Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Economic Growth Channels From Human Capital: A Dynamic Panel Analysis for Brazil

Abstract

The purpose of this paper is to test the effect of human capital on Brazilian economic growth through the factor accumulation channel and the total factor productivity channel. We used new human capital measures, covering the period from 1996 to 2015 and employed the two-step SYS-GMM method, with standard finite sample error correction and principal components analysis for the control of the proliferation of instruments. The results show that human capital affects economic growth through both individually tested channels. Also, both basic and advanced human capital have a positive impact on growth through the total factor productivity channel.

Keywords:
Human capital; economic growth GMM model; dynamic panel data

Resumo

O objetivo do artigo é testar o efeito do capital humano no crescimento econômico brasileiro através dos canais de acumulação de fatores e produtividade total de fatores. Utilizamos novas medidas de capital humano, cobrindo o período de 1996 a 2015 e empregamos o método two-step SYS-GMM, com correção de erros padrão de amostra finita e análise de componentes principais para o controle da proliferação de instrumentos. Os resultados mostram que o capital humano afeta o crescimento econômico por meio de ambos os canais, testados individualmente. No mais, tanto capital humano básico quanto avançado produzem impacto positivo no crescimento por meio do canal de produtividade total dos fatores.

1. Introduction

The theoretical models of economic growth highlighted the importance of human capital from the perspective of obtaining education (Nelson & Phelps, 1966Nelson, R. R., & Phelps, E. S. (1966). Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. The American Economic Review, 56(1/2), 69-75. http://dx.doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/stable/1821269
http://dx.doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/...
; Lucas, 1988Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3-42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)9...
; Becker, Murphy, & Tamura, 1990Becker, G. S., Murphy, K. M., & Tamura, R. (1990). Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5, Part 2), S12-S37. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261723
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261723...
; Mulligan & Sala-i-Martin, 1993Mulligan, C. B., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1993). Transitional dynamics in two-sector models of endogenous growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 739-773. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118407
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118407...
). Barro and Lee (2013)Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950-2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104,184-198. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.j deveco.2012.10.001
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.j deveco.201...
find a positive and significant effect of workers’ schooling, measured in average years of total schooling, on the production level of the countries. However, due to the limited availability of education measures for different countries and regions, many proxies are used in the literature to identify the effect of human capital on economic growth (P. M. Romer, 1990Romer, P. M. (1990). Human capital and growth: Theory and evidence. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 32,251-286. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0167-2231(90)90028
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0167-2231(90)9...
; Barro, 1991Barro, R. J. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 407-443. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2937943
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2937943...
; Kyriacou, 1991Kyriacou, G. A. (1991). Level andgrowth effects of human capital: A cross-country study of the convergence hypothesis (Working Paper No. 91-26). New York, NY: C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics.; Benhabib & Spiegel, 1992Benhabib, J., & Spiegel, M. M. (1992). The role of human capital and political instability in economic development., 1994; Barro & Lee, 1993Barro, R. J., & Lee, J.-W (1993). International comparisons of educational attainment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 363-394. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)90023-9
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)9...
). Some examples of these proxies are years of study in basic and/or advanced education, total expenditures with education and expenditures by education levels, enrollment rates, among others (Pelinescu, 2015Pelinescu, E. (2015). The impact of human capital on economic growth. Procedia Economics and Finance, 22,184-190. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(15)00258-0
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(15)...
; Ogundari & Awokuse, 2018Ogundari, K., & Awokuse, T. (2018). Human capital contribution to economicgrowth in Sub-Saharan Africa: Does health status matter more than education? Economic Analysis and Policy, 58,131-140. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2018.02.001
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2018.02....
; Li & Wang, 2018Li, T., & Wang, Y. (2018). Growth channels of human capital: A Chinese panel data study. China Economic Review, 51, 309-322. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxhieco.2016.11.002
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxhieco.2016.1...
; Kazmi, Ali, & Ali, 2017Kazmi, S. M., Ali, K., & Ali, G. (2017). Impact of human capital on economic growth: Evidence from Pakistan. http://hdl.handle.net/11540/7744
http://hdl.handle.net/11540/7744...
).

Studies on the importance of the role of human for the process of economic growth in Brazil have advanced in recent years. Several researchers try to overcome the restrictions to measuring human capital by considering different proxies to evaluate the importance of human capital in growth. For instance, Bondezan and Dias (2016)Bondezan, K. d. L., &Dias, J. (2016). Crescimento econômico no Brasil: Uma abordagem sobre o papel da acumulação de capital físico e humano. Revista de Economia, 42(3). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/re.v42i3.51619
http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/re.v42i3.51619...
proposed a method of estimating the stock of Brazilian human capital and public and private physical capital based on the estimates of Garofalo and Yamarik (2002)Garofalo, G. A., & Yamarik, S. (2002). Regional convergence: Evidence from a new state-by-state capital stock series. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 316-323. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/003465302317411569
http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/00346530231741...
and Mincer (1974)Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience, andearnings. National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). https://www.nber.org/books/minc74-1
https://www.nber.org/books/minc74-1...
. Considering the number of individuals with complete elementary and secondary education as a measure for human capital, Irffi, Arruda, Bastos, and Barboza (2016)Irffi, G., Arruda, E., Bastos, F., & Barboza, D. (2016). Impactos da abertura comercial e contribuição dos diferenciais de escolaridade sobre o nível de renda dos municípios cearenses, no período 1997-2005. Ensaios FEE, 37(1), 217-254. https://revistas.fee.tche.br/index.php/ensaios/article/view/3004
https://revistas.fee.tche.br/index.php/e...
investigate whether human capital and Brazilian trade openness have an impact in economic growth in the municipalities of Ceará. The work of Guimarães, Fully, and Silveira (2017)Guimarães, A. A. B., Fully, R. M. P., & Silveira, L. P. (2017). Análise do capital humano, sob a ótica da teoria do crescimento endógeno, na produtividade total dos fatores no Brasil. Revista Eletrônica Gestão e Serviços, 8(1), 1902-1918. http://dx.doi.org/10.15603/2177-7284/regs.v8n1p1902-1918
http://dx.doi.org/10.15603/2177-7284/reg...
analyzes the evolution of total productivity factors, considering the evolution of the number of graduates in higher education in Brazil from 1971 to 2011.

