grants, we explore Dahlby’s (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
model of Marginal Cost ofPublic Funds (MCF). First, we assume that all local governments have a homogeneous, fixed population that may be represented by a single agent. The local government is in charge of choosing a tax rate 𝜏 that affects the tax base, B, and the amount of public services provided, g, at a constant production cost per capita c. The local government receives a lump-sum transfer T. Therefore, the government’s budget constraint follows 𝜏B + T = cg.

The utility of the representative resident is U = u(𝑥, B) + 𝑤(g), where 𝑥 is the private consumption of goods (price equal to 1), u(⋅) is a quasi-concave function, 𝑤' > 0, and 𝑤" < 0. In our case, the tax base (B) depends only on the local tax rate, 𝜏. Thus, it follows B = B(𝜏). Dahlby (2011Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
, equation (1), p.307) derives MCF as

(1) MCF τ i = B i dR d τ i = B i B i + τ i dB i d τ i = 1 1 + τ i η ,

where η=lnBτ<0 is the elasticity of the tax base with respect to the tax rate and R stands for local tax revenue. Because of tax avoidance by firms, it is expected a negative association (elasticity) between the tax base and the tax rate, captured by the term 𝜂. Equation (1) indicates that the MCF is a measurement that reflects the cost of a tax rate increase in terms of tax revenue, or equivalently, how much it costs to obtain an additional R$ 1 in terms of tax revenue. For example, if the tax base is not affected by the increase in tax rate (i.e., 𝜂 = 0), then an increase in the tax rate reflects the same measurement in tax revenue. However, it is expected that the tax base shrinks with a tax rate increase (as we expect that 𝜂 < 0), which leads to MCF greater than one (MCF > 1).3 3 Furthermore, the municipalities are assumed to be in the increasing segment ofthe Laffer Curve, i.e., 1 + Ttq > 0. It can be shown that MCF is increasing with respect to tax rate under some conditions.

Assuming that local government intends to maximize the well-being of the residents, the provision of public goods goes up to the point at which the marginal benefit of public goods equals the effective price, P; e.g., P ≡ MCF ■ c, where c is the constant cost of provision of the public good per capita. If this government receives a lump-sum grants, T from the central government, the provision of public goods could increase and the tax rate might decrease. Then, the MCF decreases because tax rate has decreased, which in turn, allows for a reduction in the effective price of providing the public good. Deriving the effective price in relation to T and keeping g constant (τiT=B1MCF), the effect of an increase in grants to the relative price effect to may be expressed as

(2) P T = P τ τ T = c η 1 + τ η 3 1 + E B ,

where E=dηidτiτiηi, which corresponds to the change of the elasticity of the tax base in relation to the tax rate. If the local government is financed with lump-sum taxes we have MCF = 1. If E = -1, then there would be no price effect for lump-sum grants. Supposing that MCF > 1 and E > -1, a lump-sum grant presents a greater price effect compared to the ratio between the lump-sum grant over the local tax revenue, as well as that of the local MCF.

To find the expression that reflects the relationship between those two forms of variation in the price-effect (grants and income), we first have to completely differentiate the budget constraint, while keeping g constant, then one has to derive P with respect to Y and to 𝜏. After some algebra, one can find the price effect of income as indicated in function

(3) P Y = c η 1 + τ η 3 1 + E B B y τ .

Function (3) represents the change in the price of the public good resulting from the variation in income.4 4 For example, if we consider c = 1, E = 0 (i.e., there is no variation in the elasticity of the tax base), B = 100, and t = 1.01 (tax rate of 1%), one has a price effect resulting from the grants that is equal to -0.00017 and a price effect of income equal to -0.0000002, less (in magnitude) because the price effect of income is multiplied by the variation in the tax base in relation to income (0.001). Comparing the price-effects of income (3) to its counterpart of the grants’ function (2), we have:

(4) P T = c η 1 + τ η 3 1 E B = P Y 1 τ B y .

Equation (4) shows that if 1 > 𝜏By > 0, one has Pτ>PY. This means that intergovernmental grants have a greater ability compared income to decrease the effective price of the public good. Thus, we should expect a negative relantionship between grants and MCF. To summarize, in our empirical approach, we investigate two main hyphothesis derived from our analytical framework: i) if the the association between tax rate and tax base is negative or not; ii) if the effect of grants in MCF is also negative and its magnitude. Next, we related the MCF model with Brazilian institutional framework.

2.2 Local tax revenues and unconditional transfers in Brazil

Regarding local tax revenues, the tax on business services (ISS) is the main source of public funding. This tax is collect over services acivities (excluding any type of manufactured activity) as small retail stores, hairdressers, repair services, restaurants, financial and educational services. The statutory business tax rate ranges from 2% to 5%.5 5 It follows Lei Complementar 116/2003 and Emenda Constitucional 37/2002. Some sectors are tax exempt. Additionally, municipalities also obtain resources from local property tax (IPTU, in Portuguese). However, statutory tax rate in property tax in Brazil are historically low. In fact, average tax rate is less than 2% and most households live in areas or houses that are tax free.6 6 See Carvalho (2006) for a comprehensive discussion in Portuguese. According to Carvalho (2006)Carvalho, P. H. B. d., Jr. (2006, December). IPTU no Brasil: Progressividade, arrecadação e aspectos extra-fiscais (Texto para Discussão No. 1251). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada (IPEA). http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=4814
http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/index.php?...
, only 30% of the households collect property tax and property tax revenues represents only approximatelly 0.5% from Gross Domestic Product (GDP). In our sample, the local business tax revenues represent on average twice the revenue collected in local property tax. Thus, it is appropriate to consider the business tax as the main source of local tax revenue and source of potential distortionary taxation.

Regarding intergovernamental grants, municipalities obtain resources from States and from the Federation. Each State return approximatelly from 20% to 25% of the Valeu Added Tax (VAT) and of the Vehicle Tax revenue to the locality where the tax was collected.7 7 There are two other additional types of intergovernmental transfers: Federal Support for Education Fund (FUNDEB, in Portuguese), and Federal Support for Health System (SUS, in Portuguese). Together, those grants account for on average approximatelly 10% of municipalities revenue resources. However, as opposed to FPM grants, they are denominated matching grant transfers as they produce different allocative effects because they impose a counterpart spending for local governments. Because of that, we do not include those grants in our analysis. However, it is noteworthy to clarify that the main source of revenues for local governments in Brazil are unconditional grants. Table 1 shows that meanwhile intergovernmental grants from the Municipalities Participation Fund (FPM, in Portuguese) accounts for on average 60% of total revenue resources, local tax revenue corresponds on average to only 20% of fiscal resources for municipal jurisdictions. Because of this large share in municipalities’ budgets, it is important to comprehend the effect of unconditional grants on the MCF.

