Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Understanding the hierarchy governance choice of some wineries in Brazil - case study of 3 Brazilian wineries

Análise da escolha das estruturas de governança em vinícolas brasileiras - estudos de casos em 3 vinícolas

Análisis de la elección de las estructuras de gobierno en vinícolas brasileñas - estudios de caso en 3 bodegas

ABSTRACT

This study aims to contribute towards understanding the multiple factors, which influence firm's governance decisions. To identify some of these factors, three cases in the Brazilian wine industry were analyzed: Miolo located in Vale dos Vinhedos (South of Brazil) and in Vale do Rio São Francisco (Northeast of Brazil); Don Laurindo located in Vale dos Vinhedos; and ViniBrasil located in Vale do Rio São Francisco. For the most part, all three firms procure the grapes they use for their wine production in-house. Only Miolo purchases an insignificant amount of grapes outside of its production. By Brazilian standards, these regions have a long tradition of grape production and it is not difficult to purchase sufficient quantity of grapes to produce wine. However, the wineries are concerned also about the quality of the grapes they use and purchasing high-quality grapes might be critical issue. On the other hand, the quality of grapes is easily measured and the cost to buy in the market is cheaper than producing in-house. Furthermore, also the level of asset specificity present in the grape-grower-wine-producer transaction seems, by itself, insufficient to justify the use of hierarchical governance forms. Then, the aim of the article is to analyze the reasons why these wineries largely rely on hierarchy governance forms to procure their grape-inputs. What explains their use of hierarchy governance, given that both asset specificity and measurement problems appear to be relatively low?

Keywords:
Brazilian wineries; hierarchy governance; transaction costs economics; resource based view; property rights

RESUMO

A decisão da melhor estrutura de governança adotada pelas empresas tem sido objeto de estudo de diversas vertentes teóricas, muitas vezes, dissociadas. Assim, este estudo pretende contribuir para a compreensão dos múltiplos fatores que influenciam nas decisões de governança da empresa, a partir dos argumentos da Economia dos Custos de Transação; da Visão Baseada em Recursos e da Teoria dos Direitos de Propriedade. Para identificar alguns desses fatores, foram analisados ​​três casos na indústria do vinho brasileiro: Miolo, localizada no Vale dos Vinhedos (Sul do Brasil) e no Vale do Rio São Francisco (Nordeste do Brasil); Don Laurindo, localizada no Vale dos Vinhedos; e a Vinibrasil, localizada no Vale do Rio São Francisco. A maioria das vinícolas estudadas produz as uvas utilizadas na produção de vinho. Apenas a Miolo compra uma quantidade insignificante de uvas fora de sua produção. É importante observar que no Brasil, a produção de uva nestas regiões tem uma longa tradição e não é difícil comprar uma quantidade suficiente de uvas destinadas à produção de vinho. Identificou-se que a qualidade das uvas é fácil de ser medida e o custo de compra no mercado é mais barato do que a produção própria. Porém, as vinícolas argumentam que produzem a própria uva para garantir a qualidade das uvas e, consequentemente, do vinho produzido. Entretanto, o nível de especificidade dos ativos presentes na transação entre produtor de uva e vinícola parece, por si só, insuficiente para justificar o uso de forma de governança hierárquica. Assim, o objetivo do artigo é analisar as razões pelas quais essas vinícolas, em grande parte, dependem da forma de governança hierárquica para adquirir suas uvas. O que explica o uso de governança hierárquica, uma vez que tanto a especificidade de ativos como os problemas de mensuração parecem relativamente baixos?

Palavras-chave:
vinícolas brasileiras; governança hierárquica; economia dos custos de transação; visão baseada em recursos; direitos de propriedade

