1. INTRODUCTION
The issue of corruption currently plays a central role in global debates. Even though it affects all countries, corruption is more significant in the so-called emerging democracies. Instead of prospering towards structures of good governance, the majority of them still cling to laws and practices that favor a monopolization of power. Under the rule of particularistic logic, the state is treated as an asset, and corruption is revealed as a systemic problem (Mungiu-Pippidi, 2013a, 2015).
Resorting to World Bank data (CoC 2012), Mungiu-Pippidi (2013a, 2015) built a governance ranking of 191 countries, showing that positive democracy, which promotes the common good with proper corruption control, prevailed in only 35 countries. In the rest, the winners of the political game consider the state a personal resource benefiting themselves or their peers, using typical strategies of patronage, nepotism, and exchange of favors.
Brazil is one such nation plagued by high levels of corruption. It affects the economic, social, and judicial relations, undermining the trust and social well-being of the population. Despite the State’s efforts since the mid-1980s to promote institutional reforms, to align itself with the internationally prescribed strategies that aim at regulating, devising control structures, and strengthening judicial power, there is no perceived relevant progress. While reforms have taken place in the structure of Brazilian federal accounting and public control systems in the 1980s and 1990s, corruption has remained an everyday practice.
Currently, public bodies of control have unveiled an unprecedented fashion of the spurious relations between private and political Brazilian elites, and the perception about corruption in Brazil has worsened. Corruption indexes are showing a dramatic increase in Brazilian corruption perception since the start of Operation Car Wash in 2014. According to the International Transparency Index, Brazil was in the 69th position in 2014, and the 105th in 2018, falling 35 positions.
In order to understand why robust institutional control systems were not enough for Brazil to overcoming systemic corruption, this article studies the Brazilian case, in the light of the experiences from Sweden and Italy. Two main reasons justify the choice to tackle the Swedish case. First, Sweden has succeeded in overcoming corruption as a systemic problem in the nineteenth century. Second, the Swedish case has been studied by Rothstein for more than ten years, resulting in a consistent approach to systemic corruption. The choice to study the Italian case is based on the country’s relative failure in fighting corruption during the 1990s. Italy went through Operation Clean Hands, which has similarities with Operation Car Wash.
This study resorts to the theories of Bourdieu (1983, 1996, 2014), Tocqueville (2005) and Ostrom (1990), and the perspectives of Rothstein and Mungiu-Pippidi to address the problem of corruption. The research adopted a qualitative approach and an exploratory analysis based on secondary data, using process tracing as a research tool. Process tracing allows scrutiny of processes by which initial conditions are transformed into specific results (Cunha & Araújo, 2018).
The remaining sections of this article are organized as follows. Section 2 provides a brief theoretical introduction to corruption and an overview of the challenge of overcoming systemic corruption as a dilemma of collective action. Section 3 presents the cases of Sweden and Italy, based on information available in scientific papers, international statistical data, and research on multiple websites. Subsequently, in Section 4, the analytical schema provided by the cases of Sweden and Italy is used to analyze the Brazilian case. Finally, Section 5 brings final considerations.
2. HOW CAN A COUNTRY TACKLE SYSTEMIC CORRUPTION?
Corruption plays a central role in the current scientific, political, and economic debates worldwide. However, the concept remains a theoretical challenge (Filgueiras, 2007, 2009; Ferro, 2015; Rothstein & Varraich, 2017). For Rothstein and Varraich (2017), corruption has been found in all times and every society, and the concept is grounded on the sense of opposition to the common good, the decadence of the state’s purpose, and limitations to reach justice. However, there is still no consensual definition for the term “corruption.”
The fields of law, sociology, political science, and economics have particular interpretations of corruption and provide theories to explain the problem. Within the field of law, there are three fundamental ideas around corruption throughout the evolution from the modern state to the rule of law model, a) the separation between the assets of the ruler and those of the state; b) the impersonality of the relations between the public realm and the citizen; and c) the common good as the state’s purpose.
