Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Determinants of fiscal transfers to municipal units: effects of malapportionment of brazilian electoral districts

Abstract

The disproportionate representation of electoral districts has an effective influence on the distribution of public resources to the overrepresented regions, which shows that public spending is driven by political and institutional factors. Therefore, the objective of this article is to analyze the products of institutional factors, notably disproportionate non-legislative representation on the transfers to Brazilian municipalities. We used statistical econometric regression with panel data. Brazilian municipalities were analyzed considering the period from 2004 to 2014. The results indicate that the effect of malapportionment in the National Congress on discretionary federal and state expenditures is significant, which demonstrates that the representation structure guides political motivation and the actions of Brazilian public management.

Keywords:
malapportionment; discretionary transfers; Brazilian municipalities

Resumo

A representação desproporcional dos distritos eleitorais tem efetiva influência sobre a distribuição de recursos públicos em benefício das regiões sobrerrepresentadas, o que evidencia que os gastos públicos são dirigidos por fatores políticos e institucionais. Diante disso, o objetivo deste artigo é analisar os efeitos de fatores institucionais, notadamente da representação desproporcional no Poder Legislativo, nas transferências em direção aos municípios brasileiros. Empregou-se a técnica estatística de regressão econométrica com dados em painel, tendo como unidade de análise os municípios brasileiros no período de estudo de 2004 a 2014. Os resultados apontam expressivo efeito da desproporcionalidade representativa no Congresso Nacional nas despesas discricionárias federais e estaduais, o que demonstra que a estrutura da representação orienta as motivações políticas e as ações dos gestores públicos brasileiros.

Palavras-chave:
representação desproporcional; transferências discricionárias; municípios brasileiros

Resumen

La representación desproporcionada de distritos electorales tiene una influencia efectiva en la distribución de recursos públicos en beneficio de las regiones sobrerrepresentadas, lo que pone de manifiesto que los gastos públicos están dirigidos por factores políticos e institucionales. El objetivo de este artículo es analizar los efectos de factores institucionales, notablemente de la representación desproporcionada en el Legislativo, sobre las transferencias hacia los municipios brasileños. Se empleó la técnica estadística de regresión econométrica con datos en panel. La unidad de análisis son los municipios brasileños y el período es de 2004 a 2014. Los resultados apuntan que el efecto de la desproporcionalidad representativa en el Congreso Nacional sobre los gastos discrecionales federales y estatales es expresivo, lo que demuestra que la estructura de la representación orienta las motivaciones políticas y las acciones gestoras públicas brasileñas.

Palabras clave:
representación desproporcionada; transferencias discrecionales; municipios brasileños

1. Introduction

The literature on intergovernmental relations in Brazilian federalism has highlighted a connection between political factors and transfers, especially discretionary ones. High-caliber studies address the subject, but typically focus on transfers to states and regions. Our investigation sheds light on the constraints of tax transfers of central and state governments towards their municipalities. This article aims to analyze the effects of institutional factors, focusing on disproportionate representation in the legislative branch, and fiscal transfers to Brazilian municipalities.

Intergovernmental fiscal transfers represent an important source of revenue for the federative entities, especially those of low-level capacity, unlike large districts, whose local taxes support most of their budgets. It is expected that distribution of resources among the electoral districts would be based on equity between the various regions of the country, favoring the poorest regions. However, there is a connection between political issues and allocation of public resources, characterizing the political nature of fiscal transfers.

Existing studies have attempted to identify this connection, for example Amorim and Simonassi (2013Amorim, O Neto ; & Simonassi, A. G. (2013). Bases políticas das transferências intergovernamentais no Brasil (1985-2004). Revista de Economia Política, 33(4), 704-725.), Arretche and Rodden (2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.), Gibson, Calvo and Falleti (2004Gibson, E. L., Calvo, E. F., & Falleti, T. G. (2004). Reallocative federalism: territorial overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 173-193). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.), Soares and Neiva (2011Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.), and Turgeon and Cavalcante (2014Turgeon, M., & Cavalcante, P. (2014). Desproporcionalidade da representação dos estados no Congresso Nacional e seus efeitos na alocação dos recursos federais (Texto para Discussão n. 1980). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada. ). Among the variables affecting direct intergovernmental transfer decisions, there is consensus among the authors cited that overrepresentation of electoral districts has a considerable effect on the distribution of public funds — that is, the states overrepresented in the legislation are those that receive the most benefit. They receive a greater proportion of constitutional and discretionary fiscal transfers, although these are not necessarily distributive.

Thus, it is important to analyze what influences the pattern of fiscal transfers between government spheres, both institutional and political, considering the disproportionate representation in legislative power. Economic aspects must also be considered, emphasizing variables that would signal a fiscal transfer’s redistributive character.

Because it is widely accepted in the literature that distribution of discretionary resources is biased by political negotiations, the present study considers the hypothesis that these resources are an important governmental instrument to achieve political objectives.

To test the established hypothesis and achieve the proposed objective of the study, we used the statistical econometric regression technique, with data presented in a panel. This study covers the period between 2004 and 2014, and the sample includes all Brazilian municipalities that presented data for the analysis variables.

Following the introduction, this article is divided into five additional parts. First, we summarize the theoretical foundations of resource distribution and the disproportionate representation of electoral districts, as well as the institutional and political elements that influence the pattern of fiscal transfers from the central government to local governments. We then discuss the methodology used for empirical analysis, followed by results and analyses. Finally, we present the main conclusions of the study.

2. Intergovernmental fiscal transfer system

With the decentralization process and fiscal federalism favored by the 1988 Constitution, the federal authorities gained greater autonomy and fiscal responsibility, as well as greater accountability regarding provision of public goods and services. According to Arretche (2005Arretche, M. (2005). Quem taxa e quem gasta: a barganha federativa na Federação brasileira. Sociologia e Política, 2005(24), 69-85.), the fiscal decentralization fundamentally changed the foundations of the local government’s authority, expanding local authority on fiscal resources and tax authority on taxes of significant importance.

Brazil is a country with differences between jurisdictions, resulting in strong territorial inequality. Given this, a number of federal resources in the country aim to maintain the federal balance (Souza, 2003Souza, C. (2003). Federalismo e conflitos distributivos: disputa dos estados por recursos orçamentários federais. Dados, 46(2), 345-384.). Among these resources are intergovernmental transfers, highlighted as a way to seek greater efficiency of the public sector in implementing policies and services and as a mechanism to balance public finances. They are relevant in federal regimes in which fiscal management looks to collect taxes and spend budgets equitably and efficiently, adjusting the distribution of resources.

Through intergovernmental fiscal transfers, the federal government supposedly takes the role of reducing interregional inequalities and inequal access to public services. In Brazil, where territorial inequality is significant,1 1 Souza (2003) demonstrates inequality indicators in the Brazilian municipalities, highlighting that inequalities are found not only among the five regions of the country, but also within a single region or similar state. These differences may be found according to the distribution of the population of the municipalities; the greatest differences are found in the northeast, where the number of small municipalities (population between 10,000 and 20,000 inhabitants) is quite high compared to other regions. the ability of various municipalities to provide public services would be fairly uneven without such transfers (Arretche, 2010Arretche, M. (2010). Federalismo e igualdade territorial: uma contradição em termos? Dados, 53(3), 587-620.).

Intergovernmental fiscal transfers may be classified into two major categories: compulsory and discretionary. They are determined constitutionally or legally, as well as in negotiations between central and subnational governments. Resources are provided to another federal entity as a form of financial cooperation, aid, or assistance.

Gasparini and Miranda (2006Gasparini, C. E., & Miranda, R. (2006). B. Evolução dos aspectos legais e dos montantes de transferências realizadas pelo fundo de participação dos municípios (Texto para Discussão n. 1243). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada.) note some reasons for establishing these transfers, such as balancing tax collection capacity and public spending needs. This must be done with consideration for distribution between government spheres, reduction of regional differences throughout the national territory, and better management of public resources in each sphere of government: the union, states, and municipalities.