In addition, the literature uses several methods to identify the effect of human capital on economic performance. The empirical analysis apply from time series methods with autoregressive vectors, vector error correction (Salgueiro, Nakabashi, & De Prince, 2011Salgueiro, A. d. S., Nakabashi, L., & De Prince, D. (2011). O papel do capital humano no crescimento: Uma análise espacial para o Brasil. Revista Economia & Tecnologia, 7(4). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911
http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911...
; Guimarães et al., 2017Guimarães, A. A. B., Fully, R. M. P., & Silveira, L. P. (2017). Análise do capital humano, sob a ótica da teoria do crescimento endógeno, na produtividade total dos fatores no Brasil. Revista Eletrônica Gestão e Serviços, 8(1), 1902-1918. http://dx.doi.org/10.15603/2177-7284/regs.v8n1p1902-1918
http://dx.doi.org/10.15603/2177-7284/reg...
; Kazmi et al., 2017Kazmi, S. M., Ali, K., & Ali, G. (2017). Impact of human capital on economic growth: Evidence from Pakistan. http://hdl.handle.net/11540/7744
http://hdl.handle.net/11540/7744...
), ordinary least squares (Moreira, 2014Moreira, É. T. (2014). Impactos da tecnologia e do capital humano sobre o crescimento econômico asiático: Uma abordagem via dados de painel. Revista Teoria e Evidência Econômica, 20(43), 213-237. http://dx.doi.org/10.5335/rtee.v20i43.4591
http://dx.doi.org/10.5335/rtee.v20i43.45...
; Gama, 2014Gama, V. A. (2014). Os efeitos da qualidade da educação sobre a acumulação de capital humano e o crescimento econômico no Brasil (Tese de Doutorado, Universidade de São Paulo, Piracicaba, SP). http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/X11.2014.tde-03062014-153434
http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/X11.2014.tde-...
; Cunha & Nunes, 2016Cunha, A. F., & Nunes, S. F. (2016). Educação e crescimento econômico: Análise dos municípios da região dos Campos Gerais do Paraná. Revista de Ensino, Educação e Ciências Humanas, 17(3), 232-239. http://dx.doi.org/10.17921/2447-8733.2016v17n3p232-239
http://dx.doi.org/10.17921/2447-8733.201...
; Fully & Teixeira, 2016Fully, R. M. P., & Teixeira, A. (2016). Os efeitos da educação sobre o progresso tecnológico no Brasil. Gestão e Sociedade, 10(25), 1274-1283. http://dx.doi.org/10.21171/ges.v10i25.1978
http://dx.doi.org/10.21171/ges.v10i25.19...
; Jameel & Naeem, 2016Jameel, S., & Naeem, M. Z. (2016). Impact of human capital on economic growth: A panel study. Bulletin of Business and Economics, 5(4), 231-248. https://ideas.repec.org/aZrfh/bbejor/v5y2016i4p231-248.html
https://ideas.repec.org/aZrfh/bbejor/v5y...
), panel data (Salgueiro et al., 2011Salgueiro, A. d. S., Nakabashi, L., & De Prince, D. (2011). O papel do capital humano no crescimento: Uma análise espacial para o Brasil. Revista Economia & Tecnologia, 7(4). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911
http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911...
; Barro &Lee, 2013Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950-2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104,184-198. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.j deveco.2012.10.001
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.j deveco.201...
; Pelinescu, 2015Pelinescu, E. (2015). The impact of human capital on economic growth. Procedia Economics and Finance, 22,184-190. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(15)00258-0
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(15)...
), spatial econometrics (Salgueiro, 2012Salgueiro, A. d. S. (2012). O papel do capital humano, spillovers e difusão tecnológica no crescimento: Uma análise espacial para Brasil (Dissertação de Mestrado). Universidade Federal do Paraná, Curitiba, PR.; Firme & Simão Filho, 2014Firme, V. d. A. C., &Simão Filho, J. (2014). Análise do crescimento econômico dos municípios de Minas Gerais via modelo MRW (1992) com capital humano, condições de saúde e fatores espaciais, 1991-2000. Economia Aplicada, 18(4), 679-716. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1413-8050/ea640
http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1413-8050/ea64...
; Gama, 2014Gama, V. A. (2014). Os efeitos da qualidade da educação sobre a acumulação de capital humano e o crescimento econômico no Brasil (Tese de Doutorado, Universidade de São Paulo, Piracicaba, SP). http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/X11.2014.tde-03062014-153434
http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/X11.2014.tde-...
), to even dynamic panels (Cangussu, Salvato, & Nakabashi, 2010Cangussu, R. C., Salvato, M. A., & Nakabashi, L. (2010). Uma análise do capital humano sobre o nível de renda dos estados brasileiros: MRW versus Mincer. Estudos Econômicos, 40(1), 153-183. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/S0101-41612010000100006
http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/S0101-41612010...
; Fraga, 2011Fraga, G. J. (2011). Estudo da relação entre comércio internacional, capital humano e crescimento econômico no Brasil no período de 1995 a 2006 (Tese de Doutorado, Universidade de São Paulo, Piracicaba, SP). http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/T.11.2011.tde-02082011-103009
http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/T.11.2011.tde...
; Castelló-Climent & Mukhopadhyay, 2013Castelló-Climent, A., & Mukhopadhyay, A. (2013). Mass education or a minority well educated elite in the process of growth: The case of India. Journal of Development Economics, 105, 303-320. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.03.012
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013...
; Silva & Sumarto, 2015Silva, I. d., & Sumarto, S. (2015). Dynamics of growth, poverty and human capital: Evidence from Indonesian sub-national data. Journal of Economic Development, 40(2). http://www.jed.or.kr/full-text/40-2/1.pdf
http://www.jed.or.kr/full-text/40-2/1.pd...
; Bayraktar-Saglam, 2016Bayraktar-Saglam, B. (2016). The stages of human capital and economic growth: Does the direction of causality matter for the rich and the poor? Social Indicators Research, 127 (1), 243-302. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-0963-0
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-096...
; Li & Wang, 2018Li, T., & Wang, Y. (2018). Growth channels of human capital: A Chinese panel data study. China Economic Review, 51, 309-322. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxhieco.2016.11.002
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxhieco.2016.1...
; Irffi et al., 2016Irffi, G., Arruda, E., Bastos, F., & Barboza, D. (2016). Impactos da abertura comercial e contribuição dos diferenciais de escolaridade sobre o nível de renda dos municípios cearenses, no período 1997-2005. Ensaios FEE, 37(1), 217-254. https://revistas.fee.tche.br/index.php/ensaios/article/view/3004
https://revistas.fee.tche.br/index.php/e...
; Bondezan & Dias, 2016Bondezan, K. d. L., &Dias, J. (2016). Crescimento econômico no Brasil: Uma abordagem sobre o papel da acumulação de capital físico e humano. Revista de Economia, 42(3). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/re.v42i3.51619
http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/re.v42i3.51619...
; Teixeira & Queirós, 2016Teixeira, A. A. C., & Queirós, A. S. S. (2016). Economic growth, human capital and structural change: A dynamic panel data analysis. Research Policy, 45(8), 1636-1648. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.04.006
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016....
; Ogundari & Awokuse, 2018Ogundari, K., & Awokuse, T. (2018). Human capital contribution to economicgrowth in Sub-Saharan Africa: Does health status matter more than education? Economic Analysis and Policy, 58,131-140. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2018.02.001
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2018.02....
).

The purpose of this paper is to examine the channels by which aggregated and disaggregated human capital at the basic and advanced level affects the economic growth of the 26 Brazilian states plus the Federal District. That is, we will test the following two hypotheses: (i) whether aggregate human capital affects growth through the factor accumulation channel, through the total factor productivity channel, or through both channels simultaneously; and (ii) whether human capital disaggregated at the basic and advanced levels affect growth through the factor accumulation channel, through the total factor productivity, or through both channels simultaneously.

This study contributes to the literature of economic growth and human capital in Brazil, not only by measuring the effects of human capital through the channels of factor accumulation and productivity, but also because we consider a new measure of human capital, expressed by wages based on the education of the graduates of the different levels of education in Brazil. As far as we know, no other work has used this variable for these purposes. This measure stands out because it addresses the main caveats of the human capital proxies that are often used, since it depicts the stock rather than the flows of the accumulation of human capital, and, moreover, do not disregard aspects of school dropout or failure and of the labor productivity, related to the returns of formal education, experience and training. Another important contribution of this paper lies in its econometric analysis. That is, the empirical section innovates when applying the Two-Step System GMM Method (Arellano & Bover, 1995Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components model. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29-52. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)0...
; Blundell & Bond, 1998Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamicpanel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)...
), with Windmeijer’s (2005)Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25-51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004...
correction of standard errors for finite samples, and the Principal Component Analysis to control the proliferation of instruments (Mehrhoff, 2009Mehrhoff, J. (2009). A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM (Discussion Paper No. 31/2009). Frankfurt am Main. https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/...
; Kapetanios & Marcellino, 2010Kapetanios, G., & Marcellino, M. (2010). Factor-GMM estimation with large sets of possibly weak instruments. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 54(11), 2655-2675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04.008
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04....
; Bai & Ng, 2010Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2010). Instrumental variable estimation in a data rich environment. Econometric Theory, 26(6), 1577-1606. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990727
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990...
).

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the theoretical framework. Section 3 discusses the identification strategy, where we present the method and describe the data. Section 4 describes the results of the estimates. Section 5 presents the robustness analysis of the results listed in section 4. Finally, section 6 concludes.

2. The model1 1 This section is based on D. Romer and Chow (1996) and Li and Wang (2018).

Consider the following Solow growth model augmented with human capital, similar to those proposed by Lucas (1988)Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3-42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)9...
and Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992)Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. N. (1992). A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 407-437. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118477
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118477...
, with aggregate production function at time t given by

(1) Y t = A t K t α H t β L t γ ,

where Y is the output, A is the technological level, K is the physical capital, H is the human capital, L is the labor, and α + β + 𝛾 < 1. Assume that labor grows at the population growth rate n and that technology grows exogenously at rate g:

(2) L t = L 0 e nt ,

(3) A t = A 0 e gt .

Denoting per capita output by yit ≡ Yit/Lit, per capita physical capital by Kit ≡ Kit/Lit, and per capita human capital by hit ≡ Hit/Lit, where i denotes the corresponding individual of interest, the production function can be rewritten in per capita terms according to

(4) γ it = A it k it α h it β L it γ + α + β 1 .

Moreover, by taking the logarithm on both sides of equation (4), we obtain

(5) ln γ it = ln A it + α ln k it + β ln h it + γ + α + β 1 ln L it .

Considering (2) and (3), taking first differences of (5) and denoting by txk and by txh the growth rates of per capita physical and human capital respectively, the regression equation for growth accounting can be expressed as follows:

(6) Δ ln γ it = g + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txh it + θ 3 n it + ε it .