Table 1
Fiscal variables by populational ranges - per capita in 2010 R$.

Finally, it is important to remind that very small firms in Brazil collect tax in a differentiated regime. In the “Simples Nacional” tax regime, firms collect local, State and National tax in a unified way.8 8 It follows Lei Complementar number 123/06 and Lei Complementar 155 (2016). For example, in year 2010 firms were shared in 20 different groups according their total revenue. Statutory tax rate varied from 4.5% to 16.85%. The implication of this tax regime for this paper is that is that a share of the business tax revenue, mostly in small cities, is collect in this special tax regime. On average, around 33% of the tax collect in the “Simples” regime was redistributed to municipalities as local business tax. In our methodological approach, we try to circumvent this issue including a variable to control for fiscal capacity (see section 3.3). It is important to note that the “Simples” has reached more economic activities and firms after 2014 (as a consequence of Lei Complementar 147/2014), and because of that our sample should be less affected by this tax regime.

An important characteristic of FPM transfers is that it follows exogenous criteria based on populations cutoffs. Excluding the 27 State capitals and some large cities, municipalities which follows different distributive rules (based on both population and income inverse rules), municipalities with less than 142 thousands inhabitants receive FPM different amounts based only on populational ranges. Those ranges are on Table A-1 in Appendix Appendix. Table A-1 Population cutoffs for FPM (transfers) distribution. Population Range Factor Up to 10,188 0.6 From 10,189 to 13,584 0.8 From 13,585 to 16,980 1.0 From 16,981 to 23,772 1.2 From 23,773 to 30,564 1.4 From 30,565 to 37,356 1.6 From 37,357 to 44,148 1.8 From 44,149 to 50,940 2.0 From 50,941 to 61,128 2.2 From 61,129 to 71,316 2.4 From 71,317 to 81,504 2.6 From 81,505 to 91,692 2.8 From 91,693 to 101,880 3.0 From 101,881 to 115,464 3.2 From 115,465 to 129,048 3.4 From 129,049 to 142,632 3.6 From 142,633 to 156,216 3.8 > 156,216 4.0 Note: Law by Decree nº 1.881/1981. Table A-2 Regression on tax base elasticity (without tax capacity covariate). Dependent variable: Ln of number of firms. Bandwidth size 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 3,000 4,000 Total Cut-off 1 -0.140 *** -0.094 ** -0.050 (-3.129) (-2.453) (-1.430) Number of cases 1,355 2,687 3,904 Cut-off 2 -0.023 -0.009 -0.013 (-1.114) (-0.507) (-0.640) Number of cases 2,003 2,947 3,914 Cut-off 3 0.177 *** 0.111 -0.041 (3.253) (0.993) (-0.934) Number of cases 2,214 2,476 4,298 Cut-off 4 -0.249 -0.004 0.191 (-1.182) (-0.021) (0.957) Number of cases 1,769 2,596 3,520 Cut-off 5 -0.629 ** -0.570 ** -0.476 ** (-2.357) (-2.467) (-2.437) Number of cases 997 1,519 2,023 Total -0.016 ** (-2.463) Number of cases 37,708 Notes: All regressions include fixed effect and time effects. In parentheses are robust t statics *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Table A-3 First Stage (IV) regression results. Population cutoffs (binary variables) dfxpop1 -0.446 *** (-19.360) dfxpop2 -0.310 *** (-15.240) dfxpop3 -0.211 *** (-11.530) dfxpop4 -0.147 *** (-9.220) dfxpop5 -0.102 *** (-7.590) dfxpop6 -0.064 *** (-6.300) dfxpop7 -0.029 *** (-4.100) dfxpop9 0.020 ** (2.040) dfxpop10 0.007 (0.820) dfxpop12 0.008 (0.710) dfxpop14 -0.010 (-0.440) dfxpop16 -0.006 (-0.360) Notes: All regressions include fixed effect and time effects. In parentheses are t statistics. Number of obs is 36,211. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Figure A-1 Firms’ Size (number of Employees). . What makes this interesting for our methodological approach is that it allow us to explore this legal framework in a regression discontinuity design9 9 We should note that this fact has being previously explored by and Brollo and Nannicini (2012) in a regression discontinuity design (RDD). as discussed in further detail in the next section.

3. Methodology

3.1 Empirical strategy

As discussed by Dahlby (2008)Dahlby, B. (2008). The marginal cost of public funds: Theory and applications. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press., there are several methodologies to calculate the MCF. The method we follow consists of estimating the sensitivity of the tax base in relation to the tax rate as in equation (1).10 10 There is a large literature on the determination of the response of the tax base in relation to a tax variation. Gruber and Saez (2002) perform this estimation for the USA, and Mintz and Smart (2004) do so for Canada. Dahlby (2008) provides a good review of the topic and also shows results in the context of fiscal federalism. Thus, the parameter of interest is the sensivity of the tax base to tax rates as depicted in function (5):

(5) log B i , t = α i + η τ it + π X it + dtime t + municipalities + ξ i ,

where Bit is the tax base of municipality i at time t; 𝜏 corresponds to the tax rate; 𝜉 is a vector of control variables; and dtime are time dummies. Therefore, the coefficient of the tax rate in this regression is the semi-elasticity of the tax base in relation to the tax rate (𝜂). From our analytical discussion in section 2, we expect a negative coefficient for 𝜂 as a tax rate increase should present a negative effect on tax base.

The next step is to identify whether the increase in grants and income acts to reduce the municipal MCF according to the equation below:

(6) MCF it = α i + β grants it + γ Y it + ρ X it + dtime t + municipalities + u it ,

where MCFit corresponds to MCF of municipality i at time T; grantsit is the transfers received by the municipalities; Y captures exogenous income; and X includes the same vector of control variables used in equation (5). Regarding our empirical approach, since we have obtained the MCF from equation (5) we should calculate standard errors using bootstrapping technique.