Soares and Neiva (2011Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.) observe that federal discretionary transfers are important revenue sources in Brazilian state budgets. They account for approximately 3% of taxes and 9% of constitutional transfers. However, the importance of these transfers differs by state according to regional economic disparities—for example, in the state of Sergipe, discretionary fiscal transfers account for almost 70% of the taxes collected, whereas in São Paulo, they account for less than 0.2%. This is because transfers are made to correct regional disparities, seeking to improve and increase the provision of public goods and guaranteeing the budget balance of the less-favored federal entities with lower tax collection capacity.

Nevertheless, the redistributive aspect of federal transfers is controversial, particularly with respect to compulsory transfers, as shown by some existing literature.

The redistributive aspect of nondiscretionary transfers is supported by the investigations of Soares and Neiva (2011Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.), who found that the three states of São Paulo, Minas Gerais, and Rio de Janeiro together, which together collect over 50% of the total taxes collected by the other states, are also those that receive less than 30% of constitutional transfers. The states in the northeast, which collect approximately 14% of the overall taxes, receive more than 30% of the total constitutional transfers. Arretche and Rodden (2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.) came to a similar conclusion when investigating constitutional transfers; Gibson, Calvo, and Falleti (2004Gibson, E. L., Calvo, E. F., & Falleti, T. G. (2004). Reallocative federalism: territorial overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 173-193). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.) found a moderately positive relationship between nondiscretionary spending and poverty variables, and a negative relationship between such expenses and per capita income.

Soares and Neiva (2011Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.) state that the regions of less economic development (north, northeast, and central-west, respectively) receive a higher percentage of discretionary transfers; however, Gibson et al. (2004Gibson, E. L., Calvo, E. F., & Falleti, T. G. (2004). Reallocative federalism: territorial overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 173-193). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.) did not find a significant relationship between discretionary spending and poverty, nor among these expenditures and per capita income. According to Arretche and Rodden (2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.), the distribution of discretionary transfers does not benefit the poorest states, and thus “it is not determined by needs criteria.” In this light, Amorim and Simonassi (2013Amorim, O Neto ; & Simonassi, A. G. (2013). Bases políticas das transferências intergovernamentais no Brasil (1985-2004). Revista de Economia Política, 33(4), 704-725.) and Turgeon and Cavalcante (2014Turgeon, M., & Cavalcante, P. (2014). Desproporcionalidade da representação dos estados no Congresso Nacional e seus efeitos na alocação dos recursos federais (Texto para Discussão n. 1980). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada. ) identify a tendency to maintain interregional inequalities. The transfer of resources to the states seems to be driven more by political factors than the socioeconomic characteristics of the subnational units or criteria to reduce interregional inequalities.

The economic and political impacts of the two major transfer categories (compulsory and discretionary) differ. Compulsory transfers function as methods to redistribute resources, whereas discretionary transfers play a supplementary, emergency-adjustment role. For these transfers, the political factor appears to be more relevant. “The orientation to reduce disparities or equalize revenue distribution is an additional attribute that redistributive transfers may or may not take” (Prado, 2001Prado, S. (2001). Transferências fiscais e financiamento municipal no Brasil. Projeto Descentralização Fiscal e Cooperação Financeira Intergovernamental (Relatório de Pesquisa). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Fundação Konrad Adenauer., p. 4).

The following section focuses on discretionary transfers, in which the effects of disproportionate electoral district representation can be seen.

3. Transfers and disproportionate electoral district representation

Disproportionate representation of the electoral districts has a decisive influence on the distribution of resources to them; empirical studies have shown that a greater volume of transfers are sent to overrepresented subnational units, which are less populous and economically developed.

This disproportionality is viewed as a discrepancy between the proportion of the legislative seats occupied by the district and its population in the country. In Brazil and other countries, less-populated units are overrepresented in the national legislation because they occupy proportionally more seats than the most populous units (Kauchakje, 2017Kauchakje, S. (2017). Representação distrital e coalizões legislativas: o impacto da sobrerrepresentação nas votações no Congresso brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade Federal de São Carlos, São Carlos, SP.; Samuels & Snyder, 2001Samuels, D. J., & Snyder, R. (2001). The value of a vote: malapportionment in comparative perspective. British Journal of Political Science, 31(4), 651-671.).

In the Brazilian National Congress, districts territorially coincide with the states. In the two houses of the federal legislature, the Chamber of Deputies and the Senate, electoral district representation is disproportionate — that is, for each of the country’s 27 districts, the proportion of the population does not correspond with the proportion of seats occupied.

In the Chamber of Deputies, regulations allow each district a minimum of eight and a maximum of 70 representatives; in the Senate, each district may elect three senators. The Legislative Assembly, representatives of the state legislature, has a number of members corresponding to three times the state’s representation in the Chamber of Deputies. When this number reaches 36, the number of federal members exceeding 12 is added to it.

According to Samuels and Snyder (2001Samuels, D. J., & Snyder, R. (2001). The value of a vote: malapportionment in comparative perspective. British Journal of Political Science, 31(4), 651-671.), the democratic principle of “one person, one vote” is normally violated, especially in federations with bicameral organization. For example, a district that accounts for 20% of the country’s votes does not always occupy 20% of the seats in the legislature; this means that the votes may not translate to political representation (Turgeon & Cavalcante, 2014Turgeon, M., & Cavalcante, P. (2014). Desproporcionalidade da representação dos estados no Congresso Nacional e seus efeitos na alocação dos recursos federais (Texto para Discussão n. 1980). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada. ).

The subnational units are found to have disproportionate representation—that is, some are underrepresented and others overrepresented. In the more populous states, the proportion of seats versus population is much smaller than in the less-populated states. The large states are underrepresented, and the smaller states are overrepresented, illustrating what is known as malapportionment in the English-language literature.

When legislative representation is distributed among electoral districts, it is common that electoral rules lead to a degree of disproportionate representation in relation to the size of the population, even disregarding demographic changes over the years; some districts gain more representation than they would with proportionate representation of true population. Thus, the value of one vote in overrepresented states is greater than in underrepresented states, since a smaller number of votes is needed to elect a representative in such states (Turgeon & Cavalcante, 2014Turgeon, M., & Cavalcante, P. (2014). Desproporcionalidade da representação dos estados no Congresso Nacional e seus efeitos na alocação dos recursos federais (Texto para Discussão n. 1980). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada. ). When Samuels and Snyder (2001Samuels, D. J., & Snyder, R. (2001). The value of a vote: malapportionment in comparative perspective. British Journal of Political Science, 31(4), 651-671.) investigated district representation in 78 countries, they found that most countries exhibit disproportionality, especially those in Latin America.2 2 In the ranking of disproportionate Senate representation among the 78 sample countries, Argentina, Brazil, and Bolivia take the first, second, and third place, respectively. In the ranking of disproportionate representation in Congress, Brazil takes 17th place (Samuels & Snyder, 2001, 2004).

National and international studies, such as those performed by Amorim and Simonassi (2013Amorim, O Neto ; & Simonassi, A. G. (2013). Bases políticas das transferências intergovernamentais no Brasil (1985-2004). Revista de Economia Política, 33(4), 704-725.), Ansolabehere, Gerber and Snyder (2002Ansolabehere, S; Gerber, A; & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American States. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 767-777.), Arretche and Rodden (2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.), Gibson et al. (2004Gibson, E. L., Calvo, E. F., & Falleti, T. G. (2004). Reallocative federalism: territorial overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 173-193). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.), Kauchakje (2017Kauchakje, S. (2017). Representação distrital e coalizões legislativas: o impacto da sobrerrepresentação nas votações no Congresso brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade Federal de São Carlos, São Carlos, SP.), Lee (1998Lee, F. E. (1998). Representation and public policy: the consequences of Senate apportionment for the geographic distribution of federal funds. The Journal of Politics, 60(1), 34-62.), and Turgeon and Cavalcante (2014Turgeon, M., & Cavalcante, P. (2014). Desproporcionalidade da representação dos estados no Congresso Nacional e seus efeitos na alocação dos recursos federais (Texto para Discussão n. 1980). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada. ), have presented extensive evidence of tax imbalances favoring overrepresented units.