That is, equation (6) describes the factor accumulation channel, since it treats human capital as a factor of production, so that the growth rate of the human capital stock produces effects on the growth rate of the per capita output.

On the other hand, the total factor productivity channel derives from the approach proposed by Nelson and Phelps (1966)Nelson, R. R., & Phelps, E. S. (1966). Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. The American Economic Review, 56(1/2), 69-75. http://dx.doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/stable/1821269
http://dx.doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/...
, which maintains that treating human capital simply as an additional factor of production represents a poor specification of the relation between this variable and economic growth. According to the authors, higher levels of human capital are capable of increasing the ability of an economy to innovate and/or adapt to new technologies. In other words, higher levels of human capital positively influence the rate of technological progress.

According to the proposed model, the main source of growth is technological diffusion, which in turn is improved by education, facilitating the process of adoption and implementation of new technologies. The growth rate of technology is therefore an increasing function of per capita human capital, hit, and of the gap between the technological level supported by the theory (or technological frontier), Tit, and the observed level, Ait, given by the ratio (Tit - Ait)/Ait, i.e.:

(7) A ˙ it A it = Φ h it T it A it A it , Φ 0 = 0 , Φ h > 0 .

Note that, from the modifications made, the rate of technological progress becomes endogenous, since it depends on the human capital stock of the economy. If we assume that the stock of human capital affects output only through the productivity term A(hit), therefore not considering it as an additional production factor, equation (4) must be modified in order to reflect this new hypothesis, i.e.,

(8) γ it = A h it k it α L it γ + α 1 ,

from which we can write the equation in logs:

(9) ln γ it = ln A h it + α ln k it + γ + α 1 ln L it ,

and derive the growth accounting regression equation that considers only the total factor productivity channel:2 2 Similar to the estimated equation in Benhabib and Spiegel (1994).

(10) Δ ln γ it = g h it + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 n it + ε it ,

Rewriting (10) in order to make the increasing relation between per capita human capital and the rate of endogenous technological progress explicit:

(11) Δ ln γ it = θ 0 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 ln h it + θ 3 n it + ε it .

Equation (11) shows that, through the total factor productivity channel, an increase in human capital stock is capable of affecting output growth, instead of only producing a level effect on output as previously described by equation (6) through the factor accumulation channel.

Finally, we can think of a third specification, assuming that output growth can be simultaneously affected by both the level and the growth rate of human capital. Equation (4) should be rewritten as follows:

(12) γ it = A h it k it α h it β L it γ + α + β 1 .

Taking logs,

(13) ln γ it = ln A h it + α ln k it + β ln h it + γ + α + β 1 ln L it ,

and then taking first differences, we obtain an alternative regression equation for growth accounting, which considers both the factor accumulation channel and the total factor productivity channel:

(14) Δ ln γ it = θ 0 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txh it + θ 3 ln h it + θ 4 n it + ε it .

Therefore, equation (14) shows how growth is affected both by the level of per capita human capital and by the growth rate of this variable, since we are now assuming that both channels-factor accumulation and total factor productivity-simultaneously affect growth.

The regression equations for growth accounting formulated are aligned to the purpose of this paper, which is to analyze the relative importance of the two channels of accumulation of human capital. It is possible, from equations (6), (11) and (14), respectively, to investigate whether human capital affects growth through (i) the factor accumulation channel, (ii) the total factor productivity channel, or (iii) both channels simultaneously.

Thus, if hypothesis (i) is true, then equation (6) is correctly specified and the estimated coefficient of the growth rate of per capita human capital should be positive and significant. On the other hand, if hypothesis (ii) is true, then (11) it is correctly specified and the estimated coefficient of the level of per capita human capital should be positive and significant. Finally, if (iii) is true, then (14) is correctly specified and the estimated coefficients of both terms that take human capital into account must be positive and significant.

In addition, it is interesting to examine whether different levels of human capital can affect growth channels differently. Disaggregating human capital into two levels, basic human capital (related to obtaining experiences/skills associated with elementary and high school), denoted by bh, and advanced human capital (related to obtaining experiences/skills associated with higher education), denoted by ah, the following joint hypotheses will be tested: (A) basic human capital affects output growth from the factor accumulation channel; (B) advanced human capital affects output growth from the total factor productivity channel, or (C) basic human capital, through the factor accumulation channel, and advanced human capital, through the total factor productivity channel, affect output growth simultaneously.

Formally, considering the additional assumptions (A), (B) or (C), the regressions (6), (11) and (14) can be rewritten, respectively, as follows:

(15) Δ ln γ it = g + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txbh it + θ 3 n it + ε it ,

(16) Δ ln γ it = θ 0 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 ln ah it + θ 3 n it + ε it .

(17) Δ ln γ it = θ 0 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txbh it + θ 3 ln ah it + θ 4 n it + ε it .

Finally, as a measure of robustness for the theoretical channels and also as form of designing a public policy aiming to encourage some specific level of human capital, we can interchange the human capital measures to test whether advanced human capital affects growth via the factor accumulation channel and whether basic human capital affects growth via the total factor productivity channel, either singly or simultaneously:

(18) Δ ln γ it = g + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txah it + θ 3 n it + ε it ,

(19) Δ ln γ it = θ 0 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 ln bh it + θ 3 n it + ε it ,

(20) Δ ln γ it = θ 0 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txah it + θ 3 ln bh it + θ 4 n it + ε it .

Since this paper intends to evaluate the channels by which aggregate human capital and disaggregated human capital at the basic and advanced levels affect Brazilian economic growth, in the empirical section we will test the nine regressions described by the equations (6), (11) and (14) and from (15) to (20) using a dynamic panel containing data for the federative units of Brazil, covering the period from 1996 to 2015. We will also consider other commonly used control variables in the growth literature, as it will be clear in the next session.

3. Identification strategy

3.1 Method

For a correct identification of the human capital channels, the regression equations must also include the (log) level of output per capita at the start of the period, to account for transitional convergence. We further consider as control variables the expenditures in education by region, the effects of the macroeconomic financial crises’ shocks,3 3 We control for the Asian Giants’ crisis (1997), the Ruble crisis (1998), the Argentine debt crisis (2001-2002) and the global financial crisis (2008-2010). and a time trend variable. Also, because Brazil is a continental country with diverse cultures and different regions, we need to control for regional fixed effects, 𝜇i . Thus, we must estimate the following regressions:

(21) Δ ln γ it = α + ρ 1 ln γ i , t 1 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txh it + θ 3 n it + Covariate s it θ 4 + μ i + t + ε it ,

(22) Δ ln γ it = α + ρ 1 ln γ i , t 1 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 ln h it + θ 3 n it + Covariate s it θ 4 + μ i + t + ε it ,

(23) Δ ln γ it = α + ρ 1 ln γ i , t 1 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txh it + θ 3 ln h it + Covariate s it θ 5 + μ i + t + ε it .

Clearly these regression equations can be written equivalently as:

(24) ln γ it = α + ρ ln γ i , t 1 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txh it + θ 3 n it + Covariate s it θ 4 + μ i + t + ε it ,

(25) ln = α + ρ ln γ i , t 1 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 ln h it + θ 3 n it + Covariate s it θ 4 + μ i + t + ε it ,

(26) ln γ it = α + ρ ln γ i , t 1 + θ 1 txk it + θ 2 txh it + θ 3 ln h it + θ 4 n it + Covariate s it θ 5 + μ i + t + ε it .

Therefore, the equations to be estimated to identify the effects of human capital on economic growth should control for the lagged dependent variable as an explanatory variable. The panel data structure in which the lagged dependent variable is considered as an explanatory variable is known in the literature as Dynamic Panel Data (DPD). Growth models4 4 See Bond, Hoeffler, and Temple (2001). are usually estimated through DPD techniques, mainly by the System GMM Method proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995)Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components model. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29-52. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)0...
and Blundell and Bond (1998)Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamicpanel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)...
. In general terms, GMM models are adequate when we come across the following setting: (i) few time periods and many individuals; (ii) linear relationship between variables; (iii) the dependent variable has dynamic characteristics; (iv) explanatory variables are not strictly exogenous, and therefore, are correlated with their past and possibly current error observations; (v) individual fixed effects; (vi) heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation within individuals, but not between them (Roodman, 2009aJ Roodman, D. (2009a). How to do Xtabond2: An introduction to Difference and System GMM in Stata (No. 9). http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0900900106
http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1536867X090090...
).

