Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Assessment of potential and use of the IPTU tax, based on the fuzzy set theory

Abstract

This article proposes a comparative analysis among Brazilian municipalities in order to identify the determinants of the potential and of the ability to collect urban property tax (IPTU) in Brazil. The analysis applied the fuzzy set theory, a pioneer methodological choice in the field of public finances in Brazil, which has provided unprecedented results in terms of property taxation. The results confirmed what analysts and municipal leaders have pointed out for a long time: the majority of Brazilian municipalities do not use their full potential to collect the IPTU — a fact that tends to be more critical in smaller cities, which depend on funding from other spheres of Government. The article breaks new ground in assessing this potential based on a comparative analysis of cities with similar characteristics.

Keywords:
taxation; municipal finance; fuzzy analysis; property tax.

Resumo

A fim de identificar os determinantes do potencial de arrecadação do imposto sobre propriedade predial e territorial urbana (IPTU) no Brasil, bem como a utilização dessa capacidade, este artigo propõe uma análise comparativa dos municípios brasileiros aplicando a teoria dos conjuntos fuzzy. A aplicação dessa metodologia na área das finanças públicas é pioneira no Brasil, o que proporcionou resultados inéditos em matéria de tributação da propriedade. Os resultados confirmaram o que analistas e até mesmo dirigentes municipais já apontaram há tempos: a maioria dos municípios brasileiros não utiliza todo o seu potencial de arrecadação do IPTU - fato que tende a ser mais crítico nas cidades de menor porte e que dependem mais de recursos de outras esferas de governo. O artigo inova ao mensurar esse potencial a partir de uma análise comparativa entre cidades com semelhantes características.

Palavras-chave:
tributação; finanças municipais; análise fuzzy; imposto sobre propriedade.

Resumen

Con el fin de identificar los determinantes del potencial de la colección de impuesto sobre bienes inmuebles y territorial urbano en Brasil, así como la exploración de tal capacidad, este artículo propone un análisis comparativo de los municipios brasileños mediante la aplicación de la teoría de conjuntos fuzzy. La aplicación de esta metodología en el área de las finanzas públicas es pionera en Brasil, e ha dado resultados sin precedentes sobre los impuestos de propiedad. Los resultados confirmaron lo que los analistas y líderes municipales incluso han señalado hace algún tiempo: la mayoría de los municipios brasileños no utiliza todo su potencial para recaudar IPTU - hecho que tiende a ser más crítico en ciudades más pequeñas y que dependen de fondos desde otras esferas del gobierno. Este artículo innova para medir este potencial basado en un análisis comparativo de las ciudades con características similares.

Palabras clave:
impuestos; finanzas municipales; análisis fuzzy; impuesto a la propriedad.

1. Introduction

In Brazil, the Urban Property Tax (IPTU) — which is a municipal jurisdiction — is currently going through many challenges. The amount collected sums around R$ 25 billion/year, which in 2014 represented 0.51% of Brazilian GDP (RFB, 2015RECEITA FEDERAL DO BRASIL. Carga tributária no Brasil 2014: análise por tributos e bases de incidência. Brasília: RFB/CETAD. out. 2015. Disponível em: <Disponível em: https://www.idg.receita.fazenda.gov.br/dados/receitadata/estudos-e-tributarios-e-aduaneiros/estudos-e-estatisticas/carga-tributaria-no-brasil/29-10-2015-carga-tributaria-2014 >. Acesso em: 4 jul. 2017.
https://www.idg.receita.fazenda.gov.br/d...
).

Although it accounts for approximately 1.5% of national tax revenue, IPTU is the second most rejected tax by Brazilians, according to a public opinion poll on national taxes and problems. It is not rare for municipalities to be rejected in court when trying to adjust the tax — as was the case of the largest city in the country, São Paulo, which led to a series of inquiries in other cities.1 1 An important decision on the subject was rendered on 12/18/2013 by the STJ (Superior Court of Justice). Judiciary discussions have generated great repercussions in the media and summed to the widespread criticisms toward the tax as well as to complaints against other actions of public administration, not necessarily related to taxes.

Contrary to the feelings of civil society, preliminary technical analysis evidence that IPTU collection would be too low in most of the national territory (De Cesare and Marín, 2008DE CESARE, Claudia M.; MARÍN, José Francsico L. Impuestos a los patrimonios en América Latina. Macroeconomía del Desarrollo, n. 66, 2008. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/handle/11362/5433/1/S0800387_es.pdf >. Acesso em: 4 jul. 2017.
http://www.repositorio.cepal.org/bitstre...
; Bahl, 2009BAHL, Roy. Property tax reform in developing and transition countries. Washington: Usaid, 2009. Disponível em: < Disponível em: http://www.pdf.usaid.gov/pdf_docs/Pnadw480.pdf >. Acesso em: 4 jul. 2017.
http://www.pdf.usaid.gov/pdf_docs/Pnadw4...
; Sepulveda and Vazquez 2009SEPULVEDA, Cristian; VAZQUES, Jorge M. Property taxation in Latin-America: an assessment and options for reform. The Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (Eclac). Relaciones intergubernamentales y descentralizaciónen América Latina. Santiago de Chile, nov. 2009. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.researchgate.net/profile/Jorge_Martinez-Vazquez/publication/265541538_Property_Taxation_in_Latin-America_An_Assessment_and_Options_for_Reform/links/5525380c0cf201667be64544.pdf >. Acesso em: 20 nov. 2015.
http://www.researchgate.net/profile/Jorg...
; Afonso, Araújo and Nóbrega, 2012AFONSO, José Roberto; ARAÚJO, Érika A.; NÓBREGA, Marcos A. R. The urban property tax (IPTU) in Brazil: an analysis of the use of the property tax as a revenue source by Brazilian municipalities. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Working Paper, 2012. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/dl/2285_1624_Afonso_WP13JA2.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
http://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/dl/2285_...
), regardless of region, size, type or local economy.

Initial estimates indicate that, for all municipalities in the country, revenues from IPTU accounted for approximately 19.4% of total tax revenue in 2014. Fifteen years earlier, in 2000, this participation was 27%. However, the national average was not the reality observed in most municipalities: in approximately half of them, IPTU did not reach 10% of the municipalities’ total self-generated revenue.

Other evidence on the low use of the potential of IPTU can be observed in comparison with other taxes. A little more than 96% of the Brazilian municipalities had an estimated tax collection on Vehicle Property Tax (IPVA) higher than that of IPTU in 2014. The relation obtained between IPTU and the Tax on Service Provided (ISS), and IPTU and Real Estate Transfer Tax (ITBI) was, respectively, 87.7% and 45.9% in the same year. This latter fact draws much attention, since ITBI should be residual to IPTU. Yet, even a state capital (João Pessoa, PB) collected more ITBI than IPTU.

In this context, it is worth questioning if there is potential for IPTU collection and whether this potential is actually used by Brazilian municipalities. In addition, which municipalities in the country best use their ability to collect IPTU.