Sociology offers several theories for understanding corruption as a social practice. Pierre Bourdieu, based on his Theory of Practice, argues that the actions of agents can be understood in the reflexivity between structure and agency. In his analysis of public administration, the author supports Weber’s view of the state as the community that successfully claimed a monopoly for the legitimate use of physical violence in a determined territory. For Bourdieu, this claim was only possible because jurists state “what is right,” using universal ideas such as the notion of ‘public interest.’ The concept of public interest emerges as a symbolic capital also monopolized by the state. The author shows that the fundamental ideas brought historically by the jurists have a deep sense of symbolism, which leads people to submit to state authority (Bourdieu, 1996).
People’s submission to the state, however, depends on the population recognizing that the state deserves the symbolic capital it claims to represent. The maintenance of this capital and access to resources it entails requires agents who represent the state to submit to the authority grounded on the same symbolism (or at least appear to submit). In practice, it means that the agents of the state must renounce their private - especially economic - interests. Therefore, Bourdieu (1996) argues that the habitus of the state’s bureaucracy is to work nonstop to make the public agent’s point of view coincide with the point of view that legitimizes the state’s existence (Garcia, 2011).
The challenge for the state is reflected in the gap between the norm and the administrative practices. The distance between norms and practices may be observed through administrative incapacity, delays, influence peddling, and private use of the public sphere. More than two-thirds of the world’s countries still cannot put into practice the state’s promise to promote the common good. In these countries, republicanism is still unstable, and policymaking and implementation may be biased, giving room to ‘systemic corruption.’
The most dominant theoretical approach for the issue of alignment between the symbolic norm and official practices has been the new institutional economics, notably, the rent-seeking theory and the principal-agent theory (Krueger, 1974; Jensen & Meckling, 1976). Based on these theories, Rose-Ackerman (1978, 2002) provided the most influential understanding of corruption, associating it to the abuse of public duties, to the misuse of public resources, and the illegitimate use of political influence by public and private agents. This understanding sheds light on the meaning of the abuse carried out by public and private agents against the public sphere when they act rationally for their own benefit, which harms the public interest. Since the 1990s, these ideas have supported states’ reforms, based on holistic strategies.
Nevertheless, current studies indicate that the economic perspective has not provided a positive response to reforms made in many countries (Stefes, 2007; Rothstein, 2007; Mungiu-Pippidi, 2013a, 2013b; Persson, Rothstein, & Teorell, 2013; Rothstein & Varraich, 2017). Persson, Rothstein, and Teorell (2013) conducted a study on the reasons why the reforms implemented in Uganda and Kenya, since the late 1990s, failed to bring about the intended changes. In the study, the authors warn that the answer lies partly in the inadequacy of assumptions of the reforms, grounded on the principal-agent problem.
The Principal-Agent Theory is the main basis for the creation of mechanisms of institutional control. The theory presupposes the existence of a principal interested in controlling the agent, for the common good. The “principal” can be, for example, the bureaucracy that produces the regulations (institutions), the members of parliament who vote and approve the regulations, the high-echelon public servants who authorize contracts between the public administration and the private sector. The principal may also be a citizen willing to understand the public workings with a view of being an efficient watchdog.
The central problem perceived is that the actions of these principals, in the researched countries, are guided by personal interests. In the absence of the ‘incorruptible principal,’ the reforms proposed under the Agency Theory have failed. In one of Pierre Bourdieu’s last works, in the 90s, he stressed the critical role of the principal, foreseeing that the absence of principals focused on the common good was a relevant limit for the effectiveness of public control systems (Bourdieu, 2014).
More recently, Teorell and Rothstein (2012) defended that, in the context of systemic corruption - where the presence of a principal is uncertain - the Agency Theory needs to be complemented with the collective action approach, and adopted Ostrom’s Theory of Collective Action. One of the collective problems studied by Ostrom was the difficulty of cooperation of a group of fishermen who work in the same lake. As the profit of each of them is directly proportional to the number of fish caught, each fisherman has an incentive to lay as many nets as possible. The long term result from this lack of cooperation may be the decline in fish yield. Ostrom (1990) argues that the problem must be separated into three distinct problems: the problem of who will supply the solution, the problem of credible commitments, and the problem of monitoring. The author proved that, in this case, it is the group of fishermen that can present solutions for each of the three problems.