Blundell and Bond (1998)Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamicpanel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)...
argue that the difference-GMM estimator proposed by Arellano and Bond (1991)Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-297. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968...
may present persistence in the series, and consequently, the level variables become weak instruments for the difference equation, implying bias and low precision in finite samples. To circumvent this issue, the authors impose the condition that the difference variables should not be not correlated with the individual fixed effects. Therefore, more instruments can be considered, improving the efficiency of the Arellano-Bond estimator, and providing additional moment conditions for the level regression. Thus, the system-GMM is composed by the level equation, which uses the difference lags as an instrument, and by the difference equation, that uses the lagged variables as instruments.

It should be noted that both Arellano and Bond (1991)Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-297. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968...
and Blundell and Bond (1998)Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamicpanel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)...
estimators present one-step and two-step variants. For the one-step estimator, it is assumed that the error terms are independent and homoscedastic for each crosssection over time. For the two-step estimator, the residuals obtained in the first step are used to construct a consistent estimate of the variance-covariance matrix, relaxing the hypotheses of independence and homoscedasticity. The two-step estimator is asymptotically more efficient than one-step one, but in small samples the resulting standard errors can be strongly biased downwards. Windmeijer (2005)Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25-51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004...
corrects this problem (of standard errors being underestimated in finite samples), which makes the two-step robust and more efficient. Therefore, to identify the channels through which human capital affects economic growth in Brazil, we use the two-step system-GMM method in the analysis.

A disadvantage of the system-GMM estimator stems from the proliferation of instruments. The excess of instruments creates a trade-off between bias (overfitting of endogenous variables) and efficiency (additional moment conditions), generating an imprecise estimation of the moments’ variance-covariance matrix and weakening the instrument’s joint validity test (Bontempi & Mammi, 2012Bontempi, M. E., & Mammi, I. (2012, September). A strategy to reduce the count of moment conditions in panel data GMM (Quaderni - Working Paper No. 843). DSE. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2140799
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2140799...
; Roodman, 2009bRoodman, D. (2009b). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 135-158. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00542.x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.20...
). The proliferation of instruments occurs in a quadratic way in the temporal dimension, so we use the principal components’ extraction condition from the instrument matrix (Mehrhoff, 2009Mehrhoff, J. (2009). A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM (Discussion Paper No. 31/2009). Frankfurt am Main. https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/...
; Kapetanios & Marcellino, 2010Kapetanios, G., & Marcellino, M. (2010). Factor-GMM estimation with large sets of possibly weak instruments. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 54(11), 2655-2675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04.008
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04....
; Bai & Ng, 2010Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2010). Instrumental variable estimation in a data rich environment. Econometric Theory, 26(6), 1577-1606. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990727
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990...
).

According to Mehrhoff (2009)Mehrhoff, J. (2009). A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM (Discussion Paper No. 31/2009). Frankfurt am Main. https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/...
, the principal component analysis’ technique (PCA) for the system-GMM context is a factorization process that condenses the informational content of the available set of instruments, reducing the risk of overidentification. Moreover, the factored instruments have the advantage over other constraints’ categories in that their estimates have less bias, as well as greater robustness, being a good substitute for the arbitrariness of the researcher when restricting the number of instruments. Thus, through the use of PCA, we minimize informational loss and obtain a statistically reasoned and data-oriented technique, which is minimally arbitrary in the delimitation of the instruments, producing a smaller set of instruments that is maximally representative (Mehrhoff, 2009Mehrhoff, J. (2009). A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM (Discussion Paper No. 31/2009). Frankfurt am Main. https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/...
; Kapetanios & Marcellino, 2010Kapetanios, G., & Marcellino, M. (2010). Factor-GMM estimation with large sets of possibly weak instruments. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 54(11), 2655-2675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04.008
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04....
; Bai & Ng, 2010Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2010). Instrumental variable estimation in a data rich environment. Econometric Theory, 26(6), 1577-1606. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990727
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990...
).

As for the model specification tests, we highlight the Sargan’s (1958)Sargan, J. D. (1958). The estimation of economic relationships using instrumental variables. Econometrica, 26(3), 393-415. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1907619
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1907619...
and Hansen’s (1982)Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50(4), 1029-1054. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1912775
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1912775...
tests of overidentifying restrictions and Arellano and Bond’s (1991)Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-297. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968...
test for firstorder and second-order autocorrelation. The test of overidentifying restrictions aim to verify the validity of the instruments. The test’s null hypothesis is that the instruments are uncorrelated with the error term. Therefore, the non-rejection corroborates the validity of the instruments. The Sargan’s test is appropriate when using the one-step procedure (homoscedastic variance-covariance matrix), but when applying the two-step procedure (heteroscedastic variance-covariance matrix), the Hansen’s test must be used.

In this work, we report the Windmeijer’s corrected robust standard errors for finite samples, and so we consider Hansen’s test for the validity of the instruments. Regarding the Arellano and Bond’s test for first-order and second-order autocorrelation, assuming that there is no autocorrelation between the residuals in the level equation implies, by construction, that the difference equation will present autocorrelated errors. Thus, the test for first-order autocorrelation is expected to identify serial correction, while in the second order the autocorrelation is statistically zero. Therefore, for the estimator to be consistent, the test should reject the null hypothesis for first-order, AR(1), and do not reject the null hypothesis for the higher-order, AR(2).

When the sample is composed of a few groups and the time dimension is greater than 10, there is a tendency for the Hansen test to be weak, that is, to converge to the value 1 in order to accept the null hypothesis (Roodman, 2009bRoodman, D. (2009b). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 135-158. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00542.x
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.20...
). According to Labra and Torrecillas (2014)Labra, R., & Torrecillas, C. (2014). Guía CERO para datos de panel: Un enfoque práctico (Working Paper No. 2014/16). Madrid: UAM-Accenture. and Lillo and Torrecillas (2018)Lillo, R. L., & Torrecillas, C. (2018). Estimating dynamic panel data: A practical approach to perform long panels. Revista Colombiana de Estadística, 41(1), 31-52. http://dx.doi.org/10.15446/rce.v41n1.61885
http://dx.doi.org/10.15446/rce.v41n1.618...
, in this case, we must have a number of instruments equal to or less than the number of groups of individuals. We use the same number of instruments and groups. In our research, the number of groups is defined by the Federative Units (UF) of Brazil, which are equal to 27. It is important to note that, in the absence of the selection of the instruments by PCA, we must also consider the specification test known as difference-Hansen. When using the Blundell-Bond system-GMM (1998)Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamicpanel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)...
, there are more instruments available than when using the Arellano and Bond (1991)Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-297. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968...
difference-GMM procedure. Then the difference-Hansen tests the validity of these additional instruments. Its null hypothesis is that these additional instruments are valid.

In sum, as the main goal of this research is to evaluate the channels by which the aggregate and disaggregated human capital at the basic and advanced levels affect Brazilian states’ income growth, we use the two-step system-GMM method with Wind-meijer’s (2005) finite sample correction, which is asymptotically more efficient. Due to the fact that the dynamic panel is sensitive to the residuals’ autocorrelation, we report the Arellano and Bond’s test for first-order and second-order autocorrelation, AR(1) and AR(2), and the the Hansen and Diff-Hansen tests of the validity of instruments. Also, we use the PCA method to control the potential proliferation of instruments.

3.2 Data

One of the main problems of empirical work lies in the choice of a proxy for human capital. Barro and Lee (1993)Barro, R. J., & Lee, J.-W (1993). International comparisons of educational attainment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 363-394. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)90023-9
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)9...
argue that some proxies for human capital stock frequently used in the literature due to easy access have deficiencies, such as enrollment rates. These are deficient because they represent the flows, not the stock of human capital. The idea is that the accumulation of this flow that will generate the stock of human capital in the future, that is, the educational process takes time. According to Barro and Lee (1993)Barro, R. J., & Lee, J.-W (1993). International comparisons of educational attainment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 363-394. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)90023-9
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)9...
, there is a gap between flows and inventories and, even considering an appropriate gap, the initial stock estimates for the construction of a stock of human capital will still be necessary. In addition, enrollment rates do not consider school failure, mortality, migration, and especially school dropout, which are common in developing countries.