Ansolabehere et al. (2002Ansolabehere, S; Gerber, A; & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American States. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 767-777.), Lee (1998Lee, F. E. (1998). Representation and public policy: the consequences of Senate apportionment for the geographic distribution of federal funds. The Journal of Politics, 60(1), 34-62.), Gibson et al. (2004Gibson, E. L., Calvo, E. F., & Falleti, T. G. (2004). Reallocative federalism: territorial overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 173-193). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.), and Turgeon and Cavalcante (2014Turgeon, M., & Cavalcante, P. (2014). Desproporcionalidade da representação dos estados no Congresso Nacional e seus efeitos na alocação dos recursos federais (Texto para Discussão n. 1980). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada. ) examined federal government allocation of resources to subnational units and found that overrepresented subnational entities tend to receive more federal resources per capita compared to those who are underrepresented—that is, the number of legislative seats in relation to the population determines the allocation of government resources.

Amorim and Simonassi (2013Amorim, O Neto ; & Simonassi, A. G. (2013). Bases políticas das transferências intergovernamentais no Brasil (1985-2004). Revista de Economia Política, 33(4), 704-725.) hypothesized that intergovernmental transfers are an important mechanism used by the federal executive branch to achieve political objectives, highlighting that these objectives prevail over socioeconomic equity criteria; higher levels of per capita transfers are associated with the political composition of government coalitions.

Similarly, Kauchakje (2017Kauchakje, S. (2017). Representação distrital e coalizões legislativas: o impacto da sobrerrepresentação nas votações no Congresso brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade Federal de São Carlos, São Carlos, SP.) showed that the legislative bargaining model is used to explain the favoring of overrepresented states in distribution of public resources. This is conditioned by the participation of congressmen from these states in legislative coalitions.

Arretche and Rodden (2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.) studied the influence of electoral and legislative policies on distribution of Brazilian intergovernmental transfers and found that Brazilian presidents exercise great authority on tax transfers and incentives to exchange federal spending for legislative votes. Thus, the distribution of intergovernmental transfers is an important tool for obtaining parliamentary support.

Intergovernmental transfers are a financial aid mechanism to mitigate budgetary constraints in federative entities with low capacity for tax collection. The overrepresented units generally collect the smallest figures in local taxes. However, large districts have higher collection capacity, as their local taxes support the majority of their budget resources.

Both discretionary and compulsory transfers are vital in supplementing the budgets and implementing policies in subnational governments with less fiscal capacity and low economic development.

Kauchakje (2017Kauchakje, S. (2017). Representação distrital e coalizões legislativas: o impacto da sobrerrepresentação nas votações no Congresso brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade Federal de São Carlos, São Carlos, SP.) found a correspondence between overrepresentation, underrepresentation, and development level. In overrepresented states with low development indicators, the correspondence is 36.8% in Congress (68.4% of the Senate, 31.6% of the Chamber of Deputies); all the states in this group are from the north, northeast, and central-west regions.

Because the overrepresented units perform less in economic development, a greater volume of resources directed to these locations is justified in pursuit of territorial equity (Kauchakje, 2017Kauchakje, S. (2017). Representação distrital e coalizões legislativas: o impacto da sobrerrepresentação nas votações no Congresso brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade Federal de São Carlos, São Carlos, SP.). Soares and Neiva (2011Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.) show that in Brazil, the regions that receive a greater percentage of transfers are the less-developed ones (the north, northeast, and center-west, respectively).

The disproportionate representation of electoral districts has an effective influence on distribution of public resources to the benefit of overrepresented regions. Overrepresented states benefit most from discretionary transfers. This suggests that public spending is driven by political and institutional factors (such as disproportional representation). Therefore, it does not necessarily reflect the characteristics of the subnational units.

3.1 STANDARDS FOR FEDERAL AND STATE TRANSFERS TO MUNICIPALITIES: INSTITUTIONAL AND POLITICAL ELEMENTS

It is expected that institutional mechanisms for balancing public finances, such as tax transfers, are operated to support equity between the various regions of the country, and thus favor the poorest regions. However, there is a connection between political issues and allocation of public resources, characterizing the nature of fiscal transfers as political.

According to Amorim and Simonassi (2013Amorim, O Neto ; & Simonassi, A. G. (2013). Bases políticas das transferências intergovernamentais no Brasil (1985-2004). Revista de Economia Política, 33(4), 704-725.), it is preferable to direct transfers to locations that are more politically relevant rather than those that require the resources most. According to Gibson et al. (2004Gibson, E. L., Calvo, E. F., & Falleti, T. G. (2004). Reallocative federalism: territorial overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 173-193). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.), when resources are transferred to serve political interests, to the detriment of the economic needs of subnational entities, federalism is reallocative rather than proportional.

The political factors directing tax transfers relate to the budgetary process. The rules for presenting amendments to the budget limit the ability of each congressperson to influence the distribution of resources according to his or her geographical and electoral preferences (Kauchakje, 2017Kauchakje, S. (2017). Representação distrital e coalizões legislativas: o impacto da sobrerrepresentação nas votações no Congresso brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade Federal de São Carlos, São Carlos, SP.). Even investment spending, which comprises a smaller share of the budget, is determined by the executive power (Figueiredo & Limongi, 2008Figueiredo, A. C., & Limongi, F. (2008). Política orçamentária no presidencialismo de coalizão. Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Ed. FGV.).

The Brazilian executive branch, however, plays a central role in the budgetary process, as it is authorized to veto the approved budget and executes with a discretionary margin. For discretionary transfers, this margin is normally unrestricted with respect to the amount and purpose of the transfer (Limongi & Figueiredo, 2005Limongi, F., & Figueiredo, A. C. (2005). Processo orçamentário e comportamento legislativo: emendas individuais, apoio ao Executivo e programas de governo. Dados, 48(4), 737-776.; Soares & Neiva, 2011Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.).

The central government’s strategy to transfer more resources to the overrepresented states may be linked to obtaining parliamentary support to form political coalitions. Because resource allocation to improve infrastructure in the subnational entities generates impacts only in the long term, it holds weakened incentive for the central government (Amorim & Simonassi, 2013Amorim, O Neto ; & Simonassi, A. G. (2013). Bases políticas das transferências intergovernamentais no Brasil (1985-2004). Revista de Economia Política, 33(4), 704-725.).

Political actors are urged to exchange spending for legislative support, aiming to win political office, remain in power, or integrate majority legislative coalitions. Thus, the distribution of intergovernmental transfers is a valuable tool to achieve these political objectives (Arretche & Rodden, 2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.).

As previously mentioned, because most studies focus on transfers to states and regions, we intend to extend the previous contributions with this study, taking the Brazilian municipalities as a unit of analysis. The effects of institutional, political, and economic variables will be examined with respect to transfers from the central and state governments to municipalities.

4. Methodology

To test the established hypothesis and achieve the aim proposed in this study, we used the statistical econometric regression technique, with data presented in a panel. A spatial analysis of clusters was performed to supplement the study. The study period is from 2004 to 2014, and the sample, composed of the Brazilian municipalities, was defined according to the availability of data at the municipal level. After selecting the variables, models were developed to measure the effect of independent or explanatory variables on the variable to be explained.

4.1 DATA

Data were collected for the period from 1988 (implementation of the Federal Constitution) to 2014. However, for statistical estimates, the study period began in 2004, the year in which it became possible to distinguish compulsory from discretionary transfers.