Rothstein and Teorell, based on the work by Ostrom, studied the Swedish case and advocated that agents with common purposes can act together to “replace the old order with a new one by the force of their own making” (Teorell & Rothstein, 2012, p. 4). The authors considered systemic corruption as a problem of collective action, pointing out the need for a theory to explain how to overcome the problems of collective action and how ‘new rules of the game’ can become dominant practices. For them, even if people realize that everybody might lose with corruption-based choices, they will act in a corrupted way if they believe others will do the same.
Another relevant point of view for this kind of problem is brought by Mungiu-Pippidi, based on Alexis de Tocqueville’s vision of collective action. Observing nineteenth-century American democracy, Tocqueville was convinced that “collective force” was fundamental for creating common good in a state (Tocqueville, 2005, pp. 160, 278, 279). The quality of collective action identified in American society appears in Tocqueville as a consequence of four factors: popular sovereignty, equality and law enforcement to all on equal terms, the associative spirit, and independent press.
In order to test the Tocqueville’s ideas, Mungiu-Pippidi carried out quantitative research with World Values Survey data, between 1995 and 2008. The author found a positive correlation between the number of civil associations and political engagement and the number of civil associations, the existence of independent media, and control of corruption. Then, the author upholds that cooperation and the habit of association generate social capital, which in turn favors collective action (Mungiu-Pippidi, 2013a, 2015). Since the collective force is efficient to broaden trust-based relations, the author defends that level of association is paramount for the development of new rules of the game in societies characterized by systemic corruption.
Three relevant ideas emerged as fundamental to discussing systemic corruption. First, public agents committed to the common good result from a process of social construction, in a reflexivity process between structure and agent, as taught by Bourdieu. Agents interested in the common good are not born ready, they are formed in the socio-historical reflexivity where they live. Second, in countries dominated by systemic corruption, the reform proposals cannot presuppose the existence of the principal to make up the principal-agent relationship. Third, the collective action approaches used respectively by Rothstein and Mungiu-Pippidi bring two different elements. For Rothstein, the solution is the cooperation between institutional agents. For Mungiu-Pippidi, the problem is the ability of society to work in associations and restrict the perverse behavior of the authorities.
The next section of the article analyzes the cases of Sweden and Italy to verify the relevance of the theoretical points and central elements in the results obtained by the countries. These elements will be used to analyze the limits of the public accounting and control systems to address the Brazilian corruption problem in Section 4.
3. THE CASES OF SWEDEN AND ITALY
3.1 The Swedish case
Rothstein has shown that, in the nineteenth century, the Swedish State displayed the characteristics found in systematically corrupted societies. Personal contacts in the “king’s entourage” opened doors, the elites had more access to public office, obedience and abidance to laws and norms were not the common, and public jobs were regarded as property. Rothstein also shows that Sweden’s transition into the condition of a country with proper corruption control did not occur incrementally or by sectors, as shown in Box 1.
The transition was carried out in less than 30 years, starting in the mid-nineteenth century, but the reasons for the social transformation lie in the trauma and losses that the country had with the war with Russia in the years 1808-1809 (Teorell & Rothstein, 2012). Citing the writer August Strindberg, the author states that in the novel The Red Room, published in 1879, a character is a public servant. The description reveals the stereotypes of laziness and inefficiency, but no longer corruption as a feature associated with the State.
The change has remained historically. The country always ranks well in governance and corruption control indexes. It ranks third in the 2018 TI Index, and the 2012 Governance Index, proposed by Mungiu-Pippidi (2015), it appears in the third position, close behind New Zealand and Denmark.
Teorell and Rothstein (2012, p. 8) studied this Swedish transition and presented a new theory to explain how new rules of the social game can become dominant practices. Based on Ostrom (1990), they suggest an endogenous theory of institutional change. The argument is that state agents may “become alert of the collection action problem they are facing, and the collective costs they bear for retaining their corrupt and dysfunctional equilibrium behavior, and thereby themselves work out solutions that enable them to break out of this equilibrium” For the authors, overcoming corruption does not automatically occur solely from the efficiency of institutional control mechanisms. If efficient institutional devices “will make a country start spinning on a new path that leads it out of systemic corruption,” more countries would have succeeded in curbing systemic corruption (Rothstein, 2007, p. 4).