According to public finance literature, we should expect that municipalities decisions over local tax rate (tax revenue) and revenues on intergovernamentals grants are jointly determined which might bias the estiation of equation (6). For this reason, Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression would produce inconsistent and biased coefficient estimates. In order to obtain valid estimates of MCF, we explore the fact that the FPM grants follow populationonal ranges and build binary variables based on FPM populational cutoffs. Thus, to estimate the effect of the grants on the municipalities’s MCF, we use a regression discontinuity design approach.

3.2 FPM thresholds

The most important transfer to Brazilian Municipalities is called the Municipalities’ Participation Fund (Fundo de Participação dos Municípios, FPM). It is a mandatory, unconditional, nonmatching, revenue-sharing grant. According to Law nº 5.172/1966, out of the total amount of FPM transfers, 10% belongs to the capitals, 86.4% belongs to the municipal ities of the countryside, and the remaining 3.6% constitutes the Reserve Fund, which is distributed among countryside municipalities with more than 142,633 inhabitants (Decree Law nº 1.881/1981 and Complementary Law nº 91/1997, art. 3).

Because the amount that must be allocated to each municipality is clearly established, FPM transfers are transparent and can be separated from political pressure. Furthermore, local governments have autonomy in spending those transfers.11 11 Although Litschig and Morrison (2013) shows that the population measure could be manipulated by municipalities in the 1990s, such manipulation has not been observed since 2000, when the federal governments started to use census data and IBGE estimates for the population. See also Brollo, Nannicini, Perotti, and Tabellini (2013) and Ferraz and Finan (2011) for further evidence and discussion. On one hand, such autonomy is desirable because the municipality can allocate the transferred resources according to local needs and preferences, which they are in a better position to understand. On the other hand, this autonomy can lead to diminished returns to scale in spending and less tax effort. The Brazilian Census measures the official number of inhabitants in any particular municipality every ten years, and Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatistica (IBGE) provides annual estimates of local populations between census years. The central government then uses these estimates to distribute FPM funds to municipalities. We explore the yearly fluctuation of local populations across thresholds to quantify the causal effects of government spending on economic activity.

One important aspect of government expenditures and budget resources is that they can be simultaneously determined (Dahlberg, Mork, Rattsø, & Ågren, 2008Dahlberg, M., Mork, E., Rattsø, J., & Ågren, H. (2008). Using a discontinuous grant rule to identify the effect of grants on local taxes and spending. Journal of Public Economics, 92(12), 2320-2335. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.05.004
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007...
). To circumvent this issue, the empirical approach reconciles two exogenous aspects of categorical and block grants using a two-stage least squares (TSLS) method. Regarding block grants, the distribution rules based on the population threshold can used as IV in the first-stage regression.

More specifically, the method uses a regression discontinuity strategy in which each population cut-off is used to build a binary variable that denotes the unconditional transfer range. This allows us to build 17 variables to use as instruments in the first-stage regression, as follows: Di = 1 if Populationi > Cutoffr at each cutoff r and municipality i.

As discussed by Litschig and Morrison (2013)Litschig, S., & Morrison, K. M. (2013). The impact of intergovernmental transfers on education outcomes and poverty reduction. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(4), 206-240. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/app.5A206
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/app.5A206...
, there is no reason to believe that sorting around cut-offs (manipulations of the true size of the population, creation of new municipalities above the cut-offs or incentive effects to migrate) affects the identification strategy. Thus, TSLS estimations use selected cut-offs as excluded instruments to obtain consistent estimates of the causal effect of grants on per pupil spending (Van der Klaauw, 2002Van der Klaauw, W. (2002). Estimating the effect of financial aid offers on college enrollment: A regression-discontinuity approach. International Economic Review, 43(4), 1249-1287. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00055
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-2354.t01-...
).

Equation (7) provides the first-stage regression for a IV approach in which FPM grants are treated as an endogenous regressor. It uses the population dummies (17 population dummies Z) as valid instruments for the unconditional grant. All other variables are used as valid instruments for themselves:

(7) FPM it = α 0 + β 1 Z 1 + β 2 Z 2 + + β 17 Z 17 + ρ X it + dtime t + municipalities i + u it ,

where FPM is instrumented by the population dummies (Z); all other controls (X), time effects; municipalities, fixed effects; and uit is an error term clustered at the municipality level.

The causal effect that we are identifying is local for two reasons: first, the RDD identifies the effect only to observations around the thresholds; and second, the to compliers (that is, municipalities that received larger transfers because of the exogenous FPM revenue-sharing mechanism). However, the identification of compliers neglects a subpopulation that may also be of interest: the always-takers, or municipalities that receive larger transfers independently of their position above or below each population threshold.

Next we run this instrumented FPM on the computed MCF to identify the price effect and equation (6) would modify to:

MCF it = α 0 + δ 1 FPM ̂ 1 + + δ 17 FPM ̂ 17 + ρ X it + dtime t + municipalities i + v it

We should note that this formulation of the MCF relies on the following hypotheses: i) changes in ISS rates produce very small effect over IPTU tax revenues; ii) each municipality’s ISS tax burden is supported only by the its own; iii) there is no interaction between the tax bases-which makes sense for services in small municipalities; iv) the elasticity of the tax base may be the same in all of the local governments.

3.3 Data

Regarding local tax and revenue information, we note that annual data is available in a systematic way until year 2012 from Brazilian Treasury (Secretaria do Tesouro Nacional, STN). Data on number of service firms (which compound ISS tax base), and their number of employes and firms’s payroll total costs is available in the Brazilian Bureau of Geography and Statistics’ reports on Services Firms Census (Cadastro Central de Empresas) from 2006 to 2015.12 12 Availabe at https://sidra.ibge.gov.br/pesquisa/cempre/tabelas/brasil/2015 as in January 2018. Considering the time period availability of both datasets, our sample includes data for 5,173 (from a total of 5,565) municipalities in Brazil from year 2006 to 2012 (seven years period). We also collect data on demographic variables as described Table 2.13 13 Datasus data is available at http://www2.datasus.gov.br/DATASUS/index.php?area=0206 and HDI at http://www.firjan.com.br/ifdm/ We note that all monetary variables are deflated to year 2010 in Brazilian currency (R$ Reais) values.

Table 2
Descriptive statistics of observable variables from municipalities - from 2006 to 2012, in R$, year 2010.