When working with several observation units over a long period of time, as in this study, data for important variables may not be available in certain years. In the present case, constraining the sample to those municipalities with data for all variables during the analysis period would result in a very small number of observations, hindering the heterogeneity desired in a longitudinal study. Thus, the sample size was increased by using statistical tests with an unbalanced panel, meaning that for each municipality of the sample, different numbers of temporal data are found.

The samples used for each year of the analysis period were as follows: in 2004, 4608 municipalities; in 2005, 4548 municipalities; in 2006, 4990 municipalities; in 2007, 4831 municipalities; in 2008, 4908 municipalities; in 2009, 4881 municipalities; in 2010, 4915 municipalities; in 2011, 4613 municipalities; in 2012, 4567 municipalities; in 2013, 4757 municipalities; and in 2014, 4542 municipalities. Ultimately, it was possible to work with an average of 4741 municipalities.3 3 The loss of municipalities is due to the absence of data, but this does not harm the results: the sample adopted in this study maintains the regional diversity that characterizes Brazil. The municipalities emancipated during the study period were excluded from the sample.

Furthermore, we excluded large municipalities with a population above 300,000 inhabitants from the sample because they are considered discrepant and may cause statistical model estimation problems.4 4 In the exploratory analysis of the data, the results for the large municipalities present a substantial discrepancy among the others. This could cause distortions in the inferential analysis. To define the cutoff number of inhabitants for large municipalities, the National Treasury classification criteria were adopted. The following population groupings are proposed: a) population below 50,000 inhabitants; b) population between 50,000 and 300,000 inhabitants; d) population between 300,000 and 1,000,000 inhabitants; e) population above 1,000,000 inhabitants.

Data for the study were obtained from the Brazilian Finance Report by the National Treasury Secretariat (FINBRA), the Brazilian Institute of Geography and Statistics (IBGE), the database of the Institute of Applied Economic Research (Ipeadata), and the Superior Electoral Court (TSE).

4.2 STATISTICAL TECHNIQUE

Econometric regression models were estimated with unbalanced panel data. The models adopted had fixed effects,5 5 The procedures for adopting the most appropriate model are described in detail in section 4.3, which defines the statistical variables and models. and calculations were conducted using the Stata 13 software.

The mathematical expression for the model may be represented as a linear equation in the form:

Y i t = β 0 + δ 0 D 1 t δ 1 X 1 i t + β 2 X 2 i t + β 3 X 3 i t + α i + u i t i = 1 , X ; t = 2004 , , 2014

where i represents the i-th unit of the cross-sectional cut and t the t-th period of time; Y is the variable dependent on the independent (explanatory) variables represented by X; β0 is the model constant; D is a dummy variable; β1 , β2 , and β3 are parameters determined from the observed data, and δ is used to emphasize the interpretation of the parameters that multiply dummy variables; variable αi captures all factors that were not observed, constant in time, that affect Y it ; Y it determines that the model is of fixed effects, since αi is fixed over time; and finally, u it is the temporal variation error, as it represents non-observed factors that change over time and affect Y it .

4.3 DEFINITION OF VARIABLES AND THE ECONOMETRIC MODEL

The variables to be explained were established based on the classification of transfers as compulsory or discretionary.7 7 The transfer values were established in accordance with the competence criterion, with pledged values without accrued liability. . According to Brazilian official agencies, transfers imposed in the Federal Constitution may be considered compulsory,8 8 Examples of compulsory transfers: Municipal Share Fund (FPM); Rural Property Territorial Tax (RPTT); Industrialized Products Tax (IPT); Intervention on Economic Domain Contribution; Education Salary Contribution; Tax on Operations with Credit, Exchange, and Insurance or Operations Related to Bonds or Securities on Gold; Financial Compensation Transfers due to Exploitation of Natural Resources; Resource Transfers from the Education Development National Fund (EDNF); Financial Transfers from ICMS — Reduction of tax burden — Supplementary Law no. 87/1996; etc. . which are those imposed by the Federal Constitution; provided for by law; or discretionary, which are further classified as specific,9 9 Examples of specific transfers: Unified Health System (UHS) transfers; Social Welfare National Fund Resources (SWNFR); etc. . by delegation,10 10 Examples of transfers by delegation: Transfers to public consortia; transfers of covenants related to the Unified Health System (UHS); transfers of covenants from the Union to Social Welfare Programs; etc. . or voluntary.

The dependent variable was separated in this study to establish a clear division between the granting of transfers, facilitating analysis of resource transfers with legal and constitutional determinations and the granting of transfers upon which the executive branch has discretionary power.

Analysis focuses on voluntary transfers of resources provided as cooperation, financial aid, or assistance. They are not constitutionally or legally determined, nor are they resources intended for the Unified Health System.11 11 We chose not to address specific and delegated transfers. For many municipalities, this variable was not reported in the FINBRA database. This would result in many missing values in the sample, damaging statistical estimations. Moreover, these transfers represent a very small value compared to the total value of discretionary transfers. . It is in discretionary transfers that the effect of overrepresentation on legislative bargaining each year is observable. According to Arretche and Rodden (2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.), the federal executive branch has a substantial degree of discretion with respect to this type of transfer, deciding where the resources are intended to go and when the transfers will be executed. Other types of transfers may also be affected by overrepresentation, but this effect is applied differently and at different times.

The main independent variable used in the model was to test the hypothesis that the municipalities of overrepresented states are those that receive a greater amount of transferred resources.

The variable was built using the relative representation index (RRI) of the states in Congress, which would be related to the amount of tax transfers to states and their municipalities. The index formula will be presented further below.

The empirical research data presented by the existing literature support the use of RRI_states as a relevant measure for the analysis proposed here. The state governments, especially those administrations with low economic performance and overrepresentation, count on transfers received from the central government when composing their budgets to carry out municipal public policies (Soares & Neiva, 2011Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.). As for legislative behavior, a portion (albeit small, compared to the total of the budget) of the voluntary resources for the states is also derived from individual parliamentary amendments and addressed to specific municipalities (Arretche & Rodden, 2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.; Figueiredo & Limongi 2008Figueiredo, A. C., & Limongi, F. (2008). Política orçamentária no presidencialismo de coalizão. Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Ed. FGV.). This means that congresspeople at the federal level act upon both national and state matters that may be of interest to local populations. The endeavor to bring tangible resources to their states and specific municipalities is regarded as part of the representatives’ strategy in seeking votes, and it thus guides their parliamentary activity. Each (Cheibub, Figueiredo, & Limongi, 2009Cheibub, J. A.; Figueiredo, A.; & Limongi, F. (2009). Political parties and governors as determinants of the behavior of Brazilian legislators. Latin American Politics and Society, 51(1), 1-30.; Lee, 2007Lee, F. E. (2007). Geographic representation and the US Congress. Maryland Law Review, 67(1), 50-61.; Shepsle, 2010Shepsle, K. (2010). Analyzing politics: rationality, behavior, and institutions. New York, NY: W. W. Norton.) congressperson’s career is subject to party pressure, the national government, and the government of his or her home state. The demands of their consolidated electoral circle, or the circle they wish to expand by winning new voters, are also influences.

The disproportionality of the Brazilian states in the National Congress was observed using the Relative Representation Index (RRI) defined by Ansolabehere et al. (2002Ansolabehere, S; Gerber, A; & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American States. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 767-777.), whose formula for calculation is:

R R I = P C s e a t s e l e c t o r a l d i s t r i c t P C s e a t s c o u n t r y

where:

P C s e a t s = s e a t s e l e c t o r a l d i s t r i c t p o p u l a t i o n e l e c t o r a l d i s t r i c t

P C s e a t s c o u n t r y = l e g i s l a t i v e s e a t s c o u n t r y p o p u l a t i o n c o u n t r y

According to Ansolabehere et al. (2002Ansolabehere, S; Gerber, A; & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American States. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 767-777.), there is proportional representation when RRI = 1.0.