Source: Elaborated by the authors, based on Rothstein (2007), Teorell and Rothstein (2012) and Guimarães (2016).
Box 2 Swedish Path of Change
Besides the cooperation between institutional agents cited by Teorell and Rothstein (2012), history shows the presence of great collective force in Sweden through the years. Sweden has always experienced strong levels of cooperation among social groups. There were never periods of slavery or servitude in the country, nor periods in which the peasant class was marginalized from institutional decision-making (Guimarães, 2016). Mungiu-Pippidi (2013a, 2015) argues that this habit of living together generates social capital, which in turn favors the force necessary to constrain economic, political, and bureaucratic elites to change their practices.
Box 2shows three elements that emerge from the Swedish case, and they are important to promote the changes that may lead a country out of systemic corruption. These elements are a trigger that can provoke the possibility of sustainable cooperation among institutional decision-makers, an adequate level of institutional capacity, and a strong collective force.
3.2 The Italian case
Italy’s most recognized attempt to deal with corruption occurred in the 1990s with Operation Clean Hands. It came four years after the significant criminal procedural reform that began to provide, among others, the possibility of the instrument of cooperation agreement (Vasconcellos, 2015).
The Operation started in February 1992, with the arrest of Mario Chiesa, politician member of the Italian Socialist Party, charged with taking kickbacks. Around one month later, isolated and without the support of his old political partners, Chiesa proposed to turn state’s evidence (Vannucci, 2009; Sberna &Vannucci, 2013; Guimarães, 2016 Vannucci, 2016).
Chiesa’s information unveiled the most important corruption schemes between the political and economic elite in the country. When the arrests started, offenders agreed to turn state’s evidence as well, weakening the Italian political and economic system. The loss of legitimacy of the systems increased the power of judicial action and, at the same time, was fed by the results of the investigations (Moro, 2004; Sberna &Vannucci, 2013; Vannucci, 2016).
In a short time, the investigation had progressed in different fronts: a) at first, it included the leadership of all parties; and b) private businesspeople of every level and managers of public companies. Schemes to purchase and sell votes were uncovered, forming a criminal network made up of politicians, business people, and members of the Italian Mafia. Thirty-one people involved in the investigations committed suicide by 1994 (Guimarães, 2016; Vannucci, 2016).
In March 1993, Italian legal structure changes started, as can be observed in Box 3. They gained strength after the election of Silvio Berlusconi in 1994. Although he was involved in the investigations, the billionaire Italian businessman, owner of communication companies and the soccer team A.C. Milan, was elected prime minister, taking advantage of the vacuum of political discredit. He remained in office for six years and then, in 2008, was re-elected for four more years.
In 2002, when the Operation was considered complete, or at least disfigured, the result showed 1,254 people condemned, 430 acquitted, and 422 benefited by limitation periods and the rest not being sued. It is also interesting to observe the Transparency International indexes (Index TI) for the period between 1995 and 2018. They can show the Operation did not manage to bring Italy to a suitable control of corruption. In 2018, Italy ranked 58 out of 180 countries. The result has placed the country among the Western European countries with the worst corruption control. In the case of the index proposed by Mungiu-Pippidi (2015), Italy scored 4.54 in 2012. According to this index, Italy is one of the 109 countries in the world, where the particularistic logic prevails in the relations involving the State.

Source: Elaborated by the authors based on Guimarães (2016).
Box 3 Some relevant Italian legal structure changes (1993-2014)
Regarding the effectiveness of public control agencies, the evaluation is not favorable. Sberna and Vannucci (2013, p. 589) perceive the perpetuation of the ineffectiveness of internal and external administrative and judicial controls in Italy. For the authors, “the systemic loopholes in the judicial system made the prosecution of corruption crimes ineffective most of the time.” It is necessary to point out that in 1999, a Legislative Decree reformed the internal controls of the government through the restructuring of the mechanisms of control and evaluation of the local public administration (Paglietti, 2010). This reinforces the thesis that overcoming systemic corruption requires action involving all institutions at the same time, as advocated by Rothstein (2007).