In order to answer these questions and subsidize the debate on real estate taxes in Brazil — to identify opportunities and challenges for better use of IPTU as a source of financing the cities, considering it is a tax adopted in more than 5,500 Brazilian municipalities — this article evaluates the municipalities potential of IPTU collection, and their ability to collect IPTU. The diagnosis seeks to quantify and relativize several variables (tax and socioeconomic) that directly contribute to determine the potential of the tax, and the cities’ capacity to collect it.

Understanding the factors that contribute to the great diversity of municipalities in Brazil is fundamental for any evaluation on IPTU. The determining element of the fair use of this tax in a municipality may lie in explanations that go beyond simple political will. Among the factors that should be considered are the size of the economy, proximity to the population (voters), administrative deficiencies, legislation and low need to generate own resources. In a country characterized by deep disparities, there is no single explanation for the different levels of capacity to collect local taxes, and therefore, there is no single model to be followed in order to boost revenues in municipalities.

2. Methodology

The methodology adopted is grounded on the fuzzy set theory. This is a theory developed by Zadeh (1965ZADEH, Lotfy A. Fuzzy sets. Information and Control, v. 8, p. 338-353, 1965.) that aims at using “degrees of truth” in order to deal with situations in a mathematical way. Fuzzy functions assign real numbers, located in the interval between {0.1}, to truth degrees of statements — something which is neither definitely true (1) nor definitely false (0) could have an intermediate truth value (between 0 and 1).

This theory, like others from the broader set of the “degree of truth theories”, aims at formalizing situations (concepts, phenomena, statements) which are ambiguous and inaccurate. In time, it eventually attracted economists’ interest in quantifying poverty. There are plenty of Brazilian academic works that use this methodology to determine multidimensional poverty, inequality and human development (Chiappero-Martinetti, 2000CHIAPPERO-MARTINETTI, Enrica. A multidimensional assessment of well-being based on sen’s functioning approach. Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali, n. 2, p. 207-239, 2000.; Lelli, 2001LELLI, Sara. Factor analisys vs. fuzzy sets theory: assessing the influence of different techniques on Sen’s functioning approach. Center for Economic Studies, K. U. Leuven, 2001. Disponível em: <Disponível em: https://www.feb.kuleuven.be/eng/ew/discussionpapers/Dps01/Dps0121.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
https://www.feb.kuleuven.be/eng/ew/discu...
; Baliamoune-LutzBALIAMOUNE LUTZ, Mina. On the measurement of human well-being: fuzzy set theory and Sen’s capability approach. Tóquio: United Nations University: World Institute of Development Research, 2004. WIDER, Research Paper n. 2.004/16. Disponível em: <Disponível em: https://www.core.ac.uk/download/files/153/6483894.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
https://www.core.ac.uk/download/files/15...
, 2004; Lopes, 2003LOPES, Helger M. Análise de pobreza com indicadores multidimensionais: uma aplicação para Brasil e Minas Gerais. Dissertação (mestrado em economia) - Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento Regional, Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais, Belo Horizonte. 2003.; Fonseca, 2003FONSECA, Oswaldo L. H. Aplicação de métodos de análise espacial e da teoria dos conjuntos nebulosos em estudos sobre pobreza. Dissertação (mestrado em engenharia) - Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro, Rio de Janeiro, 2003.; Castro, Kerstenetzky and Del-Vecchio, 2010CASTRO, Kleber P.; KERSTENETZKY, Celia L; DEL-VECCHIO, Renata. Pobreza fuzzy multidimensional: uma análise das condições de vida na Zona Oeste do Rio de Janeiro - 1991 e 2000. In: SIMPÓSIO BRASILEIRO DE PESQUISA OPERACIONAL, 42., 2010, Bento Gonçalves. 2010 ). The application of this theory, in the case of poverty estimation, would be justified because poverty is an inexact phenomenon. Thus, such theory would allow classifying families in two categories: “poor” and “not poor”. This tool is commonly used in regional economic analyses in Brazil (Simões, 2003SIMÕES, Rodrigo F. Complexos industriais no espaço: uma análise de fuzzy cluster. Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento Regional. Texto para discussão, n. 209, Belo Horizonte, 2003. Disponível em: <http://www.cedeplar.ufmg.br/pesquisas/td/TD%20209.pdf>. Acesso em: 8 dez. 2015.
http://www.cedeplar.ufmg.br/pesquisas/td...
; Cechini et al., 2012CECHINI, Kerlyng et al. Brazilian automotive industry in the nineties. MPRAPaper, Munich, n. 41197, set. 2012. Disponível em: <Disponível em: https://www.mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/41197/1/MPRA_paper_41197.pdf >. Acesso em: 8 dez. 2015.
https://www.mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/4119...
), and can be easily adapted to this study.

Just as poverty, both the potential and the capacity to collect IPTU are imprecise phenomena. It is not feasible to point out a given municipality as capable or incapable of colleting a particular tax. What can be attributed to that municipality is an intermediate classification between full incapacity (0) and full capacity (1). The fuzzy set theory is used as a method for quantifying imprecise situations, and the imprecision of the studied phenomenon is recognized and made explicit. This is the case presented here.

The adoption of this tool is justified by a large number of theoretical references and practical applications. Moreover, its application in the field of public finance and taxation — at least in Brazil — may be considered pioneering, bringing innovation to studies on these issues.

2.1 Selected Indices

Taking into consideration the multidimensional characteristic of the evaluation presented here of the Urban Property Tax (IPTU), seven indicators derived from eight primary variables were chosen for the study. The variables were chosen in order to encompass aspects that are close to the actual budgetary situation of municipalities. They seek to capture three dimensions of local taxation: use of collected tax, potential of collection, and use of capacity. All data selected for fuzzy indices used in this study were extracted from three official sources: Annual reports on municipal finances released by the federal government (Finbra/STN); Population Estimate (IBGE); and Municipal Basic Information Profile (IBGE). All data were collected in 2014, except for the number of properties, which was obtained from the Demographic Census of 2010 (IBGE):

  1. . Primary variables
    1. . Population

    2. . Current Budgetary Revenue R$ (BRL)

    3. . Current Revenue from Taxes R$

    4. . Current IPTU collected R$

    5. . Current Transfer of IPVA R$

    6. . Current ITBI collected R$

    7. . Index of Municipalities Participation in ICMS (IMP)

    8. . Number of properties

  2. . Derived indicators
    1. . Current IPTU per capita R$

    2. . IPTU/Revenue

    3. . Current IPVA per capita R$

    4. . Current ITBI per capita R$

    5. . Tax revenue/Budgetary revenue (%)

    6. . Index of Municipalities Participation in ICMS (IMP)

    7. . Number of properties

In order to cover the three aforementioned dimensions to be used in this study (usage regarding the tax collection, potential of collection, and use of capacity), the derived indicators were used in a differentiated way. Therefore, three fuzzy indices were constructed in order to reach the dimensions. For the fuzzy index of the usage in terms of tax collection, only the derived indicators “a” (IPTU per capita) and “b” (IPTU/Revenue) were used. For the fuzzy index of potential of collection, the derived indicators “c” (IPVA per capita), “d” (ITBI per capita), “e” (Revenue from Taxes/Budgetary Revenue), “f” (IPM) and “g” (number of properties) were used. Finally, for the fuzzy index of use of the potential — which is a relation between fuzzy index of the usage and fuzzy index of potential of collection — all derived indicators were used.