A dummy variable was built from RRI, assigning a value of 1 to municipalities of states overrepresented in the Chamber of Deputies, the Legislative Assembly, and the Senate, and value of 0 otherwise.

The differences in legislative representation among the Brazilian states will be detailed in the results section. However, it must be noted that in the Senate, overrepresentation is higher, the number of seats is smaller, and the election system is different. The Senate uses a majority electoral system, in contrast to the proportion electoral system used in the Chamber of Deputies. One or two senators are elected in each election, so the dispute over candidates is smaller. Senators may receive votes from the entire state, whereas deputies run with a range of 7 to 69 votes (as in the state of São Paulo). In these cases, one possible electoral strategy is to form electoral pipelines to guarantee votes according to a specific voter profile (Kinzo, Martins, & Borin, 2004Kinzo, M. A., Martins, J. P., Junior , & Borin I. (2004). Patrones de competencia electoral en la disputa por la Cámara de Diputados en Brasil (1994-2002). América Latina Hoy, 2004(38), 143-162.).

The other explanatory variables were selected from the theoretical literature, including studies by Amorim and Simonassi (2013Amorim, O Neto ; & Simonassi, A. G. (2013). Bases políticas das transferências intergovernamentais no Brasil (1985-2004). Revista de Economia Política, 33(4), 704-725.), Arretche and Rodden (2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.), Gibson et al. (2004Gibson, E. L., Calvo, E. F., & Falleti, T. G. (2004). Reallocative federalism: territorial overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 173-193). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.), and Soares and Neiva (2011Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.).

Again, we would note that the studies cited focus on intergovernmental transfers from the Union to states/districts. This study, in contrast, focuses on transfers from the Union and states to municipalities.

In addition to overrepresentation, political and economic variables are shown in Box 1. We sought to test the strategic behavior of the president and the governor in sending transfers to municipalities. This was done by analyzing the effects according to objectives such as gaining popularity for the government administration and redistributing resources among the poorest regions, as well as the effects of increasing government support.

Box 1
Description of variables in the econometric models

The models were adopted from the selected variables.

I. Determinants of fiscal transfers from the Union to municipalities:

l n ( u o b r i ) i t = β 0 + δ 0 s o b r e c a m i t + δ 0 s o b r e s e n i t + δ 1 e l e p r e s i t + δ 2 e l e m u n i t + β 1 l n ( p e s ) i t + β 2 l n ( i n v ) i t + β 3 l n ( i n c o m e ) i t + α i + u i t (1)

l n ( u v o l ) i t = β 0 + δ 0 s o b r e c a m i t + δ 0 s o b r e s e n i t + δ 1 e l e p r e s i t + δ 2 e l e m u n i t + β 1 l n ( p e s ) i t + β 2 l n ( i n v ) i t + β 3 l n ( i n c o m e ) i t + α i + u i t (2)

II. Determinants of fiscal transfers from states to municipalities:

l n ( e o b r i ) i t = β 0 + δ 0 s o b r e a l i t + δ 1 e l e p r e s i t + δ 2 e l e m u n i t + β 1 l n ( p e s ) i t + β 2 l n ( i n v ) i t + β 3 l n ( i n c o m e ) i t + α i + u i t (3)

l n ( e v o l ) i t = β 0 + δ 0 s o b r e a l i t + δ 1 e l e p r e s i t + δ 2 e l e m u n i t + β 1 l n ( p e s ) i t + β 2 l n ( i n v ) i t + β 3 l n ( i n c o m e ) i t + α i + u i t (4)

The term i = 1,...,x represents the cross-sectional cut (the Brazilian municipalities); the term t = 2004,...,2014 represents the period of time analyzed. The term of error is composed by the model presented, consisting of two elements: αi , the element of the cross-sectional cut, and u it , the combined element of the temporal series and the cross-sectional cut (Gujarati and Porter, 2011Gujarati, D., & Porter, D. C. (2011). Econometria básica (5a ed.). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Elsevier.).

The notation ln indicates that the Napierian logarithm was applied to the dependent and continuous independent variables, obtaining log-line models.13 13 Interpretation of the log-linear coefficient models is in percentage variation. . This functional form seemed to be the most appropriate for the present study. The values of fiscal transfers, government expenditures, and gross domestic product tend to be asymmetric; logarithmic changes of this type of variable reduce both asymmetry and heteroscedasticity. According to Wooldridge (2005Wooldridge, J. M. (2005). Introdução à econometria: uma abordagem moderna. São Paulo, SP: Thomson.), variables that are strictly positive have heteroscedastic distributions; this problem may be mitigated, if not eliminated, by use of the Napierian logarithm. Furthermore, the use of ln “narrows the range of the values of variables, in some cases in considerable amounts. This makes estimates less sensitive to disparate observations on the dependent variable or independent variables” (Wooldridge, 2005, p. 181). Absolute values were corrected by the population and deflated; calculations were made in Brazilian reals per capita from 2014, and the General Price Index of the Getulio Vargas Foundation was used as a deflator.

The models were also estimated with the variables in their original form, and the MacKinnon-White-Davidson (MWD) test was conducted, as proposed by Gujarati (2011Gujarati, D., & Porter, D. C. (2011). Econometria básica (5a ed.). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Elsevier.), to choose between linear and log-linear models. The null hypothesis of the MWD test takes the linear model as the most appropriate, and the alternative hypothesis the log-linear model. Since neither of the models were rejected, we chose the one that achieved better adjustment and parameters with expected signs, adjusted , and improved statistical F. According to Wooldridge (2005Wooldridge, J. M. (2005). Introdução à econometria: uma abordagem moderna. São Paulo, SP: Thomson.), in the functional choice of the model, when none are rejected, can be used for selection.

The models were handled using three methods: Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) for stacked data (pooled data), in which cross-cuts are grouped over time (i.e., all data are stacked and the nature of the cross-sections and temporal series are not considered); fixed effects, in which the heterogeneity of each individual is considered, as each one has a dummy variable representing the intercept; and random effects, in which the differences between units are captured by the end of error. The fixed effects models were adopted for the analyses as they were the most adequate for this study.

5. Results

This section analyzes the effects of political and economic variables, with a focus on overrepresentation in the Brazilian legislature and the granting of public resources, based on the premise that the municipalities of smaller states — those that are overrepresented — receive greater amounts of transfers from both the Union and the states.

The study considered both compulsory and discretionary transfers from the Union and states to municipalities. However, the focus of analysis was voluntary discretionary transfers originating from the Union. This is because transfers from the Union represent a significant proportion of the budgets of local governments.14 14 Giuberti (2005), for example, shows data from the dependence of the subnational governments compared to transfers from the Union. In 2002, 50% of the current revenue from the municipalities was originally derived from this fund. .

As shown below, the results confirm a tendency for the federal and state governments to direct discretionary transfer resources to municipalities according to political criteria. As political needs prevail over socioeconomic needs, this may be a factor in intensifying regional inequalities.

5.1 DISPROPORTIONALITY OF REPRESENTATION IN BRAZILIAN STATES

The Relative Representation Index (RRI) was calculated for the Chamber of Deputies, the Legislative Assembly, and the Senate for each year from 1988 to 2014. To analyze Graph 1, we adapted the classification of Ansolabehere et al. (2002Ansolabehere, S; Gerber, A; & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American States. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 767-777.), modifying the intervals to identify the proportional (RRI > 0.90 and < 1.2), overrepresented (RRI >= 1.2), and underrepresented states (RRI <= 0.90). This adaptation was useful to represent and describe the general characteristics of the Brazilian legislature with respect to disproportionality.

Graph 1 presents the average RRI for the 27 Brazilian states during the period from 1988 to 2014.