As previously debated by several authors (see Hakonsen (1998)Hakonsen, L. (1998). An investigation into alternative representations of the marginal cost of public funds. International Tax and Public Finance, 5(3), 329-343. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1008686227749
http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:100868622774...
for a discussion), one of the main limitations of the applied literature is to identify a feasible measure of tax base for local tax to properly approach the marginal cost of public funds. One reasonable measure of firms tax burden would be the local business tax (ISS). However, there is not systematic data available for ISS tax rates across municipalities. Differently, we have information available about the payroll expenses (firms expenses with employee earnings) by municipality. Based on this information, we build a measure of effective average tax rate (AETR) as suggested by Hayashi and Boadway (2001)Hayashi, M., & Boadway, R. (2001). An empirical analysis of intergovernmental tax interaction: The case of business income taxes in Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics, 34(2), 481-503. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0008-4085.00085
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0008-4085.0008...
. Thus, instead of using statutory tax rates, our measure of AETR follows the ratio between ISS tax revenues and annual payroll of firms services under the municipalities in the analysis. The idea is that in the service sector, firms’ revenue is strongly correlated to firms’ labor spending or to payroll spending. The main advantage of using a AETR approach is that it is less rigid than statutory tax rate and provides more variation in time and across units. Additionally, it should capture better the effect of tax rate changes on number of firms and firms revenues.

Finally, following previous work on tax competition literature, we include a covariate to control for fiscal capacity. We build a measure of relative fiscal capacity based on the amount each municipality obtains from Value Added Tax (ICMS,14 14 Imposto Sobre Circulação de Mercadorias e Serviços. in Portuguese). We explore the conception that fiscal capacity is positively associated to VAT collection at the municipal level (see also section 2). We normalize the revenues originated from this devolutive grant to obtain a national average of zero. The idea is that if a municipality present a VAT refund revenue above (below) the national average it should present a higher (lower) fiscal capacity compared to their counterparts. This covariate should account for local fiscal capacity as also should minimize a potential measurement error in AETR in smaller cities, originated from the “Simples Nacional” tax regime. It should also account for informality in the municiplaities. Next Section brings our main findings.

4. Result

4.1 Tax base

We first estimate the tax base elasticity as described in equation (5). We consider as measure of tax base the natural logarithm of the number of firms in the service sector. As discussed in section 2, it is expected a negative correlation between the average effective tax rate (AETR) and the tax base (𝜂 < 0). Table 3 brings the results for the RDD approach for 5 cutoffs with three different bandwhidth ranges and for the total of observations in our sample. We note that after the 5th cutoff the number of cases around the cutoff is small. RDD approach would be possible only with very large bandwidths. All regressions include demographic variables (population, squared population, population density, share of younger and share of elderly, and a binary variable indicating if the municipality is in a metropolitan region or not) as covariates.

Table 3
Regression on tax base elasticity. Dependent variable: Ln of number of firms.

Overall, as expected, results on Table 3 shows that a tax rate increase has a negative effect on the number of firms in the municipalties. In column I, results in RDD on the first cutoff indicate that an one standard deviation increase in average tax rate reduces in 4.5% (0.2 × 0.225 × 100) the number of service firms. Interestingly, results in Table 3 suggests that the negative effect is neither homogenous nor linear around the different cutoffs. Estimated coefficients suggests that the results are negative and significant for the smaller (first cutoff) and larger (fifth cutoff) municipalities in our sample. Those cutoffs corresponds to municipalities with approximately 10 and 30 thousand inhabitants, respectively. Differently, coefficients in cutoff 3 and 4 suggest (municipalities with approximately 16 and 23 thousand inhabitants, respectively) that a tax rate increase present a positive on the number of firms in those jurisdictions (although this positive effect is significant only in one out of fifteen regression).

This trend is depicted in Figure 1 which brings the scatter plot between tax rate and the logarithm of the number of firms for three different bandwidth ranges for the five cutoffs as in Table 3. If someone depicts a linear trend line, she will note that the effect on tax base is negative as expected. Contrastingly, if someone depicts a polynomial trend line, she will obtain an inverted U shape relationship. Importantly, results suggest that, after the 2nd cutoff, the negative tax rate effect on tax base increases as municiplaities gets larger. One possible explanation for those findings is that the most populated municipalities presents the largest firms which are more affected by a tax rate increase. On the other hand, as developed by Carbonnier (2008)Carbonnier, C. (2008, February). Fiscal competition between decentralized jurisdictions, theoreti cal and empirical evidence (Documents de travail No. 2008-17). Cergy-Pontoise: THEMA - Université de Cergy-Pontoise. http://thema.u-cergy.fr/IMG/documents/2008-17.pdf
http://thema.u-cergy.fr/IMG/documents/20...
, the effect of tax competition can be greater for smaller jurisdictions with less fixed factor, as land for example. The idea is that very small jurisdictions can be more affected by tax rate spill-over if the externality is driven by a fixed factor.

Figure 1
Tax Rate Effect on Tax Base.