Adult literacy rates are also widely used in empirical work as proxies for human capital stock. Unlike enrollment rates, they represent a component of the current stock of human capital, but are an imperfect measure as well, as they do not reflect the skills that are obtained beyond the most elementary levels of schooling and disregard aspects of human capital that are important for labor productivity, such as logical and analytical reasoning and various types of technical knowledge (Barro & Lee, 1993Barro, R. J., & Lee, J.-W (1993). International comparisons of educational attainment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 363-394. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)90023-9
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)9...
). Sala-i-Martin and Mulligan (1995)Sala-i-Martin, X., & Mulligan, C. B. (1995, January). Measuring aggregate human capital (Center Discussion Paper No. 723). New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University. http://www.econ.yale.edu/growth_pdf/cdp723.pdf
http://www.econ.yale.edu/growth_pdf/cdp7...
point out that average years of schooling is also not a good proxy for human capital, since it assumes that: (i) workers are perfect substitutes regardless of their areas of expertise; (ii) the productivity differences between workers are proportional to the years of schooling regardless of their wage differences; (iii) the elasticity of substitution between workers of different categories is always constant, in every labor market; and (iv) one year of study manages the same increase of skill, regardless of study’s quality or area characteristics.

Mulligan and Sala-i-Martin (1993)Mulligan, C. B., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1993). Transitional dynamics in two-sector models of endogenous growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 739-773. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118407
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118407...
used a proxy for human capital based on labor income, with the aim of circumventing the aforementioned deficiencies. The intuition behind it was that the wage depended on the relative importance to the market, so that the type of education that was most useful to the market would be better paid. However, an income-based human capital proxy is also not a fault-free measure, since a worker’s wage does not depend solely on the skills and on the level of education, but also on the quantities of other aggregate inputs, such as physical capital and technology.

Thus, the main measure of human capital used in this study is the average wages monthly earned in the main occupation of the graduates of elementary, middle and high school, which we call “wage based on the education of graduates” and denote by HC. This measure considers both formal education returns and on-the-job training and experience. Data were extracted from the National Household Sample Survey (PNAD) and cover the period between 1996 and 2015. For the years 2000 and 2010, we use the averages between the previous and the subsequent years (Table 1).

Table 1
Description of the variables.

The data set is grouped in three ways: basic education, for the average wages of primary and secondary school graduates (HC_bh), advanced education, for the average wages of higher education graduates (HC_ah) and all levels (HC). That is, the proxy is the monthly average income in reais received in the main occupation of the graduates of elementary, middle and high school divided by the value of the minimum wage,5 5 The objective of dividing the monthly income by the minimum wage amount is to expunge the income variation determined by law. which we collect from the Institute of Applied Economic Research (IPEA). Both income and minimum wages are at constant values for the year 2010, deflated by the broad consumer price index (IPCA).

We use the expenses with education and culture in each federative unit, ln(Gec), as a control variable. The data were also collected from IPEA and, from the year 2010 on, they were complemented by data from Compara Brasil, a free access portal with data on public finances of Brazil. These values were as well deflated by the IPCA for the base year of 2010.

The dependent variable, i.e., the natural logarithm of per capita output, ln(y), is represented by the level of gross domestic product (GDP) of the Brazilian states divided by the economically active population (EAP). The GDP was collected from the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE) and deflated by the implicit GDP deflator, for 2010 values; the EAP was extracted from the PNAD and supplemented for the remaining years 2000 and 2010 by the average between the previous and the subsequent years. The growth rate of per capita physical capital, txk, was obtained from the product between the share of the states in the Brazilian GDP and the gross capital formation aggregate data for Brazil, collected from IBGE and deflated by the IPCA for the base year of 2010, divided by the EAP.

Considering that the PNAD had its geographic coverage increased gradually until covering the whole Brazilian territory from the year 2004 on, during the period between 1996 to 2003, and therefore, during part of the temporal cut of this work, PNAD did not include the rural population of Rondônia, Acre, Amazonas, Roraima, Pará and Amapá. As a result, we use the population data provided by IBGE to calculate the population growth rate (Popgr). Missing data for higher education graduates’ income for the state of Amapá in 1996 and 1997 and Roraima for 1999 were estimated using time series with exponential smoothing. Finally, data for the number of elementary school teachers (Nº Prof. Bh) and higher education teachers (Nº Prof. Ah), extracted from the reports of the National Institute of Studies and Educational Research Anísio Teixeira (INEP), are used as additional exogenous instruments.

We use a panel for the 27 federative units, being 26 states and one federal district. Additionally, we control for the macroeconomic shocks with a dummy variable for crisis.

As for the descriptive statistics, we point out that the level of human capital proxies represents the total factor productivity channel, and that the growth rates (Tx) represent the factor accumulation channel (Table 2).

Table 2
Descriptive statistics.

4. Results

Table 3 presents nine estimates to assess by which channels, and to what magnitude, human capital affects economic growth in Brazil. Estimates from (1) to (3) use wages based on the education of the graduates of elementary school, high school and higher education (HC) as a proxy for human capital. Equation (1) tests the contribution of the factor accumulation channel; equation (2) tests the total factor productivity channel; and equation (3) tests both channels simultaneously. Subsequently, in equations (4) to (6), the human capital is disaggregated into basic and advanced. Equation (4) tests the effect of basic human capital through the factor accumulation channel; equation (5) tests the effect of advanced human capital by the total factor productivity channel and equation (6) tests the two measures simultaneously. For the last group of analysis, from equations (7) to (9), we reverse the previous logic, so that we test the effect of advanced human capital through the factor accumulation channel (equation (7)), the effect of basic human capital through the total factor productivity channel (equation (8)) and the two channels simultaneously (equation (9)). In every regression, we use the two-step system-GMM method with Windmeijer’s (2005)Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25-51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004...
robust standard error, and PCA to control for the proliferation of the instruments (Mehrhoff, 2009Mehrhoff, J. (2009). A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM (Discussion Paper No. 31/2009). Frankfurt am Main. https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/...
; Kapetanios & Marcellino, 2010Kapetanios, G., & Marcellino, M. (2010). Factor-GMM estimation with large sets of possibly weak instruments. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 54(11), 2655-2675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04.008
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04....
; Bai & Ng, 2010Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2010). Instrumental variable estimation in a data rich environment. Econometric Theory, 26(6), 1577-1606. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990727
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990...
).

Table 3
Two-step System-GMM with PCA.

In general terms, to check the quality of the model’s fit we have to analyze Hansen’s J-statistic specification tests, Arellano-Bond test for first-order and second-order autocorrelation and the Kaiser-Lawyer-Olkin measuring of sample adequacy (KMO). The Hansen test results do not reject the null hypothesis that the instruments are valid for all the specifications used (>0.05 for all estimates). As for the Arellano-Bond test for autocorrelation, the results reject the null hypothesis of the absence of first order autocorrelation (<0.00 for all estimates) and do not reject the null hypothesis of the absence of second order autocorrelation (>0.05 for all estimates), indicating that the instruments are valid and are not correlated with the error term for all specifications. Finally, the Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin (KMO) measure of sample adequacy for PCA shows values higher than 0.5. That is, we have confidence that the factor analysis used is adequately adjusted to the data. In short, the tests indicate good specification quality.

The estimation of the lagged level of output per capita (transitional convergence component) complements the correct specification of the dynamic panel data models. For all regressions, the estimated coefficients of ln(yt-1) are negative and significant at the 1 % level of confidence. Thus, as expected, the growth rate depends on the initial position of the economy. In other words, all things equal, poor countries should growth at a higher rate than the rich ones.

Regarding the results of the variables of interest (human capital measures), it is possible to infer that aggregate human capital was statistically significant, at the 5% confidence level, for both channels individually (estimates 1 and 2), showing greater magnitude through the total factor productivity channel. However, only the total factor productivity channel was statistically significant when we considered both channels simultaneously (estimation 3). Therefore, these first results already indicate that the total factor productivity channel plays an important role in explaining economic growth in Brazil. We must stress that the direct effect of human capital on economic growth through the total factor productivity channel is approximately 0.08%, that is, a 1% increase in the human capital measure generates a direct increase of 0.08% of GDP, corroborating with the results for states and municipalities of Brazil (Salgueiro, 2012Salgueiro, A. d. S. (2012). O papel do capital humano, spillovers e difusão tecnológica no crescimento: Uma análise espacial para Brasil (Dissertação de Mestrado). Universidade Federal do Paraná, Curitiba, PR.; Fraga, 2011Fraga, G. J. (2011). Estudo da relação entre comércio internacional, capital humano e crescimento econômico no Brasil no período de 1995 a 2006 (Tese de Doutorado, Universidade de São Paulo, Piracicaba, SP). http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/T.11.2011.tde-02082011-103009
http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/T.11.2011.tde...
; Salgueiro et al., 2011Salgueiro, A. d. S., Nakabashi, L., & De Prince, D. (2011). O papel do capital humano no crescimento: Uma análise espacial para o Brasil. Revista Economia & Tecnologia, 7(4). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911
http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911...
; Firme & Simao Filho, 2014Firme, V. d. A. C., &Simão Filho, J. (2014). Análise do crescimento econômico dos municípios de Minas Gerais via modelo MRW (1992) com capital humano, condições de saúde e fatores espaciais, 1991-2000. Economia Aplicada, 18(4), 679-716. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1413-8050/ea640
http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1413-8050/ea64...
; Irffi et al., 2016Irffi, G., Arruda, E., Bastos, F., & Barboza, D. (2016). Impactos da abertura comercial e contribuição dos diferenciais de escolaridade sobre o nível de renda dos municípios cearenses, no período 1997-2005. Ensaios FEE, 37(1), 217-254. https://revistas.fee.tche.br/index.php/ensaios/article/view/3004
https://revistas.fee.tche.br/index.php/e...
).