Graph 1
AverageRRI for the Chamber of Deputies, Legislative Assembly, and Senate for Brazilian states during the period from 1988 to 2014

The five states with the highest representation indices in the Chamber of Deputies, the Legislative Assembly, and the Senate are located in the North Region: Acre, Amapá, Rondônia, Roraima, and Tocantins. In contrast, the state of São Paulo presents the smallest RRI values, and is the only one underrepresented in the Chamber of Deputies, the Legislative Assembly, and the Senate. The states of Pará, Maranhão, and Santa Catarina are considered proportional in the Chamber of Deputies, Legislative Assembly, and Senate.

It was further found that 67% of the states in the Chamber of Deputies have proportional state representation; most of these are from the Northeast, Southeast and South Regions. In the Senate and the Legislative Assembly, 11% and 19% of states have proportional representation, respectively.

In the Senate and the Legislative Assembly, 59% of states are overrepresented; most of these are in the North Region, followed by the Northeast and Center-West. In the Chamber of Deputies, 30% of states are overrepresented, and São Paulo is the only one underrepresented. No state from the South Region presents RRI > 1.2, and in the Southeast Region, only the state of Espírito Santo is overrepresented in the Senate and the Legislative Assembly. All others are underrepresented or proportional.

The dotted red line in Graph 1 represents RRI >= 1.2 to clearly show the states above this value (those that are overrepresented). The Senate was found to have the largest RRI values, as well as a much higher disproportionality of representation than the Chamber of Deputies. Therefore, it is possible that overrepresentation in the Brazilian Congress is driven by the Senate.

The mapping in Figure 1 was conducted using geoprocessing tools and spatial analysis, and it was designed to support statistical analysis. Voluntary transfers from the Union to municipalities were analyzed using the average from 2004 to 2014.15 15 Maps and cluster spatial analyses were produced for each year of the period analyzed. However, because there were no significant changes in the data during this period, the data are presented using calculation of the average. The objective was to identify if resource transfer is related to overrepresentation in the Brazilian legislature.

From the spatial self-correlation map, we observed the spatialization of different amounts of resources received by Brazilian municipalities. Moran’s I enabled identification of clusters of nearby areas with high or low transfers received per capita. The municipalities in dark red and dark blue form statistically significant groupings, indicating the existence of value clusters. The light red and light blue colors indicate the presence of outliers. The clearest areas are those that did not present statistical significance in calculation of Moran’s I.

Figure 1 shows that the municipalities of states with the largest RRI values (Acre, Amapá, Rondônia, Roraima, and Tocantins) generally receive the largest transfer amounts per capita. The clusters that present high, closely grouped values (high-high clusters) are concentrated in these municipalities. However, the municipalities that present clusters with lower values (low-low clusters) compose the majority of underrepresented states in the Chamber of Deputies, the Legislative Assembly, and the Senate, including Pará, Bahia, Maranhão, Pernambuco, Minas Gerais, Rio de Janeiro, and São Paulo.

Figure 1
Cluster analysis of voluntary transfers per capita from the Union to municipalities (2004 to 2014)

The municipalities considered non-significant do not fit the groupings because their transfer revenue values and the values of the neighboring municipalities vary.

These results break from the existing literature on the subject, as they highlight the influence of overrepresentation in voluntary transfers. Other political factors, such as partisan relationships and coalitions between the federal and local government, may impact transfer of public resources, especially transfers that are discretionary. To better understand the dynamics of resource transfers, more studies focusing on these variables are needed.

The following section presents the estimations of the econometric models with the previously selected variables.

5.2 EFFECTS OF OVERREPRESENTATION ON FEDERAL AND STATE TRANSFERS TO BRAZILIAN MUNICIPALITIES

Some model specification tests were conducted to identify the most appropriate approach, to ensure that results were achieved satisfactorily.

First, the most appropriate model — stacked (pooled), fixed effects, or random effects — was identified; subsequently, the Wald test was used to detect the presence of heteroscedasticity.

Initially, the Chow test was used to determine whether the stacked or fixed effects model was most appropriate. In the stacked model, which uses the OLS form, all coefficients are constant over time and within individuals. In the fixed effects model, the angular coefficients are constant, but the intercept varies between units, remaining constant over time. The result of the Chow test is shown in the F statistics of the fixed effects model estimation, in which the null hypothesis takes the restricted (stacked) model as more appropriate, and the alternative hypothesis the unrestricted (fixed effects) model.

The statistical F of the fixed effects model rejected the null hypothesis that the stacked model is more appropriate. Thus, the alternative hypothesis, proposing that the fixed effects model is preferable to the stacked model in this study, was accepted.

We then tested whether the fixed effects model was also preferable to the random effects model using the Hausman test. Under the null hypothesis of this test, the fixed effects and random effects models are both consistent, but the latter is the more efficient of the two. Under the alternative hypothesis, the random effects model provides inconsistent estimation of the parameters; thus, the difference between the two estimators must be different from zero.

The presuppositions that are made based on the likely correlation between the X regressors and the individual error component define the choice between the fixed or random effects models. If there is correlation, the fixed effects model is the most advisable; if not, the random effects model is (Gujarati, 2011). Thus, the fixed effects model is indicated when the null hypothesis (no correlation between errors) is rejected; in the absence of correlation, the random effects model is recommended.16 16 The results of the Hausman tests are found in Tables 2 and 3.

Table 1
Estimates of transfer models from the Union to the municipalities

The Hausman test provides the estimates of the two models, fixed and random effects, and calculates the difference between their coefficients. According to the chi-square probability, it was possible to reject the null hypothesis, meaning that the random effects estimator is significantly different from the fixed effects estimator; the alternative hypothesis, indicating that the random effects model is inconsistent, was accepted. Thus, the fixed effects statistics provided by the Hausman test are the most appropriate.

We also applied the Wald test, which showed heteroscedasticity in the models, as is common in longitudinal data. The fixed effects models were thus estimated on robust standard errors, a procedure that aims to adjust the standard deviation of the variables to correct the absence of homoscedasticity of the regression residuals. The estimation results are presented below, based on the process and equations previously described.

Table 1 describes the results of estimations to explain the granting of transfers from the Union to municipalities. Model 1 takes compulsory transfers as a dependent variable, and model 2 explains the voluntary transfers.17 17 It is noteworthy that in terms of functional estimation, the results were calculated with the continuous variables in their original form, as well as the log. As in Amorim and Simonassi (2013) and Arretche and Rodden (2004), the models were more robust.

Overall, the regressions were found to be significant. Statistical F, which considers the overall significance of the model, indicates that the independent variables together explain the variance in the dependent variable. The t-values indicate the individual significance of the coefficients; all variables presented statistical significance at the 1% and 5% level except for overrepresentation in the Senate (sobresen). Adjusted 18 18 Adjusted R² is preferable to R² because the latter does not decrease when new independent variables are added to a model. Te adjusted R² formula considers degrees of freedom. Tus, adjusted R² will be smaller than R², but more appropriate (Wooldridge, 2005). . is 95% for model 1 and 36% for model 2. According to Gujarati and Porter (2011Gujarati, D., & Porter, D. C. (2011). Econometria básica (5a ed.). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Elsevier.), interpretation of must be modest—that is, more significant coefficients and expected signs are more valuable than a high . For data involving several observations, low values are common due to diversity in the cross-cut units and the temporal series. Nevertheless, with a significant F, regressors can be considered to influence regression, particularly if the regressors are also individually significant. In model 2, the parameters of the first two explanatory variables employed to verify the effects of overrepresentation in the Chamber of Deputies (sobrecam) and the Senate (sobresen) in the granting of transfers were significant at 1% and presented positive signs; this indicates that the municipalities of overrepresented states in the two legislative bodies benefit more from voluntary transfers from the Union compared to the municipalities of underrepresented states. More specifically, it is estimated that the municipalities of overrepresented states in the Chamber and Senate receive approximately 14% and 13% more in voluntary transfers per capita from the Union, respectively, than the municipalities of underrepresented states. In model 1, which has compulsory transfers as a dependent variable, the sobresen variable is not statistically significant, whereas the sobrecam variable coefficient suggests that the municipalities of overrepresented states in the Chamber receive a lower per capita amount of compulsory transfers (-3.2%) than the municipalities of underrepresented states.