It is important to note that very small firms in Brazil collect taxes in a diferentied mechanism, called “Simples Nacional” (see section 3 for a brief discussion). To verify if the results in smaller municipalities could be biased because of this tax regime, we include in all regresions a covariate to control for tax capacity. Interestingly, if someone compare the results of the RDD regression with and without this variable (Table 3 and Table A-2 in Appendix Appendix. Table A-1 Population cutoffs for FPM (transfers) distribution. Population Range Factor Up to 10,188 0.6 From 10,189 to 13,584 0.8 From 13,585 to 16,980 1.0 From 16,981 to 23,772 1.2 From 23,773 to 30,564 1.4 From 30,565 to 37,356 1.6 From 37,357 to 44,148 1.8 From 44,149 to 50,940 2.0 From 50,941 to 61,128 2.2 From 61,129 to 71,316 2.4 From 71,317 to 81,504 2.6 From 81,505 to 91,692 2.8 From 91,693 to 101,880 3.0 From 101,881 to 115,464 3.2 From 115,465 to 129,048 3.4 From 129,049 to 142,632 3.6 From 142,633 to 156,216 3.8 > 156,216 4.0 Note: Law by Decree nº 1.881/1981. Table A-2 Regression on tax base elasticity (without tax capacity covariate). Dependent variable: Ln of number of firms. Bandwidth size 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 3,000 4,000 Total Cut-off 1 -0.140 *** -0.094 ** -0.050 (-3.129) (-2.453) (-1.430) Number of cases 1,355 2,687 3,904 Cut-off 2 -0.023 -0.009 -0.013 (-1.114) (-0.507) (-0.640) Number of cases 2,003 2,947 3,914 Cut-off 3 0.177 *** 0.111 -0.041 (3.253) (0.993) (-0.934) Number of cases 2,214 2,476 4,298 Cut-off 4 -0.249 -0.004 0.191 (-1.182) (-0.021) (0.957) Number of cases 1,769 2,596 3,520 Cut-off 5 -0.629 ** -0.570 ** -0.476 ** (-2.357) (-2.467) (-2.437) Number of cases 997 1,519 2,023 Total -0.016 ** (-2.463) Number of cases 37,708 Notes: All regressions include fixed effect and time effects. In parentheses are robust t statics *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Table A-3 First Stage (IV) regression results. Population cutoffs (binary variables) dfxpop1 -0.446 *** (-19.360) dfxpop2 -0.310 *** (-15.240) dfxpop3 -0.211 *** (-11.530) dfxpop4 -0.147 *** (-9.220) dfxpop5 -0.102 *** (-7.590) dfxpop6 -0.064 *** (-6.300) dfxpop7 -0.029 *** (-4.100) dfxpop9 0.020 ** (2.040) dfxpop10 0.007 (0.820) dfxpop12 0.008 (0.710) dfxpop14 -0.010 (-0.440) dfxpop16 -0.006 (-0.360) Notes: All regressions include fixed effect and time effects. In parentheses are t statistics. Number of obs is 36,211. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Figure A-1 Firms’ Size (number of Employees). , respectivelly), she will note that the inclusion of this variable leads to similar coefficient in most regressions but to a greater coefficient in the first cutoff. This result suggests that our measure of tax rate could not capture all the effects of tax rate on tax base because of this differentiated tax regime. However, this limitation seems circumnscrit to the smallest municiplaities (1st cutoff) in our sample, since the estimated coefficient over the other cutoffs are similar with or without this covariate.

Finally, we also report results for a standard panel fixed effect model. We note that regression on our total sample (column VI) seems to reflect the relantionship between tax rate and number of firms in the smaller and greater municipalities, and the estimated coefficient on the tax rate indicates that one standard deviation increase in tax rate reduces 0.36% the number of firms in the municipality. It is important to remind that, as discussed in section 2, we use the estimated coefficient of tax rate on tax base to build our measure of Marginal Cost of Fund (MCF) as described in function (1). In the next section, we discuss the results over this dependent variable.

4.2 MCF's Price-effect

In this section we estimate the unconditional grants price effect on the MCF using our model described in section 2. We expect that FPM grants present a negative effect on the MCF since this should reduce the price of public provision as discussed in Dahlby (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
. Table 4 brings the results for our RDD approach around the same five cutoffs as in Table 3 and for two stage least squares instrumental variable (2SLS-IV) with bootstrapping standard errors (last column Table 4). We note that, as in Table 3, all regressions control for demographic variables as also for Human Development Index (HDI) indicator, and fixed and time effects.

Table 4
Regression on tax price effect. Dependent variable: Ln of number of firms. Dependent variable: Marginal Cost of Public Fund (MCF).

Overall, we find limited evidence of a negative effect of unconditional grants on MCF. Estimated coefficents on grants ranges from -0.007 to 0.002. In 9 out 15 RDD results, we find a negative coefficients for grants, but only one coefficient is significant at the 10% significance level (larger bandwidth in the 5th cut-off). As the MCF reflects the marginal loss in the economy due to the marginal increase in tax rate, for example, a negative coefficient in the

last column (total)15 15 Table A-3in Appendix brings the coefficents for the first stage regression and it shows that all binary variables are significant. They present negative signal which reflects the fact that the smaller the population the higher the FPM per capita received. in Table 4 indicates that each R$ 1 increase in unconditional grants is associated with a reduction in the cost of public fund about 0.003 (1% of its standard deviation).

To examine if the effect of grants on MCF presents some trend, we plot a graph with the five cutoff and the three different bandwidths. Interestingly, Figure 2 suggests that, although not very large, the negative effects of grants on MCF increases the larger is the municipality. This seems a counter-intuitive result, since small communities tend to present higher marginal cost of public fund and they should present a stronger reaction to additional grants resources (Buettner & Fabritz, 2011Buettner, T., & Fabritz, N. (2011, June 30). Responses to grants and the marginal cost of public funds. In IV Workshop on Fiscal Federalism, Barcelona.).

Figure 2
Grant Effect on MCF.