On the side of the collective force as a constraint against systemic corruption, as argued by Mungiu-Pippidi, Garcia, and Teodósio (2017) show that, in the 1990s, Italy presented high levels of indices for the indicators associations and civic activism. However, there was no social pressure for change in public governance. The society has one of the highest social welfare rates in the world, such as life expectancy, educational attainment and human well-being. The excellent indexes may explain why there was no strong social pressure for changes in public governance in parallel to Operation Clean Hands.
Sberna and Vannucci (2013, p. 598) emphasize three aspects about the Clean Hands Operation: a) the politicization of the “anti-corruption issue,” with an institutional conflict between the political power and activism of the judges and prosecutors; b) the collapse of the party system; c) corruption affects society as a whole, including the public administration, civil society and the private sector. Box 4 summarizes the case.
In conclusion, three relevant ideas emerged from the Italian case: a) the insufficiency of the control or judicial system to work as a trigger to provoke an institutional agreement for overcoming systemic corruption; b) the risk of the politicization of the anti-corruption issue causing collapse of politics; and c) popular support given to judges does not mean that civil society is acting against the spread of corruption.
4. THE BRAZILIAN CASE
A challenge for the analysis of the Brazilian case is the fact that Operation Car Wash is still in action. However, the paths of the ongoing Operation, which seems to be losing strength, are under public and judiciary debate. There are allegations of excesses by the investigators, especially after the news organization ‘The Intercept’ published, in June-August 2019, leaked private messages exchanged between prosecutors and judges involved in the operation. The Law on Abuse of Authority (Sept./2019) was approved, the Supreme Court imposed limits on the use of reports of the Financial Intelligence Unit of the Internal Revenue Service, and other administrative bodies in criminal investigations (July/2019) and the Supreme Court has changed the understanding of the time of arrest of legal convicts, now requiring the exhaustion of all possibilities of appeal (Nov./2019). Hence, this analysis is of an ongoing case.
The analyses of the Swedish and Italian cases allow the consideration of three central elements to analyze the current attempt to overcome systemic corruption in Brazil. They are the trigger, the institutional background, and the collective force. These central elements are used to provide a basis for the understanding of the limits of the effectiveness of public accounting and control systems in the context of systemic corruption. The subsections below analyze the effects of each of the three central elements for the Brazilian case.
4.1 The Institutional Background
Brazilian history shows many institutional crises caused by corruption scandals. In the past, the fragility of the accounting and control systems, which are situated at the federal level, was considered the root cause of this problem. This article argues that such a conclusion may no longer hold true, because, in the 1980s and 1990s, Brazil made tremendous progress in these systems (Castro & Garcia, 2004).
An economic crisis in the early 1980s contributed to the visibility of the “[...] congenital process of corporatist and patrimonialist assault on the State ...” (Gouvêa, 1994, p. 174). It also evidenced the inconsistencies of financial reports, the unreliable character of balance sheets, and the precarious ability to control public spending. As stated by President Sarney, the first President after the re-democratization of Brazil, “it was not possible to calculate public deficit” (Castro & Garcia, 2004, p. 94). Considering this scenario, many important bureaucrats were convinced that changes were imperative.
This conviction provoked endogenous institutional cooperation in the government and the decision to create adequate accounting and financial control systems. Shortly after the end of the military dictatorship, in 1985, the federal government began to establish reliable accounting and financial management systems (Gouvêa, 1994). In 1986, the Secretary of the National Treasury (STN) was created, centralizing the Accounting, Financial Administration, and Internal Control Systems. One year later, the state put into operation the Integrated System of Financial Administration (SIAFI - Sistema Integrado de Administração Financeira). Together with the SIAFI, the government adopted the Conta Única do Tesouro Nacional (single account of the national treasury), which made accounting a structure that, similar to a bank, held all analytical and original data and started to be a source of information (Castro & Garcia, 2004).