The term “fuzzy index” is used in a more general way in this study because it is not only referring to the aforementioned dimensions, but also to indices that are individually constructed from each derived indicator. With this in mind and, in order to avoid any misunderstandings, the fuzzy indices used in this study are classified as “aggregate” because they encompass more than one variable. Therefore, they will be called: aggregate fuzzy index of usage, aggregate fuzzy index of potential and aggregate fuzzy index of use of capacity. In addition to these, other fuzzy indices are treated as “individuals” because they are calculated only for one variable. They are the fuzzy index of IPTU per capita, fuzzy index of IPTU/Budgetary Revenue, fuzzy index of IPVA per capita, fuzzy index of ITBI per capita, fuzzy index of Revenue from Taxes/Budgetary Revenue, fuzzy index of IPM and fuzzy index of the number of properties.

2.2 Selected municipalities and criteria to form groups

Considering the comprehensive nature of this study, all existing municipalities in Brazil in 2014 should have been included for analysis. However, the main data source — Finbra — does not present data for all municipalities, only part of them. This partial sample, however, is very inclusive as it covers almost the entire national population. Between the years 2000 and 2013, for example, Finbra covered an average of 96.9% of all Brazilian municipalities, together with 98.3% of the country’s population. In 2014, Finbra covered 4,978 of 5,570 Brazilian municipalities, or about 89.4 % of all municipalities in Brazil. The other sources of data used for this study were made compatible with the restriction imposed by Finbra.

Despite the good quality of the initial sample, a filter was applied in order to avoid gross errors and problems in the construction of derived indicators. Therefore, municipalities that presented null value (zero or non-existent) for any of the primary variables were excluded from the database. This filtering procedure reduced the sample of municipalities to 4,515 (81% of the total).

It is important to highlight that municipalities were organized in groups of analysis in order to build and analyze fuzzy indices. Municipalities were divided according to the size of their population in six large groups (up to 10,000 inhabitants; between 10,001 and 20,000 inhabitants; between 20,001 and 50,000 inhabitants; between 50,001 and 100,000 inhabitants; between 100,001 and 500,000 inhabitants; and finally, over 500,000 inhabitants). This methodological procedure was conducted in order to reduce the distance between municipalities with very contrasting characteristics.2 2 During the research, other criteria to group municipalities were considered, such as HDI and geographic location. The choice for “population” was made because of the consistent results of this criterion in relation with the intuition around the theme.

2.3 Calculation of fuzzy indices

Fuzzy indices were built from data collected from the sources presented previously, using the following basic formula:

x i j = N j - M i n M a x j - M i n j , . 1 < j < 7 ; 1 < i < 4.515

xij = value of the fuzzy index for the indicator j calculated by the municipality i;

Nj= observed value of the indicator’s series j for the municipality i;

Minj= minimum value of the indicator’s series j;

Maxj= maximum value of the indicator’s series j.

This formula was used directly in two of the three aggregate fuzzy indices proposed in this article. In the case of aggregate fuzzy index of usage (Ifau) and the aggregate fuzzy index of potential (Ifap), all indicators have a positive relation, making this formula sufficient for the calculation. As for the aggregate fuzzy index of use of capacity (Ifauc), it is much simpler and is reduced to the relation between the results of the first two aggregate indices (index of use divided by the index of potential).

Example 1: fuzzy index for IPTU per capita (in building the aggregate fuzzy index of usage) of the city of Rio de Janeiro.

Nj= 310,24

Minj= 42,98

Maxj= 501,33

x i j = 310,24 - 42,98 501,33 - 42,98 0,5831

Example 2: Fuzzy index for ITBI per capita (in building the aggregate fuzzy index of potential) in the city of Rio de Janeiro.

Nj= 114,92

Minj= 17,62

Maxj= 169,35

x i j = 114,92 - 17,62 169,35 - 17,62 0,6413

Chart 1 shows the relation between the selected indicators and the aggregate fuzzy indices.

CHART 1
Relation between variables and aggregate indices

The first two indicators of the list were used to build the aggregate fuzzy indices of usage and use of capacity and show a positive relation with both indices. As these two indicators measure — in different ways — the collection of IPTU, it is assumed that the higher the collection, the greater the usage towards tax collection (usage) and the greater the usage in relation to its potential (use of capacity).

The following five indicators show positive relation with the aggregate fuzzy index of potential and negative relation with the aggregate fuzzy index of use of capacity. The indicators were taken as proxy for different dimensions of municipal finances.

IPVA was taken as a proxy for the ability to collect property taxes. In other words, the greater the transfer/collection of IPVA, the greater the “willingness” (i.e. capacity) of local taxpayers to pay IPTU and, consequently, ceteris paribus the lower the use of capacity.

ITBI was used as proxy for the size of the local real estate market — both from the point of view of movement/transfers and real estate values. That is, the higher the ITBI collection, the greater the potential of IPTU collection and, consequently, ceteris paribus the lower the use of capacity.

The fifth variable (Revenue from Taxes/Budgetary Revenue) was used as a proxy for “fiscal autonomy”, which means, the capacity of the municipality to generate its own resources. The higher this indicator, the greater the capacity of the municipality to present good administration of the tax (raising its potential) and consequently ceteris paribus the lower the use of capacity.

IPM was chosen as a proxy for economic activity or creation of added value in the municipality. Thus, the higher the income generation in the municipality, the greater the ability of local agents to pay taxes (including IPTU), and consequently, ceteris paribus the lower the use of capacity.

The number of properties was used to measure the units that can be taxed. If the number of properties is higher, the greater the possibility of IPTU collection and, consequently, ceteris paribus the lower the use of capacity.

The indices built from the basic formula vary from 0 (zero) to 1 (one), where 0 (zero) corresponds to the index of the municipality that presents the lowest value for a given indicator in the population group, and 1 (one) corresponds to the index of the municipality that presents the highest value for a given indicator in the population group.

It should be noted that this “degree of truth” index, because using the maximum of each indicator as the denominator, implies the risk of being affected by outliers. Zeros were considered gross errors and were excluded. Eventual errors in the higher values may affect the indices of each indicator and, consequently, the aggregate indices.

2.4 Indicators’ weight

The construction of aggregate fuzzy indices depends on the aggregation of the individual fuzzy indices, obtained from each variable analyzed alone. However, in order to proceed with the aggregation, it is necessary to observe the participation of each of the individual fuzzy indices in the final composition. In other words, to obtain the indicators’ weight.