RESUMEN

Este estudio tiene como objetivo contribuir a la comprensión de los múltiples factores que influyen en las decisiones de gobernanza de las empresas. Para identificar algunos de estos factores, se analizaron tres casos en la industria del vino brasileño: Miolo ubicada en Valle de los Viñedos (sur de Brasil) y en Vale do Rio São Francisco (nordeste de Brasil); Don Laurindo ubicada en Valle de los Viñedos, y ViniBrasil ubicada en Vale do Rio São Francisco. En su mayor parte, las tres empresas producen las uvas que utilizan para su producción de vino. Sólo Miolo compra una cantidad insignificante de las uvas fuera de su producción. Según los estándares brasileños, en estas regiones tiene una larga tradición de producción de uva, y no es difícil comprar suficiente cantidad de uvas para producir vino. Sin embargo, las bodegas están preocupadas también por la calidad de las uvas que se utilizan y la compra de uvas de alta calidad podrían ser tema crítico. Por otro lado, es fácil de medir la calidad de las uvas y el costo para comprar en el mercado es más barato que producir. Por otra parte, también el nivel de especificidad de los activos presentes en la transacción de productor de uva-bodeguero parece, por sí sola, insuficiente para justificar el uso de formas jerárquicas. Entonces, el objetivo del artículo es analizar las razones por las que estas bodegas dependen en gran medida de las formas jerárquicas para adquirir sus vendimiadores entradas. ¿Cómo se explica el uso de la gobernanza jerárquica, teniendo en cuenta que tanto los problemas de especificidad de activos y de medición parecen ser relativamente bajos?

Palabras clave:
bodegas brasileñas; gobernanza jerarquía; economía de los costos de transacción; visión basada en los recursos; los derechos de propiedad

1. INTRODUCTION

The Portuguese introduced viticulture in Brazil in the early of 16thcentury and production was restricted to the south and southeast up to 1960s, after which the cultivation of grape was brought to semiarid region of the Vale do Rio São Francisco, the viticulture in tropical Brazil (Instituto Brasileiro do Vinho [IBRAVIN], 2013aIBRAVIN (2013a). História do vinho no Brasil. Disponível em:http://www.ibravin.org.br/historia-do-vinho-no-brasil.php> Acesso em 25 de marco de 2013.
http://www.ibravin.org.br/historia-do-vi...
). In the mid-1970s with the entry of multinational companies that have introduced innovations in production and logistics sector, this activity has emerged in the country (Schmidt, 2012Schmidt, C.M. (2012). A certificação como forma de criação e apropriação de valor no sistema agroindustrial do vinho do Vale dos Vinhedos. Cascavel, PR: EDUNIOESTE.). From the 80s, according to Protas (2008)Protas, J.F. (2008). A produção de vinhos finos: um flash do desafio brasileiro. Agropec. Catarin, 21(3),1., the industry engaged in political action to promote improvements in the structure of national winemaking through intensive investments in the modernization of the wineries. The motivation of the business was due to the possibility of domestic market growth, both for traditional products such as the international standard (fine wines), which have potential for commercialization with greater added value. In short, the wineries have sought strategies to expand their market.

Currently, the Brazilian viticulture covers an area of 81 thousands hectares with vineyards from the far south to regions near the equator. Two regions stand out: Vale dos Vinhedos in the South of Brazil, producing an average of 777 million kilos of grape per year, and Vale do Rio São Francisco in the Brazilian Northeastern (IBRAVIN, 2013bIBRAVIN (2013b). Principais regiões produtoras. Disponível em:http://www.ibravin.org.br/regioesprodutoras.php. Acesso em 25 de marco de 2013.
http://www.ibravin.org.br/regioesproduto...
). With regard to the Vale do Rio São Francisco, currently, it is estimated that there is an area of vineyards with varieties geared to producing wines that give rise to approximately 7 million liters of wine / year, 80% red wine and 20% white (IBRAVIN, 2013aIBRAVIN (2013a). História do vinho no Brasil. Disponível em:http://www.ibravin.org.br/historia-do-vinho-no-brasil.php> Acesso em 25 de marco de 2013.
http://www.ibravin.org.br/historia-do-vi...
).

The wineries are concerned about the quality of grapes; it is an important issue to produce wine with good quality. This is the main incentive to wineries cultivate their own grapes in order to control and monitor all phases of their wine production. However, the general argument applied to the hierarchy governance is broader than just transaction cost. Resource attributes that include skills/knowledge or resource based view and property rights theory is well connected to the former theories.

This study aims to contribute understanding the multiple factors that influence firm's governance decisions. To identify some of those factors, we analyzed three cases in the Brazilian wine industry as an example. The Brazilian wine industry is an interesting context for the purpose of this study because there is already viticulture consolidated in Rio Grande do Sul, where Vale dos Vinhedos is located, and in Vale do Rio São Francisco located in the Brazilian Northeastern. Although the purchase of grapes in market is feasible, some wineries have attempted to produce grapes in-house.