However, there two possible explanations for our results in Table 4. First, the negative effect of tax rate increase on tax base could be greater in larger cities (Buettner & Holm-Hadulla, 2008Buettner, T., & Holm-Hadulla, F. (2008, November). Cities in fiscal equalization (CESifo Working Paper No. 2447). Munich, Germany: CESifo Group. http://www.cesifo-group.de/ifoHome/publications/docbase/DocBase_Content/WP/WP-CESifo_Working_Papers/wp-cesifo-2008/wp-cesifo-2008-11/12012008002447.html
http://www.cesifo-group.de/ifoHome/publi...
), as we have previously observed in the results in Table 3. Second, grants effects on MCF tend to be larger in recipients communities with a large distortionary taxation. For example, using data for Argentinian Provinces. Vegh and Vuletin (2015)Vegh, C. A., & Vuletin, G. (2015). Unsticking the flypaper effect in an uncertain world. Journal of Public Economics, 131,142-155. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2015.09.001
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2015...
show that the flypaper effect (and the stimulative effect of grants on public spending) is larger in localities with tax rate above the national average. In our sample although the average tax rate (AETR) is similar accross municipalites, larger municipalities tend to host larger firms, in terms of number of employees and total revenues (see Figure A-1 in Appendix Appendix. Table A-1 Population cutoffs for FPM (transfers) distribution. Population Range Factor Up to 10,188 0.6 From 10,189 to 13,584 0.8 From 13,585 to 16,980 1.0 From 16,981 to 23,772 1.2 From 23,773 to 30,564 1.4 From 30,565 to 37,356 1.6 From 37,357 to 44,148 1.8 From 44,149 to 50,940 2.0 From 50,941 to 61,128 2.2 From 61,129 to 71,316 2.4 From 71,317 to 81,504 2.6 From 81,505 to 91,692 2.8 From 91,693 to 101,880 3.0 From 101,881 to 115,464 3.2 From 115,465 to 129,048 3.4 From 129,049 to 142,632 3.6 From 142,633 to 156,216 3.8 > 156,216 4.0 Note: Law by Decree nº 1.881/1981. Table A-2 Regression on tax base elasticity (without tax capacity covariate). Dependent variable: Ln of number of firms. Bandwidth size 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 3,000 4,000 Total Cut-off 1 -0.140 *** -0.094 ** -0.050 (-3.129) (-2.453) (-1.430) Number of cases 1,355 2,687 3,904 Cut-off 2 -0.023 -0.009 -0.013 (-1.114) (-0.507) (-0.640) Number of cases 2,003 2,947 3,914 Cut-off 3 0.177 *** 0.111 -0.041 (3.253) (0.993) (-0.934) Number of cases 2,214 2,476 4,298 Cut-off 4 -0.249 -0.004 0.191 (-1.182) (-0.021) (0.957) Number of cases 1,769 2,596 3,520 Cut-off 5 -0.629 ** -0.570 ** -0.476 ** (-2.357) (-2.467) (-2.437) Number of cases 997 1,519 2,023 Total -0.016 ** (-2.463) Number of cases 37,708 Notes: All regressions include fixed effect and time effects. In parentheses are robust t statics *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Table A-3 First Stage (IV) regression results. Population cutoffs (binary variables) dfxpop1 -0.446 *** (-19.360) dfxpop2 -0.310 *** (-15.240) dfxpop3 -0.211 *** (-11.530) dfxpop4 -0.147 *** (-9.220) dfxpop5 -0.102 *** (-7.590) dfxpop6 -0.064 *** (-6.300) dfxpop7 -0.029 *** (-4.100) dfxpop9 0.020 ** (2.040) dfxpop10 0.007 (0.820) dfxpop12 0.008 (0.710) dfxpop14 -0.010 (-0.440) dfxpop16 -0.006 (-0.360) Notes: All regressions include fixed effect and time effects. In parentheses are t statistics. Number of obs is 36,211. *** p < 0.01, ** p < 0.05, * p < 0.1. Figure A-1 Firms’ Size (number of Employees). ).

Thus, overall, our results reflects most of the public funding scheme in Brazil, where public provision in smaller cities are financed mostly by grants (this resource accounts for 80% of total public resources) and in larger cities mostly by local taxes. Results in total sample could be capturing this higher price effect of grants on municipalities that present higher distortionary taxation over business services.

5. Conclusion

This paper investigates the effect of unconditional grants on the Marginal Cost of Public Funding (MCF) using Brazilian local governments data. In particular, we explore the model proposed in Dahlby (2011)Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-916...
, to design a theoretical extension that shows the difference between the price effect resulting from grants and from income attempt to show how these different methods of increasing income change the effective price of public goods.

Using data from Brazilian national Treasury for the years 2006 to 2012 we construct average effective ISS local taxes and unconditional (FPM - the recipient government has complete freedom to decide on the allocation of the resources) transfers to estimate such difference.

We first estimate the effect of tax rates on tax basis in order to construct MCF estimations. That estimated semi-elasticity (-0.016) is used to calculate the MCF, representing the price of the public good for each municipality.

Next, we estimate the effect of transfers and income on the constructed MCF, correcting the standard error of these estimations. We estimate that for R$ 1 increase in unconditional transfers seems to reduce (in average) the local price effect (MCF) but not in a consistent fashion. Considering the entire sample, our estimates suggests that an increase in R$ 1.00 in per capita unconditional transfers reduces the local price effect (MCF) around 0.00003 (0.07 % of the average MCF), but this result is not consistently estimated across all subsamples.