There are two options when it comes to attributing weights: arbitration and mathematical instruments. Although some studies using the fuzzy set methodology adopt a more subjective concept for attributing weights (Barros, Carvalho and Franco, 2006 BARROS Ricardo P.; CARVALHO, Mirela; FRANCO, Samuel. Pobreza multidimensional no Brasil. Texto para Discussão n. 1227 - Ipea. 2006. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.repositorio.ipea.gov.br/bitstream/11058/1688/1/TD_1227.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
http://www.repositorio.ipea.gov.br/bitst...
; Carvalho, Kerstenetzky and Del-Vecchio, 2007CARVALHO, Maristela; KERSTENETZKY, Celia L; DEL VECCHIO, Renata. Uma aplicação da teoria dos conjuntos fuzzy na análise da pobreza: o caso das regiões metropolitanas do Sudeste brasileiro - 2000. In: ENCONTRO NACIONAL DE ECONOMIA, ANPEC, XXXV, 2007, Recife. p. 22. Disponível em: <http://www.anpec.org.br/encontro2007/artigos/A07A001.pdf>. Informações detalhadas sobre o Anais em: <https://www.ideas.repec.org/s/anp/en2007.html>.
http://www.anpec.org.br/encontro2007/art...
), for this research mathematical instruments were used.

The choice was made considering that most studies based on fuzzy set theory adopt mathematical instruments for attributing weights (Diniz and Diniz, 2009DINIZ, Marcelo B.; DINIZ, Marcos M. Um indicador comparativo de pobreza multidimensional a partir dos objetivos do desenvolvimento do milênio. Economia Aplicada, v. 13, n. 3, p. 399-423, 2009.; Ottonelli and Mariano, 2014OTTONELLI, Janaina; MARIANO, Jorge Luiz. Pobreza multidimensional nos municípios da Região Nordeste. Rev. Adm. Pública, Rio de Janeiro, v. 48, n. 5, p. 1253-1279, out. 2014.), since they are more objective. The advantage of this methodology for calculating weights is, precisely, the non-arbitrage. In addition, this methodology emphasizes the relative position, assuming that the relevance of the fiscal situation of the municipality is the comparison with the other municipalities. A hierarchy is obtained by simple comparison.

Based on this, the indicators’ weights are calculated weighted by the population size of the municipalities and based on the following formula:

w j = l n n i = 1 n x i , j n i

xi,j = value of the fuzzy index for indicator j calculated for municipality I;

n = total population;

ni = municipality population i.

Example: weight of indicator IPVA per capita (in building the aggregate fuzzy index of potential).

n= 180.583.711

w j = l n 180.583.711 i = 1 4.515 x i , j n i

x1,jn1 = 0,22 ? 822

x2,jn2 = 0,05 ? 1.000

(...)

x4.515,jn4.515 = 0,76 ? 11.895.893

w j = I n 180.583.711 56.203.907 1,17

In general, the idea of attributing weight based on this formula is to avoid that individual indices with higher values gain influence in the aggregated result, which could happen in a choice of weight by arbitrage.

Based on this attribution of weights, which allows a complete order (avoiding that two indicators present the same weight), the classification is obtained and presented in table 1.

Table 1
Weight of individual indicators forming the use of capacity index (2014)

2.5 Aggregation of fuzzy indices

For a more accurate comparison of the context of IPTU among municipalities, it is necessary to aggregate the seven indicators selected into another indicator (in this case, three other indicators), which would be the general representative of the dimension to be captured by the aggregate indicator (usage, potential and use of capacity).

The aggregation is calculated using the fuzzy indices of each variable (individual indices) and the weights of those variables. It is only a weighted average of the fuzzy indices, as observed in the following formula:

μ i = j = 1 n x i , j w j j = 1 n w j

xi,j = value of the fuzzy índex for indicator j calculated for municipality i;

wj = weight of indicator j.

Example: aggregate fuzzy index of potential of Rio de Janeiro

μ i = j = 1 5 x i j w j j = 1 5 w j

xi,1w1 = 0,32 ? 1,17

xi,2w2 = 0,64 ? 1,54

(...)

xi,5w5 = 0,56 ? 0,93

μ i = 3,25 7,04 0,46

With aggregation, it can only be by coincidence that a municipality has an aggregate fuzzy index of 0 (zero) or 1 (one). This is because it is rare for a city to present extreme results (0 or 1) on all selected indicators. The probability of finding an aggregate fuzzy index of 0 (zero) or 1 (one) is increasingly difficult the higher the number of variables and the municipalities to be used in the analysis. As the number of indicators selected in this study is not considered high (seven), the closest results of 0 (zero) and 1 (one) findings are presented in table 2.

TABLE 2
Minimum and maximum of aggregate fuzzy indices (2014)

As observed in table 2 and will be noted throughout the article, only the aggregate fuzzy index of use of capacity can vary beyond 1 (one), because it is a mathematical relationship between the aggregate fuzzy index of usage and the aggregate fuzzy index of potential. Whenever the former is greater than the latter, the result will be an aggregate fuzzy index of use of capacity higher than 1 (one). Another important point is the fact that the minimum and the maximum of the aggregate fuzzy index of usage are almost always in the extremes (respectively 0 (zero) and 1 (one)). Since this index is composed of only two indicators (related to each other), it increases the possibility of the same municipality be the worst or the best in both dimensions that make up the index.

3. Results analysis

Analysis was conducted to understand the municipalities’ behavior regarding housing tax (IPTU) collection. The analysis was carried out both in an aggregated and individualized way, by observing the behavior of a specific city or a predetermined group.

This section will be divided into four subsections. The first presents descriptive statistics of aggregate indices (aggregate usage fuzzy index; aggregate potential fuzzy index; and capacity usage fuzzy index). In the second subsection, the data obtained from the aggregate usage fuzzy index will be used rank the municipalities. In the third section, a graphic analysis of comparison groups will be provided, allowing to identify which municipalities are “efficient” in collecting IPTU. Finally, the fourth and last subsection will address the main tendencies observed from the results.

3.1 Aggregate results and descriptive statistics

Regarding the descriptive statistics obtained from aggregate results, it is possible to observe that some of the indicators’ behaviors are common among these results.

A methodological aspect affecting the analysis of aggregate results is the impossibility of comparing different groups of municipalities. The groups were formed according to population. For instance, it is not recommended to compare the average Ifau (acronym in Portuguese for Aggregate Usage Fuzzy Index) and Ifap (acronym in Portuguese for Aggregate Potential Fuzzy Index) of municipalities with a populations of more than 500,000 inhabitants with the average of municipalities of a maximum population of 10,000 inhabitants. This limitation is reasonable since it is not important to compare a rich, well-developed city with a small one with fewer resources and serious social deficiencies. However, this is not the main explanation for not making such comparison, but the methodology of the study itself. The two aggregate indices — Ifau and Ifap — were calculated from an intragroup comparison, rather than intergroup. In other words, for each group, the municipalities with the best performance in the individual indicators within that group, served as references (benchmark) for the calculation. Thus, different municipalities serve as a reference in each group.

The comparability limitation is applicable to both Ifau and Ifap, and can be more flexible for Ifauc (acronym in Portuguese for aggregate usage capacity fuzzy index). Ifauc is the index object of this study and it seeks to measure how a municipality is using its capacity to collect IPTU. The study observes how each group takes advantage of its potential tax collection. For example, the group of municipalities with a population between 50,001 and 100,000 inhabitants uses an average of 40% of its potential to collect IPTU (Ifauc = 0,40), whereas the group of municipalities with a population of up to 10,000 inhabitants uses 21% of its potential to collect IPTU (Ifauc = 0.21). In this case, the former group uses its potential better than the latter.