The 1988 Constitution consolidated the changes that occurred in the accounting and internal control systems. However, it also strengthened the external control of the Public Administration, especially with the role of the Federal Court of Accounts (Tribunal de Contas da União), the Federal Police Department (Departamento da Polícia Federal), Federal Prosecution Office (Ministério Público Federal) and civil society (Avritzer & Filgueiras, 2011). Despite this strong structure, five years later, two other scandals emerged. In 1992, President Collor was impeached, motivated by corruption. In 1993, there was a major scandal of the National Congress with the revelation of deviation schemes in federal budgets. In 1994, the official explanation for the institutional crisis caused by these scandals was the fragility of internal control.
The solution implemented was the creation of the Federal Secretary for Internal Control (Secretaria Federal de Controle Interno - SFC), subordinated to the Ministry of Finance (MP 480/1994). The SFC and the STN form the Internal Control System of the Federal Executive Branch. They have autonomy and centralized the roles of financial administration, accounting, and control at the federal level. Seven years later, the Law 10.180/2001 institutionalized these three roles in separate systems (accounting, financial administration, and control). The first two roles were operated under the responsibility of the STN and the latter under the responsibility of the SFC. In 2003, the Comptroller General (Controladoria-Geral da União - CGU) was created, incorporating the Secretary for Internal Control and expanding its functions to include an ombudsman, combating corruption, and correction. Figure 1 shows how systems work, under the supervision of the external control of the Federal Court of Auditors.

(*)(*)The Office of the Chief of Staff (Casa Civil da Presidência da República), the Federal Attorney General’s Office (Advocacia-Geral da União), the Ministry of Foreign Affairs (Ministério das Relações Exteriores) and the Ministry of Defense (Ministério da Defesa) have their own organ of internal control. Source: Elaborated by the authors.
Figure 1 The Brazilian Federal Systems of Accounting and Financial Control
At the time this structure was formed, during the 1990s, new laws of control were created in the country, shown in Box 5. They have improved the Brazilian state enforcement.
It is possible to conclude that Brazil constituted strong systems of bureaucratic and judicial control in the last 30 years. The expectation was that the existence of specialized agencies to supervise and punish possible acts of corruption committed by public agents could help Brazil to overcome the problem of corruption. Unfortunately, this did not happen, as the next subsection will show.
4.2 The Trigger: Operation Car Wash
The Operation began on March 17, 2014, when the Federal Justice authorized the Federal Police to carry out the first phase of the operation, arresting Youssef, a black market dollar dealer, and subpoenaing Paulo Roberto, former manager of Petrobrás,1 to testify. Like the Italian Operation, the offenders accepted to turn state’s evidence, and investigative techniques against money laundering and criminal organizations played an important role in the process of uncovering corrupt practices in the interface between political parties and the private sector. It was possible to prove the formation of cartels in several economic sectors, mostly involving the country’s largest contractors, with severe financial losses for the contracting state-owned companies.
Due to the complexity of the operation, an investigative task force of Prosecutors of the Republic was formed for the investigation work in the first instance of the Federal Court of Paraná. The task force, all the time, has been working together with the Federal Police and the Federal Revenue Secretariat (in Brazil called Secretaria da Receita Federal). These bodies were occasionally joined by members of the Federal Comptroller, the Administrative Council for Economic Defense, and members of Petrobrás.
During the investigation, collaborative agreements, particularly those made with the staff of the companies Odebrecht2 and JBS3, have proved that the behaviors unveiled in the Operation were not a deviating fact, but rather the standard behavior in the interface between the public and the private sectors. After a little more than five years, the Operation had had an impact on the economic elite due to the arrest of important business people.
The legitimacy of politicians and that of the state was challenged. In the specific case of the Executive Power, one of the outcomes of the losses on legitimacy was the impeachment of former president Dilma Rousseff, which was made possible, to a great extent, due to the loss of legitimacy of the political party to which she belonged, the Workers’ Party (PT). Other outcomes were the imprisonment of former president Lula and the former president of the Chamber of Deputies, Eduardo Cunha. Former president Temer is now under investigation, after being released from preventive detention.
According to the Federal Prosecution Office4 (Ministério Público Federal), on July 5, 2019, the numbers of Operation Car Wash were: 2,476 inquiries, 754 requests of international collaboration, 155 preventive arrests, 183 collaborative agreements, 11 leniency agreements, and 1 conduct adjustment agreement. There are still criminal charges against 421 people, 159 already sentenced.