The effects of overrepresentation on the granting of transfers provided for by law are opposite those of voluntary transfers. In compulsory transfers (model 1), overrepresentation causes reduction in resource granting, counter to the effect observed in voluntary transfers (model 2). It is therefore necessary to highlight that “the effect of overrepresentation is not merely an artifact of the rules governing constitutional transfers. It seems to emerge from the bargaining power of the smaller states” (Arretche & Rodden, 2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576., p. 565).

This result was expected, since it aligns with the literature. As mentioned in the theoretical foundations, there is consensus that political leaders preferentially grant tax resources, especially discretionary resources, to the districts that will provide them with more legislative support. In other words, leaders exchange localized spending with electoral and legislative strategies in mind (Arretche & Rodden, 2004Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.). Analysis of the elepres and elemun variables shows that in presidential election years, municipalities receive 6% more voluntary transfers per capita than in the other years, highlighting the existence of electoral cycles in politics. Again, the effects of these variables on compulsory transfers is opposite. Compulsory transfers to municipalities fall in presidential and municipal election years, along with the effects on transfers of voluntary resources in municipal elections.

The expenditure variable coefficients indicate positive elasticities—that is, increases in spending on personnel and investments19 19 The models were estimated without the personnel and investment expenses variables. Their removal did not significantly alter the parameters and relevance of the other regressors. We chose to include them in the models and analyses. . motivates greater transfers of resources, both compulsory and voluntary.

Interestingly, increased investments by municipality public management involve significantly greater amounts of voluntary transfer revenues than compulsory transfer revenues. This indicates that voluntary resource transfers stimulate expenditures in this category.

Because discretionary resources are intended for emergencies, and in most cases, they are intended for investments, it is expected that an increase in this expenditure implies more resources will be directed to these units. Analysis of the pes variable shows that personnel expenses may maximize population approval; in small municipalities, where income generation is low, payroll expenses serve constituent interests. These expenditures guarantee a minimum income to a part of the population, and the municipality is the main local employer. This enables politicians to maintain good electoral performance and political power.

In contrast, the income variable employed as a development proxy tests the theories that predict redistributive results towards the poorest regions. The variable presents positive coefficients in all models, suggesting that an increase in per capita income in the municipalities causes increase in the receipt of compulsory and voluntary transfers.

Table 2 presents estimations of transfers from states to municipalities.

Table 2
Estimations of transfer models from the states to the municipalities

As in the previous interpretations, the focus is on voluntary transfers (model 6). The F and t statistics indicate the significance of the models. values are satisfactory, indicating 95% and 46% of the explanatory power of models 5 and 6, respectively.

The first explanatory variable, sobreal, is a dummy variable for the municipalities of states overrepresented in the Legislative Assembly. It was not statistically significant to explain the receipt of voluntary transfers. The results of model 5 show a positive relationship between sobreal and the dependent variable. This suggests that the municipalities of states overrepresented in the Legislative Assembly receive an average of 9% more transfers of state resources provided for by law than the municipalities of underrepresented states.

The coefficients analyzing the existence of electoral cycles show an increase in the receipt of voluntary state resources in both presidential and municipal election years.

In the models with the dependent variable is in its logarithmic form, and when the coefficient of an independent dummy variable suggests a major proportional change in y, the exact proportional difference may be obtained by calculating semi-elasticity (Wooldridge, 2005Wooldridge, J. M. (2005). Introdução à econometria: uma abordagem moderna. São Paulo, SP: Thomson.). In general, if β1 is the coefficient of a dummy variable, say x1, when ln(y) is the dependent variable, the exact percentage difference in y predicted when x1 = 1 versus when x1 = 0 is calculated using the following formula:

100 . e x p β 1 ' . 1

where exp is the antilogarithm of β1’ (estimated parameter of the dummy variable).

Table 3 shows the results of the semi-elasticity calculation for the elepres and elemun variables20 20 This calculation was completed for dummy variable coefficients with large values. In small-value coefficients, there is no significant change when the most precise estimate is calculated using semi-elasticity. . in model 6.

Table 3
Calculation of semi-elasticity for the elepres and elemun variables of model 6

In presidential election years, there are 38% (most accurate estimate is 46%) more voluntary transfers per capita from the states to the municipalities. In municipal election years, this increase, according to the most precise estimate calculated in Table 3, is approximately 22%. This highlights the existence of political electoral cycles related specifically to the amount of voluntary resources transferred from the states to the municipalities.

The two municipal expenditure headings have a positive relationship with the dependent variables. According to model 6, expenditures on personnel and investments influence the amount of resources transferred to the municipalities similarly — that is, a 1% increase in these expenditures is associated with an increase in transfers of 30% and 41%, respectively. There is an incentive to increase state transfers to municipalities that increase their investment and personnel expenses. It is likely that the transfer of more resources to the municipalities that spend on personnel is motivated by constituent interests.

Finally, the variable that tests the redistributive character of intergovernmental transfers was not statistically significant to explain the transfer of voluntary resources. It has a positive effect on constitutional resources, indicating that transfers are not made according to criteria for promoting equity among the various municipalities analyzed, as shown in previous models.

6. Conclusions

This study aimed to observe the effects of disproportionate representation in the Brazilian legislature on transfer of federal and state resources to municipalities. The main explicative valuable analyzed was overrepresentation. The general hypothesis guiding this research was that the municipalities of overrepresented states are favored in transfers of discretionary resources, because such transfers function as a means of exchange in the legislative bargaining model.

The study’s findings suggest that disproportionate representation in the Chamber of Deputies, the Legislative Assembly, and the Senate is a factor influencing fiscal resource transfer. The municipalities of overrepresented states receive more transfers per capita than the municipalities of underrepresented states. This effect is quantitatively greater when it comes to voluntary transfers. These results are in line with the existing literature, in which smaller municipalities — those of overrepresented states — benefit most from discretionary transfers.

There is evidence that political determinants have prevailed over socioeconomic needs. The most developed municipalities receive more resources (even compulsory transfers), a fact that contradicts the idea of redistribution, identified as reallocative federalism. It is worth noting that not all overrepresented units — those that are less populated — have the lowest development indices.

To conclude, the effect of disproportionate representation in the National Congress on federal and state discretionary expenditures in Brazil is significant. Additionally, the political representation structure has guided the actions of the public administrators of the Union and the Brazilian states. One immediate consequence of this pattern of public resource distribution may be aggravation of interregional inequalities.