Deepening the analysis, we propose the use of measures of human capital denominated “wages based on the disaggregated education of the graduates”, that is to say, basic education, for the average wages of the graduating students of primary and secondary school (HC_bh) and advanced education, for the average of wages of the graduating students of higher education (HC_ah). The first variable is a suitable proxy for measuring the factor accumulation channel, since the basic human capital proxy is related to average labor productivity and the second, in turn, for measuring the total factor productivity channel, since the advanced human capital proxy is related to labor intensive human capital, which is specific and linked to the development of technology. Then, considering these disaggregated measures, the results show that the total factor productivity channel affects Brazilian growth at the 1% of significance level. This corroborates our earlier results. In addition, it should be noted that the direct effect of a 1% increase in the level of advanced human capital, through the total factor productivity, is also an increase of approximately 0.08% in GDP (estimation 5). Also, once again only the total factor productivity channel was statistically significant when we considered both channels simultaneously (estimation 6).

Finally, we propose the use of basic human capital and advanced human capital proxies in reverse. The idea is to test both the robustness of the total factor productivity channel and to analyze the relative importance of basic human capital. Then, the total factor productivity channel remains robust (regressions 8 and 9), that is, it is significant to at the 5% confidence level, presenting the same signal and slightly higher magnitude than previously found.

With respect to the covariates, in all specifications the growth rate of the stock of physical capital was positive and statistically significant at the 1 % significance level, as predicted by the theoretical model. In terms of the magnitude of the coefficients, the relative importance of physical capital for Brazilian economic growth becomes clear. The results agree with ones of previous works (Cangussu et al., 2010Cangussu, R. C., Salvato, M. A., & Nakabashi, L. (2010). Uma análise do capital humano sobre o nível de renda dos estados brasileiros: MRW versus Mincer. Estudos Econômicos, 40(1), 153-183. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/S0101-41612010000100006
http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/S0101-41612010...
; Salgueiro et al., 2011Salgueiro, A. d. S., Nakabashi, L., & De Prince, D. (2011). O papel do capital humano no crescimento: Uma análise espacial para o Brasil. Revista Economia & Tecnologia, 7(4). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911
http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911...
; Gama, 2014Gama, V. A. (2014). Os efeitos da qualidade da educação sobre a acumulação de capital humano e o crescimento econômico no Brasil (Tese de Doutorado, Universidade de São Paulo, Piracicaba, SP). http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/X11.2014.tde-03062014-153434
http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/X11.2014.tde-...
; Bondezan & Dias, 2016Bondezan, K. d. L., &Dias, J. (2016). Crescimento econômico no Brasil: Uma abordagem sobre o papel da acumulação de capital físico e humano. Revista de Economia, 42(3). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/re.v42i3.51619
http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/re.v42i3.51619...
). The expenses with education and culture variable, ln(Gec), was statistically significant and positive for all specifications. This result shows that regional investments in education and culture also have an effect on economic growth. The population growth variable did not present statistical significance, except in the estimation (1). The variable for the controlling for macroeconomic shocks due to crises had a negative coefficient, as expected, and was statistically significant at the 10% confidence level, except for estimates (7) and (9). Finally, the trend variable had a coefficient close to zero in all the estimates, being significant to at the 1% confidence level in estimates (1), (4), and (7).

In sum, the results indicate that total factor productivity is the most important channel for the growth process of the Brazilian states, and that education and culture spending also have a positive impact on growth. Regarding the hypotheses raised in this research, we can highlight the importance of the total factor productivity channel as an important driving force for the economic growth of the Brazilian states.

Another important characteristic of the estimation through dynamic panel models is the possibility of estimating the long-term effects of human capital on economic growth. Thus, Table 4 presents the long-term effects.

Table 4
Long-term effects.

In general terms, the long-term effects follow the same relative relationships as those previously found. That is, human capital affects economic growth through the total factor productivity channel, while the factor accumulation channel remains without statistical effect for most specifications, except for regression (1).

The long-term effect amplifies the direct effect found, insofar as the conditions of the state of the economy in the previous period are considered by the dynamic term. In this way, it can be observed that the human capital long-term coefficient for the regressions that analyze the total factor productivity channel are statistically significant at the 1% confidence level in equations (2), (5) and (8). In equation (2), we have that a 1% increase in the level of human capital results in a 0.18% increase in long-term economic growth for the Brazilian economy. In the fifth equation, when we deepen this analysis and consider the measure of advanced human capital the long-term effect remains at approximately 0.17%. Finally, in the analysis of channel robustness, we have that the long-term effect is approximately 0.18% at the 1 % level of significance.

In sum, the results show that the total factor productivity channel is crucial for formulating economic policies in Brazil.

5. Robustness analysis

In this section we put the results to the test by considering different econometric specifications, in order to verify if the results previously found are robust. In this way, we propose three different specifications for controlling the proliferation of the number of instruments in the two-step system-GMM. First, we consider the limits of the lags along with the collapsed instruments (Table 5). Then, we relax the specifications, considering only the limits of the lags (Table 6). And, finally, we consider only the collapsed instruments (Table 7).

Table 5
Two-Step System-GMM with laglimits and collapse.
Table 6
Two-Step System-GMM with laglimits.
Table 7
Two-Step System-GMM with collapse.

According to Bontempi and Mammi (2012)Bontempi, M. E., & Mammi, I. (2012, September). A strategy to reduce the count of moment conditions in panel data GMM (Quaderni - Working Paper No. 843). DSE. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2140799
http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2140799...
the collapse of the instruments’ method and depth truncation of the lags involve a certain degree of arbitrariness, so that there must be confidence in the restrictions imposed by the researcher. When the instrument matrix is collapsed, specific dynamics are assumed in the data; when we apply the method of depth truncation of the lags, the number of lags that must be included among the instruments are chosen, assuming that the relevant information is transmitted only by the considered lags of the endogenous variables. Therefore, in this robustness analysis we continue with the two-step system-GMM estimator, but we define the collapsed internal instruments and limit the number of lags of the endogenous variables in lag (2 10) by total factor productivity channel and in lag (2 6) by the the factor accumulation channel.

The results reported in tables 5, 6 and 7 corroborate the effect of human capital on Brazilian economic growth. In most of the estimates, the coefficients related to human capital remained significant, presenting magnitudes close to those found through the PCA model. The proportion of effects follows the same logic as previous results, that is, aggregate human capital (HC) affects Brazilian economic growth through the two individually tested channels. With regard to disaggregated human capital, the results show that advanced education’s estimated coefficient was positive and statistically significant by the total factor productivity channel, corroborating its importance. Basic education, however, was also statistically significant only by the total factor productivity channel. The transitional convergence component variable is also statistically significant in all estimates for the three strategies considered.

Even though the variables of interest’s coefficients have presented both direction and magnitude similar to those found previously, we must check the quality of the adjustment in the three strategies in the robustness analysis. So, first, we have to analyze Hansen’s J-statistic specification tests and the Arellano-Bond first-order and second-order tests for autocorrelation. For the first strategy Table 5, the results of Hansen’s test do not reject the null hypothesis that the instruments are valid for all of the specifications used (value >0.05). As for the Arellano-Bond tests for autocorrelation, the results reject the null hypothesis of the absence of first order autocorrelation (<0.001 for all estimates) and do not reject the null hypothesis of the absence of second order autocorrelation (>5 for all estimates), indicating that the instruments are valid and that they are not correlated with the error term for all specifications.