4.3 The Brazilian Collective Action
Avritzer (2016, p. 6) affirms that Brazil “[…] by any significant criterion proposed by theories that measure the state of the art of democracy, the country is in a good position”. Nonetheless, Brazil has never succeeded in building a democracy that is genuinely focused on the common good. It has remained an electoral democracy, without a real sense of universalism and the common good. Brazilian social construction has always presented a high level of social inequality and low levels of trust and social capital. The economic, political, and bureaucratic elites have always received high income, better public services than the average Brazilian, and, to a certain extent, have put themselves above the law.
In general, they build ties with the Government and the Judiciary in order to be benefited by the laws. Carvalho (2008:215) affirms that, in Brazil, “[t]here are first-class citizens, the privileged people, the ‘doutores’ who are above the law and always manage to defend their own interest through the power of money and social prestige. The ‘doutores’ are invariably white, rich, well-dressed, with university education”. So, considering Tocqueville’s theory, it is not yet possible to affirm that there is, in practice, popular sovereignty in Brazil. There is no indication of significant changes in the ability of Brazilian society to effectively interfere with the institutions in a way that solves civic or public interest problems. Table 1 demonstrates the period after the re-democratization of Brazil and shows some social indicators that may help the analysis of the idea of collective force in Brazilian society.
Table 1 Collective Force - Brazil
Year | Civic Activism | Intergroup Cohesion | Clubs and Associations | Interpersonal Safety and Trust |
---|---|---|---|---|
1990 | 0.587 | 0.643 | 0.440 | 0.477 |
2000 | 0.530 | 0.497 | 0.502 | 0.349 |
2010 | 0.524 | 0.703 | 0.492 | 0.286 |
Source: International Social Development Indexes (ISDI, in June 2013).
There was a particularly significant decline in the indicator “Interpersonal_Safety_and_Trust.” This indicator reduced from 0,477 in 1990 to 0,286, in 2010. The other indicators remained relatively constant in that same period. Despite no recent data of the ISDI, a survey on interpersonal trust made by IBOPE5 in 2014, at the request of the National Confederation of Industry, confirmed this declining trend. According to the survey, only 6% of the population perceived itself as having much confidence in people in general. In contrast, 31% indicated that they had some confidence, and the majority did not show any confidence.
On the other hand, it is important to highlight that activism and the association trend of civil society have not shown a significant decline since 1990. This force of civil society can be seen in the social movements that took place in the country in 2013, which preceded the approval of the anti-corruption laws and the collaboration agreement that allowed the emergence of Operation Car Wash. The question, however, is what kind of changes can this force produce without interpersonal trust and a sense of collectivity?
4.4 Preliminary inferences about the Brazilian case
The Brazilian case can be summarized, in a very preliminary way, as shown in Box 6. In terms of the trigger and scope of the attempt to change, the Brazilian case bears a resemblance to the Italian case. Concerning the institutional background, there is a similarity in terms of changes in investigative processes (a collaborative agreement, for example). However, Brazil has not gone through law changes to protect offenders and make it difficult to punish deviations, as it happened in Italy. The recent Supreme Court’s understanding that offenders convicted in the court of appeal cannot be arrested if there is still legal instances to appeal represents not a change, but an interpretation of a very complex point of the Federal Constitution.
Unlike Sweden and Italy, at the time of their process, regarding the collective force, the condition of Brazilian civil society to defend public interests is much more fragile. The society presents a low level of interpersonal trust and deep social inequality.
In addition to the crisis of legitimacy of the State, Brazil has faced a deep economic crisis since 2014. The Brazilian society is severely impacted, and it has difficulty in advocating for principles of social cohesion. In the last federal elections of 2018, a strong social movement led to the rejection of traditional and more consolidated political parties.
The current institutional setting is complex and challenging. However, there are still no signs that these crises are enough to be understood as a new trigger able to provoke an endogenous institutional solution, as it occurred in Sweden in the nineteenth century, despite the fragility of civil society. Nevertheless, this possibility cannot be ruled out, especially if the political, institutional, and economic problems are further aggravated. In this context, Sweden’s lesson is that a significant part of society, including part of the elites, is aware that everyone can lose and they can decide to work together to change the rules of the dominant social game.