The three wineries selected for this study are located in Vale dos Vinhedos and in Vale do Rio São Francisco, where production of grapes is well developed. Although plural forms were observed (Koenig, Sousa, Watanabe & Wever, 2014Koenig, C.L.C., Sousa, R.N.L., Watanabe, K., Wever, M. The fine wine industry in Brazil: The cases of Miolo, Don Laurindo, and ViniBrasil Wineries. In: Ménard, C.; Saes, M.S.M., Silva, V.L.S., Raynaud, E.(Eds) Challenges to Economic Organization. Plural Forms. São Paulo: Atlas , p. 225-241, 2014.), they are mainly organized into hierarchy governance form, what seem contradictory since it is not difficult purchase grapes in the market. One of the reasons for choosing the hierarchy form is that the wineries are concerned about the quality of grapes, because it is an important issue to produce wine with good quality. On the other hand the quality of grapes is measurable and the cost to buy grapes in the market is less expensive than producing it in-house. Therefore, asset specificity and measurement problems seem to be not the only characteristics that explain the hierarchy governance choice. The question that then arises is: What explains the hierarchy governance, besides the asset specificity and measurement problems? In other words, the general argument applied to the hierarchy governance, besides transaction cost economics, also requires a resource based view and property rights-based explanation, both which are well connected to transaction cost economics.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section, the three theories - transaction cost, property rights, and resource-based view - are briefly described. Subsequently, we discuss the methodology used in the study. In the fourth section, the cases - Miolo, Don Laurindo, and ViniBrasil - are described and analyzed using the theories discussed. In the fifth and final section, concluding remarks are presented.

2. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK

In this section we argue that each of the three theories - Transaction Cost Economics; Resource Based View; Property Rights - gives an incomplete picture of the factors affecting firms' governance decisions when taking in isolation. Some authors' contributions concerned the comparison, complementarity or possible integration between the theories. Particularly, with regard to transaction costs, there are studies that explore the possibilities of integration with capabilities/resources (Williamson, 1999Williamson O.E. (1999). Strategy research: Governance and competence perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 1087-1108.;Jacobides & Winter, 2005Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413.; Argyres & Bigelow, 2008Bigelow, L.S., Argyres, N. (2008). Transaction costs, industry experience and make-or-buy decisions in the population of early U.S. auto firms.Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,66, 791-807.; Argyres & Zenger, 2012Argyres, N., Zenger, T. (2012). Capabilities, transaction costs, and firm boundaries. Organization Science, 1-15.). As we will explain below, in some situations each of the three theories will predict a different governance decision, while in other situations the theories will predict the same governance decision, but for different reasons. Jointly considering all three theoretical perspectives when analyzing firms' governance decisions will therefore help researchers to better predict what governance forms firms use in specific situations and why.

2.1. Transaction cost economics

Differently from neoclassical economic conceptualizations, that considers pricing mechanism and firm solely as a production function, transaction cost economics (TCE) describes the firm also as an efficiency-inducing administrative instrument that takes into account the costs for negotiation efforts, contract design and coordination (Williamson, 1975Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.). The notion of these costs was introduced by Coase (1937Coase, R. H. (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386-404., 1960)Coase, R. H. (1960). El problema del costo social. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, (october), 1-44.and further developed by Williamson (1979Williamson, O.E. (1979). The governance of contractual relations.Journal of Law and Economics, (22:2), October, 233-261., 1985Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press ., 1991a)Williamson, O.E. (1991a). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quaterly, 36, 269-296. under the label of transaction costs. The transaction costs include ex-ante costs for negotiation efforts, contracts design, and safeguarding agreements, and ex-post costs for aligning and adapting the contract (Williamson, 1985Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press .).

The choice of institutional arrangement is seen as a central means through which management influences, monitors and enforces contractual performance (Williamson, 1975Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press.). It is related to firm's intentions to economize on transaction costs. The presence of these costs explains which transactions are undertaken through the market and which are internalized within the firm (Coase, 1937Coase, R. H. (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386-404.). Economic agents align transaction with institutional arrangement to affect outcomes; therefore, the costs of one mode of governance are always examined in relation to alternative feasible modes (Williamson, 1996Williamson, O.E. (1996). The mechanism of governance. New York; Oxford: Oxford University Press.). Transaction costs arise from human behavioral assumptions that are: bounded rationality and opportunism. Bounded rationality is defined as behavior where economic agents attempt to optimize, but lack the cognitive capabilities to do so. In other words, it is the inability of economic actors to anticipate properly the consequences of their actions as well as the contingencies (Simon, 1957Simon, H.A. (1957). Models of man: Social and rational. mathematical essays on rational human behavior in a social setting. John Wiley &Sons, New York, NY.). Opportunism refers to the assumption that economic actors are self-interested in a calculative and devious manner - they comply with rules and regulations only when the cost of compliance is lower than the costs of non-compliance and they try to hide non-compliance (Williamson, 1985Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press .).