REFERÊNCIAS

  • Amorim, O Neto ; & Simonassi, A. G. (2013). Bases políticas das transferências intergovernamentais no Brasil (1985-2004). Revista de Economia Política, 33(4), 704-725.
  • Ansolabehere, S; Gerber, A; & Snyder, J. (2002). Equal votes, equal money: court-ordered redistricting and public expenditures in the American States. American Political Science Review, 96(4), 767-777.
  • Arretche, M. (2005). Quem taxa e quem gasta: a barganha federativa na Federação brasileira. Sociologia e Política, 2005(24), 69-85.
  • Arretche, M. (2010). Federalismo e igualdade territorial: uma contradição em termos? Dados, 53(3), 587-620.
  • Arretche, M.; & Rodden, J. (2004). Política distributiva na federação: estratégias eleitorais, barganhas legislativas e coalizões de governo. Dados, 47(47), 549-576.
  • Cheibub, J. A.; Figueiredo, A.; & Limongi, F. (2009). Political parties and governors as determinants of the behavior of Brazilian legislators. Latin American Politics and Society, 51(1), 1-30.
  • Figueiredo, A. C., & Limongi, F. (2008). Política orçamentária no presidencialismo de coalizão Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Ed. FGV.
  • Gasparini, C. E., & Miranda, R. (2006). B. Evolução dos aspectos legais e dos montantes de transferências realizadas pelo fundo de participação dos municípios (Texto para Discussão n. 1243). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada.
  • Gibson, E. L., Calvo, E. F., & Falleti, T. G. (2004). Reallocative federalism: territorial overrepresentation and public spending in the Western Hemisphere. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 173-193). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
  • Giuberti, A. C. (2005). Lei de Responsabilidade Fiscal: efeitos sobre o gasto com pessoal dos municípios brasileiros Brasília, DF: Escola de Administração Fazendária.
  • Gujarati, D., & Porter, D. C. (2011). Econometria básica (5a ed.). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Elsevier.
  • Kauchakje, S. (2017). Representação distrital e coalizões legislativas: o impacto da sobrerrepresentação nas votações no Congresso brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade Federal de São Carlos, São Carlos, SP.
  • Kinzo, M. A., Martins, J. P., Junior , & Borin I. (2004). Patrones de competencia electoral en la disputa por la Cámara de Diputados en Brasil (1994-2002). América Latina Hoy, 2004(38), 143-162.
  • Lee, F. E. (1998). Representation and public policy: the consequences of Senate apportionment for the geographic distribution of federal funds. The Journal of Politics, 60(1), 34-62.
  • Lee, F. E. (2007). Geographic representation and the US Congress. Maryland Law Review, 67(1), 50-61.
  • Limongi, F., & Figueiredo, A. C. (2005). Processo orçamentário e comportamento legislativo: emendas individuais, apoio ao Executivo e programas de governo. Dados, 48(4), 737-776.
  • Prado, S. (2001). Transferências fiscais e financiamento municipal no Brasil. Projeto Descentralização Fiscal e Cooperação Financeira Intergovernamental (Relatório de Pesquisa). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Fundação Konrad Adenauer.
  • Samuels, D. J., & Snyder, R. (2001). The value of a vote: malapportionment in comparative perspective. British Journal of Political Science, 31(4), 651-671.
  • Samuels, D. J., & Snyder, R. (2004). Legislative malapportionment in Latin America. In E. L. Gibson (Ed.), Federalism and democracy in Latin America (pp. 131-172). Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
  • Shepsle, K. (2010). Analyzing politics: rationality, behavior, and institutions New York, NY: W. W. Norton.
  • Soares, M. M., & Neiva, P. (2011). Federalism and public resources in Brazil: federal discretionary transfers to states. Brazilian Political Science Review, 5(2), 94-116.
  • Souza, C. (2003). Federalismo e conflitos distributivos: disputa dos estados por recursos orçamentários federais. Dados, 46(2), 345-384.
  • Turgeon, M., & Cavalcante, P. (2014). Desproporcionalidade da representação dos estados no Congresso Nacional e seus efeitos na alocação dos recursos federais (Texto para Discussão n. 1980). Brasília, DF: Instituto de Pesquisa Econômica Aplicada.
  • Wooldridge, J. M. (2005). Introdução à econometria: uma abordagem moderna São Paulo, SP: Thomson.
  • 1
    Souza (2003) demonstrates inequality indicators in the Brazilian municipalities, highlighting that inequalities are found not only among the five regions of the country, but also within a single region or similar state. These differences may be found according to the distribution of the population of the municipalities; the greatest differences are found in the northeast, where the number of small municipalities (population between 10,000 and 20,000 inhabitants) is quite high compared to other regions.
  • 2
    In the ranking of disproportionate Senate representation among the 78 sample countries, Argentina, Brazil, and Bolivia take the first, second, and third place, respectively. In the ranking of disproportionate representation in Congress, Brazil takes 17th place (Samuels & Snyder, 2001, 2004).
  • 3
    The loss of municipalities is due to the absence of data, but this does not harm the results: the sample adopted in this study maintains the regional diversity that characterizes Brazil.
  • 4
    In the exploratory analysis of the data, the results for the large municipalities present a substantial discrepancy among the others. This could cause distortions in the inferential analysis. To define the cutoff number of inhabitants for large municipalities, the National Treasury classification criteria were adopted. The following population groupings are proposed: a) population below 50,000 inhabitants; b) population between 50,000 and 300,000 inhabitants; d) population between 300,000 and 1,000,000 inhabitants; e) population above 1,000,000 inhabitants.
  • 5
    The procedures for adopting the most appropriate model are described in detail in section 4.3, which defines the statistical variables and models.
  • 6
    For each year of the temporal cut, there is a different number of observations due to the unbalanced nature of the panel. The number of municipalities used in each annual sample is described in section 4.1.
  • 7
    The transfer values were established in accordance with the competence criterion, with pledged values without accrued liability. .
  • 8
    Examples of compulsory transfers: Municipal Share Fund (FPM); Rural Property Territorial Tax (RPTT); Industrialized Products Tax (IPT); Intervention on Economic Domain Contribution; Education Salary Contribution; Tax on Operations with Credit, Exchange, and Insurance or Operations Related to Bonds or Securities on Gold; Financial Compensation Transfers due to Exploitation of Natural Resources; Resource Transfers from the Education Development National Fund (EDNF); Financial Transfers from ICMS — Reduction of tax burden — Supplementary Law no. 87/1996; etc. .
  • 9
    Examples of specific transfers: Unified Health System (UHS) transfers; Social Welfare National Fund Resources (SWNFR); etc. .
  • 10
    Examples of transfers by delegation: Transfers to public consortia; transfers of covenants related to the Unified Health System (UHS); transfers of covenants from the Union to Social Welfare Programs; etc. .
  • 11
    We chose not to address specific and delegated transfers. For many municipalities, this variable was not reported in the FINBRA database. This would result in many missing values in the sample, damaging statistical estimations. Moreover, these transfers represent a very small value compared to the total value of discretionary transfers. .
  • 12
    To identify the effects of development from the municipalities, we considered using the Municipal Human Development Index (MHDI). However, benchmarking of the results including this variable could cause problems, since it is measured every 10 years. This would compromise the necessary variation required for a panel model with a 10-year temporal series. .
  • 13
    Interpretation of the log-linear coefficient models is in percentage variation. .
  • 14
    Giuberti (2005), for example, shows data from the dependence of the subnational governments compared to transfers from the Union. In 2002, 50% of the current revenue from the municipalities was originally derived from this fund. .
  • 15
    Maps and cluster spatial analyses were produced for each year of the period analyzed. However, because there were no significant changes in the data during this period, the data are presented using calculation of the average.
  • 16
    The results of the Hausman tests are found in Tables 2 and 3.
  • 17
    It is noteworthy that in terms of functional estimation, the results were calculated with the continuous variables in their original form, as well as the log. As in Amorim and Simonassi (2013) and Arretche and Rodden (2004), the models were more robust.
  • 18
    Adjusted is preferable to because the latter does not decrease when new independent variables are added to a model. Te adjusted formula considers degrees of freedom. Tus, adjusted will be smaller than , but more appropriate (Wooldridge, 2005). .
  • 19
    The models were estimated without the personnel and investment expenses variables. Their removal did not significantly alter the parameters and relevance of the other regressors. We chose to include them in the models and analyses. .
  • 20
    This calculation was completed for dummy variable coefficients with large values. In small-value coefficients, there is no significant change when the most precise estimate is calculated using semi-elasticity. .
  • [Translated version] Note: All quotes in English translated by this article’s translator

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Jan-Feb 2019

History

  • Received
    27 Aug 2017
  • Accepted
    05 June 2018
Fundação Getulio Vargas Fundaçãoo Getulio Vargas, Rua Jornalista Orlando Dantas, 30, CEP: 22231-010 / Rio de Janeiro-RJ Brasil, Tel.: +55 (21) 3083-2731 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: rap@fgv.br