5. FINAL CONSIDERATIONS
The literature reviewed indicates that corruption is a matter of contemporary relevance. This is particularly true for countries characterized by systemic corruption - which are the majority in the world. In these countries, there are clear limitations in stabilizing the foundations of the rule of law, such as (a) there is no effective separation between private political gains/economic elites and public resources; (b) there is no impersonality in the relations between the public and the private sphere; and (c) the common good stated by positive law is articulated by the economic interest in collusion with politicians, thus trapping the legal structures.
Economic theories, primarily through the principal-agent theory, suggest mechanisms to control public bureaucracy, even in the absence of the “incorruptible principal.” Examples of such suggestions are the establishment of institutions and horizontal control agencies. However, the impact of such institutions in states that face systematic corruption is very different from the one in developed countries. In light of the limitations of the principal-agent theory, collective action can complement some possibilities to overcome systemic corruption. Starting from the cases of Sweden, Italy, and Brazil, some points merit reflection in order to overcome the problem of systemic corruption.
The existence of an external phenomenon is necessary to break the perverse balance of systemic corruption. Sweden sought a new equilibrium motivated by war, which demonstrated that the very continuity of the Swedish state could be at risk. Italy and Brazil did not experience an external phenomenon. The fight of the judiciary against certain types of corruption, such as bribes, cannot be characterized as an external phenomenon. The particularity of the Brazilian crisis, however, can be considered an external phenomenon. The crisis in the country combines: (i) a crisis of legitimacy of the political classes with Operation Car Wash (ii) a serious economic crisis; and (iii) a brutal social inequality. This combination is a threat to the democratic order and stability of institutions. It is precisely this threat that may be considered an external phenomenon.
Normative constraints, independent Judiciary, and adequate control systems based on principal-agent theory are necessary for encouraging public agents to align themselves with official standards. Sweden had, as a background to its the process of overcoming systematic corruption, a reform of the Judiciary. It instituted new rules of the game for the functioning of the State, as well as mechanisms of control to interface with private interests. While Italy and Brazil each have a control system, its effectiveness in the context of systematic corruption is limited. Their respective control systems were established before the crisis analyzed, and they were absorbed by the rules of the game that were in force.
The change must be endogenous. In Sweden, the comprehensive pact for changing the rules of the game involved the political and bureaucratic fields and involved all areas and all institutions. In Italy, a portion of the Judiciary conducted the prosecution of a specific type of corruption (bribe), which was typical of the relationship between political parties and the market. In this context, Italian political parties and the market protected each other and found a way to overcome the crisis, while, at the same time, not conducting a profound change in the rules of the game. Systematic corruption was thus not overcome. Brazil is now facing a type of confrontation of corruption that appears to be like that of Italy.
Collective force is also a structural condition relevant to overcoming systemic corruption. In Sweden, civil society had a strong movement to build a liberal, efficient, and equalitarian democracy. In Italy, civil society had a high level of political activism and social trust. However, there was no pressure for change in public governance, as this society has one of the highest social welfare rates in the world, such as life expectancy, educational attainment, and human well-being. The social structure of Brazil is different from that of Italy. Since the 1980s, in the reconstruction of democracy, Brazilian society has not yet been able to advance social indexes of well-being.
Considering that Operation Car Wash is still underway, the possible contribution of this article is to alert against sectarian perspectives of solutions for the problem of corruption in Brazil. A joint effort from leaders from all sectors for a possible pact to change the rules of the corruption game that is in force can be a strategy for change. It is not possible to divide agents into corrupt and non-corrupt. Instead, it is essential to perceive systemic corruption as a problem for everyone.
A new research agenda about public finance, accountability, and corruption control could be improved through the comparative analysis between countries, as done in this article. Some relevant issues related to the political culture of the countries and the trajectory of public policies considering the institutions can bring new insights for these academic issues that are relevant to the society and the policymakers. To advance points that are not focused on in this research such as the role of the private corporations adopting (or not) self-regulation about corruption, the kind of activism against the corruption created by NGOs, and the population’s perception about the ethical crimes on public finance, are relevant issues for the new research in this field.