Different institutional arrangements depend on transaction attributes, which are part of TCE and they are related to various dimensions of the transaction, especially asset specificity and uncertainty. According to Williamson (1979Williamson, O.E. (1979). The governance of contractual relations.Journal of Law and Economics, (22:2), October, 233-261., 1985Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press ., 1991aWilliamson, O.E. (1991a). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quaterly, 36, 269-296., 1996Williamson, O.E. (1996). The mechanism of governance. New York; Oxford: Oxford University Press., 2005)Williamson, O. E. (2005). The economics of governance. The American Economic Review, 95(2), 1-18., these dimensions affect a firm's governance decision that is based on a choice between competing alternative forms: market, hybrid, and hierarchy. In the original TCE framework, as developed by Williamson (1985)Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press ., three main attributes of the transaction were distinguished: asset specificity, uncertainty and frequency. However, `frequency` is not considered in our study, since its effect on firms' governance decisions is ambiguous and not well understood (Geyskens, Steenkamp & Kumar, 2006Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J.E. ,Kumar, N.(2006). Make, buy, or ally: A transaction cost theory meta-analysis. The Academy of Management Journal, 49(3), 519-543.; Rindfleisch & Heide, 1997Rindfleisch, A., Heide, J.B. (1997). Transaction cost analysis: Past, present and future applications. Journal of Marketing, (61:4), October, pp. 30-54.).

Asset specificity refers to the degree by which the investments a party makes to support the transaction, ties it to the other party to the transaction. Williamson (1985)Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press . defines asset specific investment as "durable investment that are undertaken in support of particular transactions, the opportunity cost of which investment is much lower in best alternative uses or by alternative uses should the original transaction be prematurely terminated". In other words, a specialized investment cannot be used in another transaction without a loss in value. The difference in value of the assets within and out of the specific relation is called the quasi-rent (Alchian, 1984Alchian, A. (1984). Specificity, specialization and coalitions.Journal of Economic Theory and Institutions, 140(3), 34-49.). Hence, insofar as asset specificity is present, ex-post bargaining or hold-up risk increases and transaction costs rise (Klein, Crawford & Alchian, 1978Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., Alchian, A.A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process.Journal of Law & Economics, 21, 30.). In order to reduce the hold-up risk in the transaction that involves specialized investment, the transaction parties have strong incentives to rely less on spontaneous, market-based governance forms and more on hands-on governance forms (Williamson, 1991bWilliamson, O.E. (1991b). Economic institutions: spontaneous and intentional governance. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 7, January, pp. 159-187.). This can take the form of neoclassical contracts (i.e., arbitrator mediated arrangements) for transactions involving mixed-use investments (i.e., for transactions involving medium levels of asset specificity), or unified, hierarchical governance (vertical integration) for transactions involving idiosyncratic investments (i.e., for transactions involving highly specific investments) (Williamson, 1991aWilliamson, O.E. (1991a). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quaterly, 36, 269-296.; see also Williamson, 1975Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press., 1979Williamson, O.E. (1979). The governance of contractual relations.Journal of Law and Economics, (22:2), October, 233-261., 1985Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press .; Klein et al., 1978Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., Alchian, A.A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process.Journal of Law & Economics, 21, 30.).

Uncertainty refers to unanticipated changes in the larger industry-context and institutional environment in which transactions are embedded. Given actors' bounded rationality, they cannot (fully) anticipate these changes when entering into a transaction. As a result, actors will not be able to write contracts, which take into account all future states of the world; i.e., contracts are incomplete. Uncertainty makes transactions more unstable involving specific investments (more prone to maladaptation and hold-up problems) and more likely to be internalized even when the investments are only of a mixed-use nature (seeWilliamson, 1991aWilliamson, O.E. (1991a). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quaterly, 36, 269-296.).