Except for the PCA model, the Difference in Hansen test is available for all other estimates, which has as null hypothesis that the additional instruments are valid. The results show that we can accept the null hypothesis. Thus, the models in Table 5 indicate good specification quality. When analyzing the quality of the specification of the strategies of tables 6 and 7, some distrust about the validity of the instruments arises, due to proliferation of instruments. Since the Hansen tests are sensitive to the proliferation of instruments, the confidence in the quality of the estimates in tables 6 and 7 is lost. Thus, the estimates in tables 6 and 7 are not of satisfactory quality and cannot be considered.

The results of this section are relevant because they reinforce the results previously found, since the total factor productivity channel was statistically significant in most specifications, even if we do not have confidence about the correct identification of the coefficient associated with human capital. That is, as the proliferation of instruments is a serious issue for the System-GMM estimator, we should expect that relaxing the instruments’ control would cause a reduction in the quality of the estimates, especially in the models of tables 6 and 7. In addition, it should be emphasized that the model of Table 5 is very well adjusted and comparable to the model proposed by the research. However, the model with PCA is considered superior, since, in addition to greater efficiency, it represents a minimally arbitrary way of limiting the counting of the instruments, minimizing the loss of information and making it possible to maintain a set of major components with higher eigenvalues (Bai & Ng, 2010Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2010). Instrumental variable estimation in a data rich environment. Econometric Theory, 26(6), 1577-1606. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990727
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990...
; Kapetanios & Marcellino, 2010Kapetanios, G., & Marcellino, M. (2010). Factor-GMM estimation with large sets of possibly weak instruments. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 54(11), 2655-2675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04.008
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04....
; Mehrhoff, 2009Mehrhoff, J. (2009). A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM (Discussion Paper No. 31/2009). Frankfurt am Main. https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/...
).

6. Conclusion

Based on a Solow growth model augmented with human capital, similar to those proposed by Lucas (1988)Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3-42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)9...
and Mankiw et al. (1992)Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. N. (1992). A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 407-437. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118477
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118477...
and the contributions of Nelson and Phelps (1966)Nelson, R. R., & Phelps, E. S. (1966). Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. The American Economic Review, 56(1/2), 69-75. http://dx.doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/stable/1821269
http://dx.doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/...
, the main goal of this study was to investigate through which channels human capital affected Brazil’s economic growth, from 1996 to 2015. The following hypotheses were tested: human capital-both aggregated and disaggregated at basic and advanced levels-affects growth through (i) the factor accumulation channel; (ii) the total factor productivity channel; or (iii) both channels simultaneously.

This paper contributes to the national debate, as it proposes new proxies for human capital stocks, related to formal education returns, experience and workplace training, measures that are not affected by the main shortcomings of the ones already proposed by the literature, such as those related to school dropout and failure rates, and labor productivity aspects (Barro & Lee, 1993Barro, R. J., & Lee, J.-W (1993). International comparisons of educational attainment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 363-394. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)90023-9
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)9...
; Mulligan & Sala-i-Martin, 1993Mulligan, C. B., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1993). Transitional dynamics in two-sector models of endogenous growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 739-773. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118407
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118407...
).

For the empirical analysis, we used the two-step system-GMM method (Arellano & Bover, 1995Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components model. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29-52. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)0...
; Blundell & Bond, 1998Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamicpanel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)...
), with Windmeijer’s (2005)Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25-51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004...
finite sample standard errors’ correction and principal component analysis (PCA) for controlling the proliferation of instruments (Mehrhoff, 2009Mehrhoff, J. (2009). A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM (Discussion Paper No. 31/2009). Frankfurt am Main. https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/...
; Kapetanios & Marcellino, 2010Kapetanios, G., & Marcellino, M. (2010). Factor-GMM estimation with large sets of possibly weak instruments. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 54(11), 2655-2675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04.008
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04....
; Bai & Ng, 2010Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2010). Instrumental variable estimation in a data rich environment. Econometric Theory, 26(6), 1577-1606. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990727
http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990...
). As a test of the results’ robustness, we control the proliferation of the instruments through the laglimit and collapse methods.

The results showed that aggregate human capital, through both channels individually considered, affects economic growth. Regarding the measures of human capital disaggregated at basic and advanced levels, economic growth is affected only via the total factor productivity channel. With regard to the magnitudes of the estimated coefficients, we should emphasize those related to human capital at the basic level, which were significant and always produced a higher impact than those related to advanced human capital. In summary, the results found in this study, although using different data and methods, are close to those already known from the literature.

Based on the above results, we recommend that public policies aimed at promoting economic growth from higher levels of human capital be stimulated and, if there is a need for an allocative choice for resources involving distinct educational stages, that priority be given to those related to human capital at the basic level.

  • 1
    This section is based on D. Romer and Chow (1996)Romer, D., &Chow, C. (1996). Advanced macroeconomic theory. Mcgraw-Hill. and Li and Wang (2018)Li, T., & Wang, Y. (2018). Growth channels of human capital: A Chinese panel data study. China Economic Review, 51, 309-322. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxhieco.2016.11.002
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxhieco.2016.1...
    .
  • 2
    Similar to the estimated equation in Benhabib and Spiegel (1994)Benhabib, J., & Spiegel, M. M. (1994). The role of human capital in economic development evidence from aggregate cross-country data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 34(2), 143-173. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(94)90047-7
    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(94)9...
    .
  • 3
    We control for the Asian Giants’ crisis (1997), the Ruble crisis (1998), the Argentine debt crisis (2001-2002) and the global financial crisis (2008-2010).
  • 4
    See Bond, Hoeffler, and Temple (2001)Bond, S., Hoeffler, A., & Temple, J. (2001). GMM estimation of empirical growth models..
  • 5
    The objective of dividing the monthly income by the minimum wage amount is to expunge the income variation determined by law.