  • 1
    For a detailed survey, see Inman (2008)Inman, R. P. (2008, December). The flypaper effect (Working Paper No. 14579). National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w14579
    http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w14579...
    and Gamkhar and Shah (2007)Gamkhar, S., & Shah, A. (2007). The impact of intergovernmental transfers: A synthesis of the conceptual and empirical literature. In R. Boadway & A. Shah (Eds.), Intergovernmental fiscal transfers: Principles and practice (pp. 225-258). Washington, DC: World Bank. http://hdl.handle.net/10986/7171
    http://hdl.handle.net/10986/7171...
    . For Brazil, Siqueira, Nogueira, Souza, and Carvalho (2010)Siqueira, R. B. d., Nogueira, J. R. B., Souza, E. S. d., & Carvalho, D. B. (2010, December). O custo marginal social da tributação indireta no Brasil: Identificando direções de reforma. In 38ºEncontro Nacional de Economia da ANPEC, Salvador, BA. http://www.anpec.org.br/encontro2010/inscricao/arquivos/271-8dbd10a9e0435a7e286905e9dda8141a.doc
    http://www.anpec.org.br/encontro2010/ins...
    found 0.002 to 2.2 using 27 groups of goods. Lanzer and Porto (2011)Lanzer, B. N., & Porto, S. d. S., Jr. (2011, December). A economia informal e o custo marginal da trib utação no Brasil. In 39º Encontro Nacional de Economia daANPEC, Foz do Iguaçu. http://anpec.org.br/encontro/2011/inscricao/arquivos/000-614536d09ffbc91573943c164f21ad09.pdf
    http://anpec.org.br/encontro/2011/inscri...
    estimated the MCF forthe whole Brazilian tax system in between 1.167 and 1.173. See also Cossio (2002)Cossio, F. A. B. (2002). Ensaios sobre federalismo fiscal no Brasil (PhD Thesis, PUC-Rio, Rio de Janeiro). http://dx.doi.org/10.17771/PUCRio.acad.3712
    http://dx.doi.org/10.17771/PUCRio.acad.3...
    and Cossio and Carvalho (2001)Cossio, F. A. B., & Carvalho, L. M. d. (2001). Os efeitos expansivos das transferências intergovernamentais e transbordamentos espaciais de despesas públicas: Evidências para os municípios brasileiros - 1996. Pesquisa e Planejamento Econômico, 31(1), 75-124. http://ppe.ipea.gov.br/index.php/ppe/article/view/161
    http://ppe.ipea.gov.br/index.php/ppe/art...
    .
  • 2
    Recently Auriol and Warlters (2012)Auriol, E., & Warlters, M. (2012). The marginal cost of public funds and tax reform in Africa. Journal of Development Economics, 97(1), 58-72. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.01.003
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011...
    estimated a mean MCF of 1.21 for 38 African countries using a general equilibrium model, finding that taxes on production factors have higher MCFs than do taxes on imports and domestic goods.
  • 3
    Furthermore, the municipalities are assumed to be in the increasing segment ofthe Laffer Curve, i.e., 1 + Ttq > 0. It can be shown that MCF is increasing with respect to tax rate under some conditions.
  • 4
    For example, if we consider c = 1, E = 0 (i.e., there is no variation in the elasticity of the tax base), B = 100, and t = 1.01 (tax rate of 1%), one has a price effect resulting from the grants that is equal to -0.00017 and a price effect of income equal to -0.0000002, less (in magnitude) because the price effect of income is multiplied by the variation in the tax base in relation to income (0.001).
  • 5
    It follows Lei Complementar 116/2003 and Emenda Constitucional 37/2002.
  • 6
    See Carvalho (2006)Carvalho, P. H. B. d., Jr. (2006, December). IPTU no Brasil: Progressividade, arrecadação e aspectos extra-fiscais (Texto para Discussão No. 1251). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada (IPEA). http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=4814
    http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/index.php?...
    for a comprehensive discussion in Portuguese.
  • 7
    There are two other additional types of intergovernmental transfers: Federal Support for Education Fund (FUNDEB, in Portuguese), and Federal Support for Health System (SUS, in Portuguese). Together, those grants account for on average approximatelly 10% of municipalities revenue resources. However, as opposed to FPM grants, they are denominated matching grant transfers as they produce different allocative effects because they impose a counterpart spending for local governments. Because of that, we do not include those grants in our analysis.
  • 8
    It follows Lei Complementar number 123/06 and Lei Complementar 155 (2016). For example, in year 2010 firms were shared in 20 different groups according their total revenue. Statutory tax rate varied from 4.5% to 16.85%.
  • 9
    We should note that this fact has being previously explored by and Brollo and Nannicini (2012)Brollo, F., & Nannicini, T. (2012). Tying your enemy’s hands in close races: The politics of federal transfers in Brazil. American Political Science Review, 106(4), 742-761. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055412000433
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055412000...
    in a regression discontinuity design (RDD).
  • 10
    There is a large literature on the determination of the response of the tax base in relation to a tax variation. Gruber and Saez (2002)Gruber, J., & Saez, E. (2002). The elasticity of taxable income: Evidence and implications. Journal of Public Economics, 84(1), 1-32. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(01)00085-8
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(01)...
    perform this estimation for the USA, and Mintz and Smart (2004)Mintz, J., & Smart, M. (2004). Income shifting, investment, and tax competition: Theory and evidence from provincial taxation in Canada. Journal of Public Economics, 88(6), 1149-1168. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(03)00060-4
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(03)...
    do so for Canada. Dahlby (2008)Dahlby, B. (2008). The marginal cost of public funds: Theory and applications. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. provides a good review of the topic and also shows results in the context of fiscal federalism.
  • 11
    Although Litschig and Morrison (2013)Litschig, S., & Morrison, K. M. (2013). The impact of intergovernmental transfers on education outcomes and poverty reduction. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(4), 206-240. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/app.5A206
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/app.5A206...
    shows that the population measure could be manipulated by municipalities in the 1990s, such manipulation has not been observed since 2000, when the federal governments started to use census data and IBGE estimates for the population. See also Brollo, Nannicini, Perotti, and Tabellini (2013)Brollo, F., Nannicini, T., Perotti, R., & Tabellini, G. (2013). The political resource curse. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1759-1796. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.5.1759
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.5.1759...
    and Ferraz and Finan (2011)Ferraz, C., & Finan, F. (2011). Electoral accountability and corruption: Evidence from the audits oflocal governments. American Economic Review, 101(4), 1274-1311. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.10L4.1274
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.10L4.1274...
    for further evidence and discussion.
  • 12
  • 13
  • 14
    Imposto Sobre Circulação de Mercadorias e Serviços.
  • 15
    Table A-3in Appendix brings the coefficents for the first stage regression and it shows that all binary variables are significant. They present negative signal which reflects the fact that the smaller the population the higher the FPM per capita received.

Appendix.

Table A-1
Population cutoffs for FPM (transfers) distribution.
Table A-2
Regression on tax base elasticity (without tax capacity covariate). Dependent variable: Ln of number of firms.
Table A-3
First Stage (IV) regression results.

Figure A-1
Firms’ Size (number of Employees).