Another common feature of the statistics is the fact that the averages of both Ifau and Ifap are relatively higher in the groups that have fewer municipalities. That is, a negative relation between the mean value of the aggregate index (Ifau or Ifap) and the number of municipalities in that group was identified. The only explanation for this result is better performance among the members of the group with higher indices, observing that this is a remarkable feature within the municipalities with a population of over 500,000 inhabitants. In other words, evidence shows that the highest average index value for these groups is explained by the greater effort of these groups to collect more IPTU (Ifau) and by their greater potential for collecting the tax due to a more favorable socioeconomic environment (Ifap). However, this relation is not as clear when comparing two similar groups (populations with similar characteristics).

Despite this problem, statistics of aggregate indices allow to fairly compare the indices within the same group. Given this possibility, results show that the mean value of Ifau is almost always lower than the mean value of Ifap. This relation is reversed only in the group of municipalities with more than 500,000 inhabitants, which is relevant as it reveals that most Brazilian municipalities are collecting less IPTU than they have potential for — the hypothesis raised in the introduction of this article. With the existence of the relation Ifau < Ifap, the index derived from them (Ifauc) is, on average, lower than 01 (except in the aforementioned group — more than 500,000 inhabitants).

The standard deviation in the aggregate indices is high, vis-à-vis the averages, which provide a reasonable degree of uncertainty to the data series. Two normality tests (Anderson and Darling, 1952ANDERSON, Theodore W.; DARLING, Donald A. Asymptotic theory of certain goodness-of-fit criteria based on stochastic processes. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, v. 23, n. 2, p. 193-212, 1952.; Shapiro and Wilk, 1965SHAPIRO, Samuel S.; WILK, Martin B. An analysis of variance test for normality (complete samples). Biometrika, Oxford, v. 52, n. 3/4, p. 591-611, 1965.) were applied to group data and the result was always negative, which indicates that the “normal distribution” is not applicable to the data of this research. This high dispersion (and uncertainty) can be explained by two reasons: the municipalities are very different which does not permit that their indices have a low variance; and the data from ‘Finbra’ are prone to errors, especially those of the small municipalities, which can accentuate the differences.

The maximum (or the minimum) values of Ifap hardly ever reach 1 (one) or 0 (zero), since it is highly unlikely that a municipality gets its best (or worst) result in all individual indices within its own analysis group. In the case of Ifau, this possibility is considerably higher, since it is composed of only two individual indices. Thus, for a municipality to reach 01 (one) on Ifau, for instance, it should present its best results of IPTU per capita and IPTU/Revenue. For Ifap, 01 (one) would only be possible if a municipality presented the best result for indices for IPVA (vehicle tax) per capita, ITBI (real estate transfer tax) per capita, Tax Revenue/ Budget Revenue, IPM (transfers from state taxes) and amount of real estate. If the coincidence of results does not seem to be improbable for Ifau, in the case of Ifap, a municipality would only achieve all these requirements by chance. Table 2 reveals that Ifau has maximums and minimums in both end positions of the table, 1 (one) and 0 (zero), respectively. This cannot be observed for Ifap.

In the case of Ifauc, results higher than 1 (one) were common. In fact, this was evidenced in various municipalities of the sample analyzed. The interpretation for this result indicates these municipalities present an “over-exploration” of their capacities. The fact that there are municipalities that have an index higher than 1 (one) is not a problem at first because it is a mathematical equation that uses two other indices which are built in a relative way (that is, a comparison between municipalities).

In any case, it is not acceptable that something is “producing” beyond its capacity. Statistically, this can be the result of a random event or even an error. In practice, the results might suggest that a municipality has considerably increased its IPTU levy in a specific year in order to correct a lag of many years, however, that adjustment was overestimated (above the municipality capacity). Another possibility is the so-called summer cities, in which there are many properties (vacant almost all year) and little economic activity.

Table 3 presents the descriptive statistics of aggregate indices per population in the year 2014.

As we can see, there is a tendency for the average of Ifauc to increase as the municipalities grow (population), with some oscillation between similar groups. This index ranges from 0.21, on average, in the municipalities with a population up to 10,000 inhabitants. Then, it ranges from 0.14 to 0.82 in the intermediate groups, finally reaching 1.58 in the municipalities with a population of more than 500,000 inhabitants. The medians present similar behavior. This result is important as it is aligned with the expectations: smaller municipalities make less effort to collect taxes (including IPTU), while larger municipalities do the opposite.

TABLE 3
Descriptive statistics of aggregate fuzzy indices per population (2014)

Another relevant aspect is the fact that the maximum Ifauc index is very high in municipalities of smaller populations (group of municipalities with up to 10,000 inhabitants and the group of municipalities with a population between 10,001 and 20,000 inhabitants). They reach values of 3.87 and 4.67, respectively, which are results very close to those of municipalities with a population of more than 500,000 inhabitants (4.21). As these are relative indicators, the aforementioned results can be explained by the fact that it is easier to stand out against “weaker competitors” than stronger ones. In other words, in a group that uses little of its potential, any municipality that has a good performance in collecting tax would stand out from others.

3.2 Ifauc ranking of municipalities

The ranking of data that is presented below used Itauc, which is the main index and object of this study. Although the results of the other two indices are presented in the table, they are considered informative data and are not relevant to the classification of municipalities.

As well as presenting and briefly analyzing the data, whenever it is possible (depending on the availability of information), some characteristics of the municipalities that had the most positive results in the rankings will be highlighted. This helps to understand the reasons why a municipality managed to achieve good results within its analysis group.

Table 4presents the ranking of the 05 best Ifauc per population in the year of 2014. The best positioned municipalities were: Aparecida de Goiânia (GO) — in the group of municipalities with population of more than 500,000 inhabitants; Guarujá (SP) — municipalities with a population between 100,001 and 500,000 inhabitants; Campos do Jordão (SP) — municipalities with a population between 50,001 and 100,000 inhabitants; Ilhabela (SP) — in the group of municipalities with a population between 20,001 and 50,000 inhabitants; Ilha Comprida (SP) — municipalities with a population between 10,001 and 20,000 inhabitants; and Barra de São Miguel (AL) — in the group of municipalities with a population of up to 10,001 inhabitants.

TABLE 4
Ranking of the five municipalities with highest Ifauc — per population (2014)

Of the six municipalities highlighted above, only one is not a tourist destination: Aparecida de Goiânia (GO). This is not a fact that resulted from mere chance since municipalities that welcome a great number of visitors also have a great number of underused properties (these properties are vacant for most of the year). Therefore, the political cost of the mayor in adopting a more rigid taxation policy (higher taxes and higher values of land as source of calculation of tax) in those municipalities is lower than it is in municipalities that do not have this characteristic. As all holiday homes are usually located in noble regions and neighborhoods, there is a possibility for the collecting of housing tax to be concentrated on this kind of real estate, without any loss of significant “electoral power”. That is, the floating population who do not vote in the tourist destination end up paying most of the tax.