References

  • Arellano, M., & Bond, S. (1991). Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies, 58(2), 277-297. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2297968
  • Arellano, M., & Bover, O. (1995). Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components model. Journal of Econometrics, 68(1), 29-52. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-4076(94)01642-D
  • Bai, J., & Ng, S. (2010). Instrumental variable estimation in a data rich environment. Econometric Theory, 26(6), 1577-1606. http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990727
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/S0266466609990727
  • Barro, R. J. (1991). Economic growth in a cross section of countries. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2), 407-443. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2937943
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2937943
  • Barro, R. J., & Lee, J.-W (1993). International comparisons of educational attainment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 32(3), 363-394. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)90023-9
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(93)90023-9
  • Barro, R. J., & Lee, J. W (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950-2010. Journal of Development Economics, 104,184-198. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.j deveco.2012.10.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.j deveco.2012.10.001
  • Bayraktar-Saglam, B. (2016). The stages of human capital and economic growth: Does the direction of causality matter for the rich and the poor? Social Indicators Research, 127 (1), 243-302. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-0963-0
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11205-015-0963-0
  • Becker, G. S., Murphy, K. M., & Tamura, R. (1990). Human capital, fertility, and economic growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5, Part 2), S12-S37. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261723
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261723
  • Benhabib, J., & Spiegel, M. M. (1992). The role of human capital and political instability in economic development
  • Benhabib, J., & Spiegel, M. M. (1994). The role of human capital in economic development evidence from aggregate cross-country data. Journal of Monetary Economics, 34(2), 143-173. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(94)90047-7
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(94)90047-7
  • Blundell, R., & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamicpanel data models. Journal of Econometrics, 87(1), 115-143. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-4076(98)00009-8
  • Bond, S., Hoeffler, A., & Temple, J. (2001). GMM estimation of empirical growth models
  • Bondezan, K. d. L., &Dias, J. (2016). Crescimento econômico no Brasil: Uma abordagem sobre o papel da acumulação de capital físico e humano. Revista de Economia, 42(3). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/re.v42i3.51619
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/re.v42i3.51619
  • Bontempi, M. E., & Mammi, I. (2012, September). A strategy to reduce the count of moment conditions in panel data GMM (Quaderni - Working Paper No. 843). DSE. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2140799
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2140799
  • Cangussu, R. C., Salvato, M. A., & Nakabashi, L. (2010). Uma análise do capital humano sobre o nível de renda dos estados brasileiros: MRW versus Mincer. Estudos Econômicos, 40(1), 153-183. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/S0101-41612010000100006
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/S0101-41612010000100006
  • Castelló-Climent, A., & Mukhopadhyay, A. (2013). Mass education or a minority well educated elite in the process of growth: The case of India. Journal of Development Economics, 105, 303-320. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.03.012
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2013.03.012
  • Cunha, A. F., & Nunes, S. F. (2016). Educação e crescimento econômico: Análise dos municípios da região dos Campos Gerais do Paraná. Revista de Ensino, Educação e Ciências Humanas, 17(3), 232-239. http://dx.doi.org/10.17921/2447-8733.2016v17n3p232-239
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.17921/2447-8733.2016v17n3p232-239
  • Firme, V. d. A. C., &Simão Filho, J. (2014). Análise do crescimento econômico dos municípios de Minas Gerais via modelo MRW (1992) com capital humano, condições de saúde e fatores espaciais, 1991-2000. Economia Aplicada, 18(4), 679-716. http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1413-8050/ea640
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1590/1413-8050/ea640
  • Fraga, G. J. (2011). Estudo da relação entre comércio internacional, capital humano e crescimento econômico no Brasil no período de 1995 a 2006 (Tese de Doutorado, Universidade de São Paulo, Piracicaba, SP). http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/T.11.2011.tde-02082011-103009
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/T.11.2011.tde-02082011-103009
  • Fully, R. M. P., & Teixeira, A. (2016). Os efeitos da educação sobre o progresso tecnológico no Brasil. Gestão e Sociedade, 10(25), 1274-1283. http://dx.doi.org/10.21171/ges.v10i25.1978
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.21171/ges.v10i25.1978
  • Gama, V. A. (2014). Os efeitos da qualidade da educação sobre a acumulação de capital humano e o crescimento econômico no Brasil (Tese de Doutorado, Universidade de São Paulo, Piracicaba, SP). http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/X11.2014.tde-03062014-153434
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.11606/X11.2014.tde-03062014-153434
  • Garofalo, G. A., & Yamarik, S. (2002). Regional convergence: Evidence from a new state-by-state capital stock series. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 84(2), 316-323. http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/003465302317411569
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1162/003465302317411569
  • Guimarães, A. A. B., Fully, R. M. P., & Silveira, L. P. (2017). Análise do capital humano, sob a ótica da teoria do crescimento endógeno, na produtividade total dos fatores no Brasil. Revista Eletrônica Gestão e Serviços, 8(1), 1902-1918. http://dx.doi.org/10.15603/2177-7284/regs.v8n1p1902-1918
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.15603/2177-7284/regs.v8n1p1902-1918
  • Hansen, L. P. (1982). Large sample properties of generalized method of moments estimators. Econometrica, 50(4), 1029-1054. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1912775
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1912775
  • Irffi, G., Arruda, E., Bastos, F., & Barboza, D. (2016). Impactos da abertura comercial e contribuição dos diferenciais de escolaridade sobre o nível de renda dos municípios cearenses, no período 1997-2005. Ensaios FEE, 37(1), 217-254. https://revistas.fee.tche.br/index.php/ensaios/article/view/3004
    » https://revistas.fee.tche.br/index.php/ensaios/article/view/3004
  • Jameel, S., & Naeem, M. Z. (2016). Impact of human capital on economic growth: A panel study. Bulletin of Business and Economics, 5(4), 231-248. https://ideas.repec.org/aZrfh/bbejor/v5y2016i4p231-248.html
    » https://ideas.repec.org/aZrfh/bbejor/v5y2016i4p231-248.html
  • Kapetanios, G., & Marcellino, M. (2010). Factor-GMM estimation with large sets of possibly weak instruments. Computational Statistics & Data Analysis, 54(11), 2655-2675. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04.008
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxsda.2010.04.008
  • Kazmi, S. M., Ali, K., & Ali, G. (2017). Impact of human capital on economic growth: Evidence from Pakistan http://hdl.handle.net/11540/7744
    » http://hdl.handle.net/11540/7744
  • Kyriacou, G. A. (1991). Level andgrowth effects of human capital: A cross-country study of the convergence hypothesis (Working Paper No. 91-26). New York, NY: C.V. Starr Center for Applied Economics.
  • Labra, R., & Torrecillas, C. (2014). Guía CERO para datos de panel: Un enfoque práctico (Working Paper No. 2014/16). Madrid: UAM-Accenture.
  • Li, T., & Wang, Y. (2018). Growth channels of human capital: A Chinese panel data study. China Economic Review, 51, 309-322. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxhieco.2016.11.002
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/jxhieco.2016.11.002
  • Lillo, R. L., & Torrecillas, C. (2018). Estimating dynamic panel data: A practical approach to perform long panels. Revista Colombiana de Estadística, 41(1), 31-52. http://dx.doi.org/10.15446/rce.v41n1.61885
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.15446/rce.v41n1.61885
  • Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3-42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7
  • Mankiw, N. G., Romer, D., & Weil, D. N. (1992). A contribution to the empirics of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 107(2), 407-437. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118477
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118477
  • Mehrhoff, J. (2009). A solution to the problem of too many instruments in dynamic panel data GMM (Discussion Paper No. 31/2009). Frankfurt am Main. https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
    » https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/703532/0f974326445ac974f525b0e277c7bc6b/mL/2009-11-06-dkp-31-data.pdf
  • Mincer, J. (1974). Schooling, experience, andearnings National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). https://www.nber.org/books/minc74-1
    » https://www.nber.org/books/minc74-1
  • Moreira, É. T. (2014). Impactos da tecnologia e do capital humano sobre o crescimento econômico asiático: Uma abordagem via dados de painel. Revista Teoria e Evidência Econômica, 20(43), 213-237. http://dx.doi.org/10.5335/rtee.v20i43.4591
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.5335/rtee.v20i43.4591
  • Mulligan, C. B., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1993). Transitional dynamics in two-sector models of endogenous growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3), 739-773. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118407
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2118407
  • Nelson, R. R., & Phelps, E. S. (1966). Investment in humans, technological diffusion, and economic growth. The American Economic Review, 56(1/2), 69-75. http://dx.doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/stable/1821269
    » http://dx.doi.org/https://www.jstor.org/stable/1821269
  • Ogundari, K., & Awokuse, T. (2018). Human capital contribution to economicgrowth in Sub-Saharan Africa: Does health status matter more than education? Economic Analysis and Policy, 58,131-140. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2018.02.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.eap.2018.02.001
  • Pelinescu, E. (2015). The impact of human capital on economic growth. Procedia Economics and Finance, 22,184-190. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(15)00258-0
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S2212-5671(15)00258-0
  • Romer, D., &Chow, C. (1996). Advanced macroeconomic theory Mcgraw-Hill.
  • Romer, P. M. (1990). Human capital and growth: Theory and evidence. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 32,251-286. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0167-2231(90)90028
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0167-2231(90)90028
  • J Roodman, D. (2009a). How to do Xtabond2: An introduction to Difference and System GMM in Stata (No. 9). http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0900900106
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/1536867X0900900106
  • Roodman, D. (2009b). A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 71(1), 135-158. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00542.x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.2008.00542.x
  • Sala-i-Martin, X., & Mulligan, C. B. (1995, January). Measuring aggregate human capital (Center Discussion Paper No. 723). New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University. http://www.econ.yale.edu/growth_pdf/cdp723.pdf
    » http://www.econ.yale.edu/growth_pdf/cdp723.pdf
  • Salgueiro, A. d. S. (2012). O papel do capital humano, spillovers e difusão tecnológica no crescimento: Uma análise espacial para Brasil (Dissertação de Mestrado). Universidade Federal do Paraná, Curitiba, PR.
  • Salgueiro, A. d. S., Nakabashi, L., & De Prince, D. (2011). O papel do capital humano no crescimento: Uma análise espacial para o Brasil. Revista Economia & Tecnologia, 7(4). http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.5380/ret.v7i4.25911
  • Sargan, J. D. (1958). The estimation of economic relationships using instrumental variables. Econometrica, 26(3), 393-415. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1907619
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1907619
  • Silva, I. d., & Sumarto, S. (2015). Dynamics of growth, poverty and human capital: Evidence from Indonesian sub-national data. Journal of Economic Development, 40(2). http://www.jed.or.kr/full-text/40-2/1.pdf
    » http://www.jed.or.kr/full-text/40-2/1.pdf
  • Teixeira, A. A. C., & Queirós, A. S. S. (2016). Economic growth, human capital and structural change: A dynamic panel data analysis. Research Policy, 45(8), 1636-1648. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.04.006
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.04.006
  • Windmeijer, F. (2005). A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. Journal of Econometrics, 126(1), 25-51. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2004.02.005

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    08 May 2020
  • Date of issue
    Jan-Mar 2020

History

  • Received
    22 Nov 2018
  • Accepted
    19 Aug 2019
Fundação Getúlio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 11º andar, 22253-900 Rio de Janeiro RJ Brazil, Tel.: +55 21 3799-5831 , Fax: +55 21 2553-8821 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: rbe@fgv.br