References

  • Auriol, E., & Warlters, M. (2012). The marginal cost of public funds and tax reform in Africa. Journal of Development Economics, 97(1), 58-72. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.01.003
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.01.003
  • Brollo, F., & Nannicini, T. (2012). Tying your enemy’s hands in close races: The politics of federal transfers in Brazil. American Political Science Review, 106(4), 742-761. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055412000433
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0003055412000433
  • Brollo, F., Nannicini, T., Perotti, R., & Tabellini, G. (2013). The political resource curse. American Economic Review, 103(5), 1759-1796. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.5.1759
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.103.5.1759
  • Browning, E. K. (1987). On the marginal welfare cost of taxation. The American Economic Review, 77(1), 11-23. https://www.jstor.org/stable/1806725
    » https://www.jstor.org/stable/1806725
  • Buettner, T., & Fabritz, N. (2011, June 30). Responses to grants and the marginal cost of public funds. In IV Workshop on Fiscal Federalism, Barcelona.
  • Buettner, T., & Holm-Hadulla, F. (2008, November). Cities in fiscal equalization (CESifo Working Paper No. 2447). Munich, Germany: CESifo Group. http://www.cesifo-group.de/ifoHome/publications/docbase/DocBase_Content/WP/WP-CESifo_Working_Papers/wp-cesifo-2008/wp-cesifo-2008-11/12012008002447.html
    » http://www.cesifo-group.de/ifoHome/publications/docbase/DocBase_Content/WP/WP-CESifo_Working_Papers/wp-cesifo-2008/wp-cesifo-2008-11/12012008002447.html
  • Carbonnier, C. (2008, February). Fiscal competition between decentralized jurisdictions, theoreti cal and empirical evidence (Documents de travail No. 2008-17). Cergy-Pontoise: THEMA - Université de Cergy-Pontoise. http://thema.u-cergy.fr/IMG/documents/2008-17.pdf
    » http://thema.u-cergy.fr/IMG/documents/2008-17.pdf
  • Carvalho, P. H. B. d., Jr. (2006, December). IPTU no Brasil: Progressividade, arrecadação e aspectos extra-fiscais (Texto para Discussão No. 1251). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada (IPEA). http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=4814
    » http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=4814
  • Cossio, F. A. B. (2002). Ensaios sobre federalismo fiscal no Brasil (PhD Thesis, PUC-Rio, Rio de Janeiro). http://dx.doi.org/10.17771/PUCRio.acad.3712
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.17771/PUCRio.acad.3712
  • Cossio, F. A. B., & Carvalho, L. M. d. (2001). Os efeitos expansivos das transferências intergovernamentais e transbordamentos espaciais de despesas públicas: Evidências para os municípios brasileiros - 1996. Pesquisa e Planejamento Econômico, 31(1), 75-124. http://ppe.ipea.gov.br/index.php/ppe/article/view/161
    » http://ppe.ipea.gov.br/index.php/ppe/article/view/161
  • Dahlberg, M., Mork, E., Rattsø, J., & Ågren, H. (2008). Using a discontinuous grant rule to identify the effect of grants on local taxes and spending. Journal of Public Economics, 92(12), 2320-2335. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.05.004
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.05.004
  • Dahlby, B. (2008). The marginal cost of public funds: Theory and applications Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
  • Dahlby, B. (2011). The marginal cost of public funds and flypaper effect. International Tax and Public Finance, 18(3), 304-321. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-010-9160-x
  • Ferraz, C., & Finan, F. (2011). Electoral accountability and corruption: Evidence from the audits oflocal governments. American Economic Review, 101(4), 1274-1311. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.10L4.1274
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.10L4.1274
  • Fisher, R. C. (1982). Income and grants effects on local expenditure: The flypaper effect and other difficulties. Journal of Public Economics, 17(3), 324-345. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(82)90021-3
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(82)90021-3
  • Gamkhar, S., & Shah, A. (2007). The impact of intergovernmental transfers: A synthesis of the conceptual and empirical literature. In R. Boadway & A. Shah (Eds.), Intergovernmental fiscal transfers: Principles and practice (pp. 225-258). Washington, DC: World Bank. http://hdl.handle.net/10986/7171
    » http://hdl.handle.net/10986/7171
  • Gramlich, E. (1977). Intergovernmental grants: A review of the empirical literature. In W.E. Oates (Ed.), The political economy of fiscal federalism Lexington Press.
  • Gruber, J., & Saez, E. (2002). The elasticity of taxable income: Evidence and implications. Journal of Public Economics, 84(1), 1-32. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(01)00085-8
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(01)00085-8
  • Hakonsen, L. (1998). An investigation into alternative representations of the marginal cost of public funds. International Tax and Public Finance, 5(3), 329-343. http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1008686227749
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1008686227749
  • Hamilton, J. H. (1986). The flypaper effect and the deadweight loss from taxation. Journal of Urban Economics, 19(2), 148-155. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(86)90036-7
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(86)90036-7
  • Hayashi, M., & Boadway, R. (2001). An empirical analysis of intergovernmental tax interaction: The case of business income taxes in Canada. Canadian Journal of Economics, 34(2), 481-503. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0008-4085.00085
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0008-4085.00085
  • Hines, J. R., & Thaler, R. H. (1995). The flypaper effect. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(4), 217-226. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.9A217
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/jep.9A217
  • Inman, R. P. (2008, December). The flypaper effect (Working Paper No. 14579). National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w14579
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w14579
  • Jacobs, B. (2018). The marginal cost of public funds is one at the optimal tax system. International Tax and Public Finance, 25(4), 883-912. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-017-9481-0
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10797-017-9481-0
  • Lanzer, B. N., & Porto, S. d. S., Jr. (2011, December). A economia informal e o custo marginal da trib utação no Brasil. In 39º Encontro Nacional de Economia daANPEC, Foz do Iguaçu. http://anpec.org.br/encontro/2011/inscricao/arquivos/000-614536d09ffbc91573943c164f21ad09.pdf
    » http://anpec.org.br/encontro/2011/inscricao/arquivos/000-614536d09ffbc91573943c164f21ad09.pdf
  • Litschig, S., & Morrison, K. M. (2013). The impact of intergovernmental transfers on education outcomes and poverty reduction. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 5(4), 206-240. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/app.5A206
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/app.5A206
  • Mintz, J., & Smart, M. (2004). Income shifting, investment, and tax competition: Theory and evidence from provincial taxation in Canada. Journal of Public Economics, 88(6), 1149-1168. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(03)00060-4
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0047-2727(03)00060-4
  • Siqueira, R. B. d., Nogueira, J. R. B., Souza, E. S. d., & Carvalho, D. B. (2010, December). O custo marginal social da tributação indireta no Brasil: Identificando direções de reforma. In 38ºEncontro Nacional de Economia da ANPEC, Salvador, BA. http://www.anpec.org.br/encontro2010/inscricao/arquivos/271-8dbd10a9e0435a7e286905e9dda8141a.doc
    » http://www.anpec.org.br/encontro2010/inscricao/arquivos/271-8dbd10a9e0435a7e286905e9dda8141a.doc
  • Van der Klaauw, W. (2002). Estimating the effect of financial aid offers on college enrollment: A regression-discontinuity approach. International Economic Review, 43(4), 1249-1287. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00055
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1468-2354.t01-1-00055
  • Vegh, C. A., & Vuletin, G. (2015). Unsticking the flypaper effect in an uncertain world. Journal of Public Economics, 131,142-155. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2015.09.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2015.09.001
  • Wyckoff, P. G. (1991). The elusive flypaper effect. Journal of Urban Economics, 30(3), 293-305. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(91)90052-9
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0094-1190(91)90052-9

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Oct-Dec 2018

History

  • Received
    17 Dec 2015
  • Accepted
    05 July 2018
Fundação Getúlio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 11º andar, 22253-900 Rio de Janeiro RJ Brazil, Tel.: +55 21 3799-5831 , Fax: +55 21 2553-8821 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: rbe@fgv.br