Reaffirming the vocation of these five locations, IBGE (Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics) uses a tool called “Cidades” that shows that tourism is an essential activity in the aforementioned municipalities. Guarujá, Ilhabela, Ilha Comprida (considered to be a beach resort by the Government of the State of São Paulo) and Barra de São Miguel focus on beach tourism. Campos do Jordão (considered to be ‘climatic resort’ by the Government of São Paulo) focuses on mountain tourism.

In the case of Aparecida de Goiânia (GO), the good result can be linked to the recent efforts of the local city hall in improving IPTU tax collection. Good examples of these efforts are Municipal Law no 2.929/2010 (Establishes a campaign that stimulates collection and payment of debts regarding IPTU and ITU), as well as the implementation of ITU3 3 In Aparecida de Goiânia, ITU is similar to IPTU. However, it refers to taxes on urban areas with no constructions, such as a piece of land. as a progressive tax, in which the land owner is notified to build on the land or to pay higher taxes that may increase over time.

The following table shows the ranking for the five municipalities with the worst Ifauc per population in the year of 2014. The municipalities that negatively stood out from others were: São Luís (MA) — in the group of municipalities with a population of more than 500,000 inhabitants; Tucuruí (PA) — in the group of municipalities with a population between 100,001 and 500,000 inhabitants; Zé Doca (MA) — in the group of municipalities with a population between 50,001 and 100,000 inhabitants; Traipu (AP) — in the group of municipalities with a population between 20,001 and 50,000 inhabitants; Palmácia (CE) — in the group of municipalities with a population between 10,001 and 20,000 inhabitants; and Caridade do Piauí (PI) — in the group of municipalities with a population below 10,001inhabitants.

TABLE 5
Ranking of the five municipalities with lowest Ifauc — per population (2014)

The analysis of this ranking are limited to two of the aforementioned groups: municipalities with more than 500,000 inhabitants; and municipalities with a population between 100,001 and 500,000 inhabitants. The other three groups have several municipalities that are in the last position with results close to 0 (Zero).

Within the group of municipalities with a population of more than 500,000 inhabitants, the city of São Luís stood out negatively for presenting quite modest indices (Ifau) for collection of IPTU (together, they represent approximately 11% of the best results in the group) compared to its (only) reasonable potential for tax collection (Ifap).

Tucuruí (PA) was ranked in last position for Ifauc in the group of municipalities with a population between 100,001 and 500,000 inhabitants. This result can be explained by low indices for the collection of IPTU — all of them very close to 0 (Zero). In addition to that, the city had an unsatisfactory potential (approximately 9.3% of the group’s highest potential), which indicates that there is still space for improving the collection of urban property tax (IPTU), but in a moderate way.

3.3 Visual analysis of the IPTU collection

In order to increase the perception of the number of municipalities which are not exploring IPTU adequately, dispersion graphs — which relate the positioning of each municipality according to Ifau and Ifap — are presented in this section. Interpreting these graphs is quite simple: in a good scenario, a municipality that manages to use all its potential for collecting IPTU would reach the exact same value for both Ifau and Ifap, obtaining 01 as Ifauc value. This situation is represented by the diagonal line that crosses the plot area, starting from 0.0 and reaching 1.1. If the municipality is located on this line, it is classified as “efficient”.4 4 This study does not aim at discussing the concept of efficiency mainly because it can be understood in many different ways. This term, as well as the terms “inefficiency” and “super efficiency” are used in a generic way, only to differentiate what is on the dispersion graphs.

However, a municipality would be on this line only by coincidence. The most common situation is when a location is positioned either above or below the line. Since Ifau is located on the x-axis (horizontal) and Ifap is located on the y-axis (vertical), any municipality positioned above the line would be in a situation in which Ifau is lower than Ifap, meaning that this municipality is “inefficient”. Similarly, any municipality positioned below the line would be in a situation in which Ifau is higher than Ifap, meaning that this municipality is “super efficient”.

Graphs 1;2;3;4;5 to 6 show each municipality’s behavior between Ifau and Ifap per population.

Graph 1
Ifau x Ifap — municipalities with a population of over 500,000 inhabitants (2014)

Graph 2
Ifau x ifap — municipalities with a population between 500,000 and 100,001 inhabitants (2014)

Graph 3
Ifau × Ifap — municipalities with a population between 10,000 and 50,001 inhabitants (2014)

Graph 4
Ifau x Ifap — municipalities with a population between 20,001 and 50,000 inhabitants (2014)

Graph 5
Ifau x ifap — Municipalities with a population between 10,001 and 20,000 inhabitants (2014)

Graph 6
Ifau × Ifap — municipalities with a population of up to 10,000 inhabitants (2014)

The graphs make it clear that there is a progression of the relative number of inefficient municipalities as their size, in terms of population, decreases. In the group of more populated municipalities, however, only 37% are located in the graph’s ‘inefficient zone’. In the group of municipalities with a population of up to 10,000 inhabitants, approximately 95.8% are above the line (inefficient). Out of the 1,957 in this group, only 30 were classified as efficient (or super efficient). The previous group (10,001 to 20,000 inhabitants) presented an even worse percentage of inefficiency (99%). Nevertheless, there is a general tendency for it to get worse as the municipality population decreases.

The worst relative performance of low-population municipalities was already evidenced by Alonso and Castro (2014). They point out political reasons (proximity between mayors and their voters) to explain this fact. Moreover, a lower taxable base (Sepulveda and Vasquez, 2009SEPULVEDA, Cristian; VAZQUES, Jorge M. Property taxation in Latin-America: an assessment and options for reform. The Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (Eclac). Relaciones intergubernamentales y descentralizaciónen América Latina. Santiago de Chile, nov. 2009. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.researchgate.net/profile/Jorge_Martinez-Vazquez/publication/265541538_Property_Taxation_in_Latin-America_An_Assessment_and_Options_for_Reform/links/5525380c0cf201667be64544.pdf >. Acesso em: 20 nov. 2015.
http://www.researchgate.net/profile/Jorg...
) and other administrative issues (e.g. administrative costs) (Afonso, Araujo and Nobrega, 2012AFONSO, José Roberto; ARAÚJO, Érika A.; NÓBREGA, Marcos A. R. The urban property tax (IPTU) in Brazil: an analysis of the use of the property tax as a revenue source by Brazilian municipalities. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Working Paper, 2012. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/dl/2285_1624_Afonso_WP13JA2.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
http://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/dl/2285_...
) are possible explanations for the poor results of smaller municipalities.

All the inefficient cities in this study could, in theory, improve their revenue from IPTU. Based on this, the next section proposes an estimation of the possible increase to municipalities’ revenue from IPTU through a better use of their potential.

3.4 Potential to expand IPTU collection

Results show that many of the municipalities do not properly use their potential to collect IPTU. Based on this finding, the study has used the relation between Ifau and Ifap to help estimate the possible increase to municipalities’ revenue from IPTU. The simple inversion of the equation proposed to obtain Ifauc (from Ifau/Ifap to Ifap/Ifau) provides an expansion factor for increased IPTU collection per municipality. Therefore, table 6 presents the aggregate results obtained from this estimate.

TABLE 6
Aggregate potential to expand IPTU tax collection (2014)

It is to note that there is potential for increasing the amount of IPTU collected in all groups of municipalities. In most groups, the potential for expansion is very high, exceeding 400% in cities with a population between 10,001 and 20,000 inhabitants, for example. Many of the locations with this potential, however, collect very little IPTU. By observing the estimation in an aggregate way, it is possible to realize that there is a potential for IPTU collection to grow by slightly more than 40%. In terms of GDP, the estimated expansion would be 0.18% of the municipality GDP.

The idea of potential for tax collection described in this article is important, as municipalities are increasingly demanded to provide more and better public services, at the same time suffering from the uncertainty (inconsistency) of revenue flow from the Federal and States’ governments.

{...} if society demands more action from the municipal administration, structural increases in revenue are crucial. The only plausible hypothesis, if there is a need for increasing revenue, will be feasible if the tax policy is in line with taxpayers’ capacity to contribute and with the consequent strengthening of tax management. {Guedes, 2008GUEDES, José Rildo M. Tributos imobiliários: carga tributária. Instituto Brasileiro de Administração Municipal (Ibam), Rio de Janeiro, mar. 2008. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.ibam.org.br/media/arquivos/estudos/tributos_imobil.pdf >. Acesso em: 20 nov. 2015.
http://www.ibam.org.br/media/arquivos/es...
:17}

4. Final considerations

There is a consensus among public finance experts in Brazil regarding property tax: in spite of the high tax burden on standard Brazilian development, there is still a huge potential for resource generation that is not explored in many Brazilian cities, especially for property tax — the most traditional and worldwide source used to finance local governments.

This study assessed Brazilian municipalities’ usage and potential for collecting IPTU in order to obtain, by comparing municipalities, opportunities to increase their revenue. A simple and unique methodology was used, attributing “degrees of truth” in relative terms. A fairer analysis was conducted by classifying municipalities in groups according to their population before applying the methodology.

Other methodologies could be adapted and applied in this study for the same purpose. Additionally, using the same method, other choices could have been made in terms of attributing weights and establishing variables, choices that would possibly lead to other classification among the cities, especially on their potential to collect IPTU. However, it is important to highlight the effort of the study to build a consistent and coherent analytical framework for data analysis.

Findings confirm what analysts and even municipal leaders had already pointed out: the majority of Brazilian municipalities do not use their potential for collecting IPTU — a fact that tends to be more critical in smaller municipalities, which depend on resources from other spheres of government. Finally, the innovation of this study was to use comparative analysis between cities in order to measure this potential.

Despite confirming both hypotheses and researchers’ intuition, it is necessary to interpret the results carefully, considering that primary data are not infallible (data provided by Finbra sometimes present inconsistencies that are not easily identifiable), that the choice of methodology has a reasonable effect in determining results (it is possible that applying an alternative proposal or using different indicators, results at the municipal level could be different), and that the proposed classification may change the positioning of most municipalities (the choice of classification may vary according to the analyst’s preferences).

Exploring IPTU’s potential in a minimally compatible way with other Brazilian taxes, including property tax, is an action that should not be taken only to obtain greater revenue potential — as explained by Afonso (2014AFONSO, José Roberto; CASTRO, Kleber P. A dificuldade para financiamento municipal via imposto sobre propriedade urbana no Brasil. In: JORNADAS IBERO-AMERICANAS DE FINANCIAMENTO LOCAL, III, 2014, São Paulo. São Paulo: Fundação Instituto Fernando Henrique Cardoso, ago. 2014. p. 1-20.). Moreover, it can and should be used for regulatory purposes and for urban policy purposes in each city.

Finally, it is worth reinforcing that a better exploration of IPTU would allow the tax system to be aligned with two of its crucial objectives. First, it would improve fairness in a country that does not apply property taxes properly and charges high taxes on consumption. Collecting IPTU may be a faster, more efficient and effective way to achieve the same results desired by those that advocate for the creation of tax on fortunes, inheritances, and donations. The second objective would be to strengthen finances of local governments. This would reduce their dependence on resource transfers. It would expand funding for essential public services, such as education and health. Therefore, attention to IPTU is important in order to face a variety of important challenges for economic and social development in Brazil.

Referências

  • AFONSO, José Roberto. Financiamento da Inovação Urbana. In: LAZZARINI, Sergio. Arquiteto do futuro: financiamento da inovação urbana, novos modelos. São Paulo: BEI, 2014. p. 72-92.
  • AFONSO, José Roberto; ARAÚJO, Érika A.; NÓBREGA, Marcos A. R. The urban property tax (IPTU) in Brazil: an analysis of the use of the property tax as a revenue source by Brazilian municipalities. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Working Paper, 2012. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/dl/2285_1624_Afonso_WP13JA2.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
    » http://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/dl/2285_1624_Afonso_WP13JA2.pdf
  • AFONSO, José Roberto; CASTRO, Kleber P. A dificuldade para financiamento municipal via imposto sobre propriedade urbana no Brasil. In: JORNADAS IBERO-AMERICANAS DE FINANCIAMENTO LOCAL, III, 2014, São Paulo. São Paulo: Fundação Instituto Fernando Henrique Cardoso, ago. 2014. p. 1-20.
  • AFONSO, José Roberto; SOARES, Julia M.; CASTRO, Kleber P. Avaliação da estrutura e do desempenho do sistema tributário brasileiro: livro branco da tributação brasileira. Documento para discussão IDB-DP-265, Banco Interamericano de Desenvolvimento. Brasília, 2013. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/publications/documents/37434330.pdf >. Acesso em: 11 nov. 2015.
    » http://www.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/publications/documents/37434330.pdf
  • ANDERSON, Theodore W.; DARLING, Donald A. Asymptotic theory of certain goodness-of-fit criteria based on stochastic processes. The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, v. 23, n. 2, p. 193-212, 1952.
  • BAHL, Roy. Property tax reform in developing and transition countries. Washington: Usaid, 2009. Disponível em: < Disponível em: http://www.pdf.usaid.gov/pdf_docs/Pnadw480.pdf >. Acesso em: 4 jul. 2017.
    » http://www.pdf.usaid.gov/pdf_docs/Pnadw480.pdf
  • BALIAMOUNE LUTZ, Mina. On the measurement of human well-being: fuzzy set theory and Sen’s capability approach. Tóquio: United Nations University: World Institute of Development Research, 2004. WIDER, Research Paper n. 2.004/16. Disponível em: <Disponível em: https://www.core.ac.uk/download/files/153/6483894.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
    » https://www.core.ac.uk/download/files/153/6483894.pdf
  • BARROS Ricardo P.; CARVALHO, Mirela; FRANCO, Samuel. Pobreza multidimensional no Brasil Texto para Discussão n. 1227 - Ipea. 2006. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.repositorio.ipea.gov.br/bitstream/11058/1688/1/TD_1227.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
    » http://www.repositorio.ipea.gov.br/bitstream/11058/1688/1/TD_1227.pdf
  • CARVALHO, Maristela; KERSTENETZKY, Celia L; DEL VECCHIO, Renata. Uma aplicação da teoria dos conjuntos fuzzy na análise da pobreza: o caso das regiões metropolitanas do Sudeste brasileiro - 2000. In: ENCONTRO NACIONAL DE ECONOMIA, ANPEC, XXXV, 2007, Recife. p. 22. Disponível em: <http://www.anpec.org.br/encontro2007/artigos/A07A001.pdf>. Informações detalhadas sobre o Anais em: <https://www.ideas.repec.org/s/anp/en2007.html>.
    » http://www.anpec.org.br/encontro2007/artigos/A07A001.pdf» https://www.ideas.repec.org/s/anp/en2007.html
  • CASTRO, Kleber P.; KERSTENETZKY, Celia L; DEL-VECCHIO, Renata. Pobreza fuzzy multidimensional: uma análise das condições de vida na Zona Oeste do Rio de Janeiro - 1991 e 2000. In: SIMPÓSIO BRASILEIRO DE PESQUISA OPERACIONAL, 42., 2010, Bento Gonçalves. 2010
  • CECHINI, Kerlyng et al. Brazilian automotive industry in the nineties MPRAPaper, Munich, n. 41197, set. 2012. Disponível em: <Disponível em: https://www.mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/41197/1/MPRA_paper_41197.pdf >. Acesso em: 8 dez. 2015.
    » https://www.mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/41197/1/MPRA_paper_41197.pdf
  • CHIAPPERO-MARTINETTI, Enrica. A multidimensional assessment of well-being based on sen’s functioning approach. Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali, n. 2, p. 207-239, 2000.
  • DE CESARE, Claudia M.; MARÍN, José Francsico L. Impuestos a los patrimonios en América Latina. Macroeconomía del Desarrollo, n. 66, 2008. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/handle/11362/5433/1/S0800387_es.pdf >. Acesso em: 4 jul. 2017.
    » http://www.repositorio.cepal.org/bitstream/handle/11362/5433/1/S0800387_es.pdf
  • DINIZ, Marcelo B.; DINIZ, Marcos M. Um indicador comparativo de pobreza multidimensional a partir dos objetivos do desenvolvimento do milênio. Economia Aplicada, v. 13, n. 3, p. 399-423, 2009.
  • FONSECA, Oswaldo L. H. Aplicação de métodos de análise espacial e da teoria dos conjuntos nebulosos em estudos sobre pobreza Dissertação (mestrado em engenharia) - Universidade Federal do Rio de Janeiro, Rio de Janeiro, 2003.
  • GUEDES, José Rildo M. Tributos imobiliários: carga tributária. Instituto Brasileiro de Administração Municipal (Ibam), Rio de Janeiro, mar. 2008. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.ibam.org.br/media/arquivos/estudos/tributos_imobil.pdf >. Acesso em: 20 nov. 2015.
    » http://www.ibam.org.br/media/arquivos/estudos/tributos_imobil.pdf
  • LELLI, Sara. Factor analisys vs. fuzzy sets theory: assessing the influence of different techniques on Sen’s functioning approach. Center for Economic Studies, K. U. Leuven, 2001. Disponível em: <Disponível em: https://www.feb.kuleuven.be/eng/ew/discussionpapers/Dps01/Dps0121.pdf >. Acesso em: 10 dez. 2015.
    » https://www.feb.kuleuven.be/eng/ew/discussionpapers/Dps01/Dps0121.pdf
  • LOPES, Helger M. Análise de pobreza com indicadores multidimensionais: uma aplicação para Brasil e Minas Gerais. Dissertação (mestrado em economia) - Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento Regional, Universidade Federal de Minas Gerais, Belo Horizonte. 2003.
  • OTTONELLI, Janaina; MARIANO, Jorge Luiz. Pobreza multidimensional nos municípios da Região Nordeste. Rev. Adm. Pública, Rio de Janeiro, v. 48, n. 5, p. 1253-1279, out. 2014.
  • RECEITA FEDERAL DO BRASIL. Carga tributária no Brasil 2014: análise por tributos e bases de incidência. Brasília: RFB/CETAD. out. 2015. Disponível em: <Disponível em: https://www.idg.receita.fazenda.gov.br/dados/receitadata/estudos-e-tributarios-e-aduaneiros/estudos-e-estatisticas/carga-tributaria-no-brasil/29-10-2015-carga-tributaria-2014 >. Acesso em: 4 jul. 2017.
    » https://www.idg.receita.fazenda.gov.br/dados/receitadata/estudos-e-tributarios-e-aduaneiros/estudos-e-estatisticas/carga-tributaria-no-brasil/29-10-2015-carga-tributaria-2014
  • SEPULVEDA, Cristian; VAZQUES, Jorge M. Property taxation in Latin-America: an assessment and options for reform. The Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (Eclac). Relaciones intergubernamentales y descentralizaciónen América Latina. Santiago de Chile, nov. 2009. Disponível em: <Disponível em: http://www.researchgate.net/profile/Jorge_Martinez-Vazquez/publication/265541538_Property_Taxation_in_Latin-America_An_Assessment_and_Options_for_Reform/links/5525380c0cf201667be64544.pdf >. Acesso em: 20 nov. 2015.
    » http://www.researchgate.net/profile/Jorge_Martinez-Vazquez/publication/265541538_Property_Taxation_in_Latin-America_An_Assessment_and_Options_for_Reform/links/5525380c0cf201667be64544.pdf
  • SHAPIRO, Samuel S.; WILK, Martin B. An analysis of variance test for normality (complete samples). Biometrika, Oxford, v. 52, n. 3/4, p. 591-611, 1965.
  • SIMÕES, Rodrigo F. Complexos industriais no espaço: uma análise de fuzzy cluster. Centro de Desenvolvimento e Planejamento Regional. Texto para discussão, n. 209, Belo Horizonte, 2003. Disponível em: <http://www.cedeplar.ufmg.br/pesquisas/td/TD%20209.pdf>. Acesso em: 8 dez. 2015.
    » http://www.cedeplar.ufmg.br/pesquisas/td/TD%20209.pdf
  • ZADEH, Lotfy A. Fuzzy sets. Information and Control, v. 8, p. 338-353, 1965.
  • 1
    An important decision on the subject was rendered on 12/18/2013 by the STJ (Superior Court of Justice).
  • 2
    During the research, other criteria to group municipalities were considered, such as HDI and geographic location. The choice for “population” was made because of the consistent results of this criterion in relation with the intuition around the theme.
  • 3
    In Aparecida de Goiânia, ITU is similar to IPTU. However, it refers to taxes on urban areas with no constructions, such as a piece of land.
  • 4
    This study does not aim at discussing the concept of efficiency mainly because it can be understood in many different ways. This term, as well as the terms “inefficiency” and “super efficiency” are used in a generic way, only to differentiate what is on the dispersion graphs.
  • 13
    {Translated version} Note: All quotes in English translated by this article’s translator.
  • 14
    Tis article is a modifed, updated, and reduced version of a research originally developed for the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy in 2013.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Sep-Oct 2017

History

  • Received
    25 Feb 2016
  • Accepted
    10 July 2017
Fundação Getulio Vargas Fundaçãoo Getulio Vargas, Rua Jornalista Orlando Dantas, 30, CEP: 22231-010 / Rio de Janeiro-RJ Brasil, Tel.: +55 (21) 3083-2731 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: rap@fgv.br