2.2. Resource based view

The Resource-based view (RBV) is largely based on the work of Wenerfelt (1984)Wernerfelt B. (1984). A resource-based theory of the firm.Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171-180., Rumelt (1984)Rumelt, R. P. (1984). Towards a strategic theory of the firm. In: Richard B. Lamb, ed. Competitive Strategic Management. New Jersey: Englewood Cliffs, 1984, p.556-570., Barney (1991)Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120. doi:10.1177/014920639101700108.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206391017001...
, Peteraf (1993)Peteraf, M. A. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive advantage: a resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal.14(3), 179-91. andConner (1991)Conner, K.R. (1991). A historical comparison of resource- based theory and five schools of thought within industrial organization economics: Do we have a new theory of the firm? Journal of Management,17, 121-154.. RBV has been developed with a specific focus on how firms manage resources or knowledge and the complex combination between different sets of resources. According to RBV theory, resources that are common to many companies or which are easily available in the market cannot provide a sustainable competitive advantage. Only strategic resources (e.g., assets, skills, knowledge) that satisfy the conditions of being valuable rare, inimitable and non-substitutable can generate such an advantage (Barney, 1991)Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120. doi:10.1177/014920639101700108.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206391017001...
.

Barney (1991)Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120. doi:10.1177/014920639101700108.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206391017001...
distinguishes three main categories of resources: physical resources such as plant and equipment, human resources, such as technical specialists and teams, but also company executives, and organizational resources, formed by the norms and routines that coordinate the physical and human resources of the company. Hierarchical governance can help to develop and transfer tacit resources or knowledge, including shared norms and routines. Barney (1991)Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120. doi:10.1177/014920639101700108.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206391017001...
considers the dynamics of the process performance among the resources and their effects on the organization. Therefore, the strategic value of the resource is not only a result of the resource itself, nor for their connection with each other, but coming from the inter-relationships that exist between the whole set of resources controlled by the organization.

From this perspective, the essence of the firm is its ability to create, transfer, assemble, integrate and exploit these resources. Considering that these resources are used differently in each organization, according to the perceptions of managers, then the firms are heterogenic and, consequently, there is different profitability among them. This conception of heterogeneity comes from the assumption that admits the nature of competition determined by establishing barriers to imitation and constant innovations. In RBV, not all features and capabilities have elastic supply, even for that, to be developed; some of them require a long period of time. This inelasticity of supply implies that firms possessing valuable resources can gain sustainable competitive advantage (Peteraf, 1993Peteraf, M. A. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive advantage: a resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal.14(3), 179-91.). In this sense, the deduction is that the main sources differences in profitability between firms arise from rents in Ricardian sense (return higher than the opportunity cost). In other words, it is assumed that economic rents for efficient firms derive from scarce sources and are made possible by the imperfections of market factors. Imperfections arise from managerial ability, the unique language used inside the firm and its specific organizational culture. They also arise from physical assets and innovations protected by patents or organizational competence, and even intangible assets such as consumer confidence, brand image and reputational capital. Barney and Arikan (2001)Barney, J.B., Arikan, A.M. (2001). The resource-based view: Origins and implications. In Hitt, M.A., Freeman, R.E., Harrison, J.S. (2001).Handbook of Strategic Management. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. argue that these factors of production are perfectly inelastic, since the quantities offered are fixed (they are unique) and do not respond to changes in prices. From this perspective, what makes it a valuable resource is the peculiar way in which it is used by the firm (Teece and Pisano, 1994Teece, D. J., & Pisano, G. (1994). The dynamics capabilities of firms. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3(3), 537-556.). However, there are authors that expand the notion of resources, assuming that its value, at least in part, depends on environmental conditions (Barney, 2001Barney, J. B. (2001). Is the resource-based "view" a useful perspective for strategic management research? Yes. The Academy of Management Review, 26, 41-56.; Foss & Foss, 2005Foss, K., Foss, N. J. (2005). Resources and transaction costs: How property rights economics furthers the resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal, 553(12), 541-553. doi:10.1002/smj.465.
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.465...
).

Foss and Foss (2005)Foss, K., Foss, N. J. (2005). Resources and transaction costs: How property rights economics furthers the resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal, 553(12), 541-553. doi:10.1002/smj.465.
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.465...
argue in their study that also the property rights aspects of resources should be considered, especially the social environment should also be seen as a source of resource value, not only as a restrictive factor. The way how property rights are restricted under law, agreements or norms, influences the value that an owner of any resource can create and how much can be appropriated from that resource (Foss & Foss, 2005Foss, K., Foss, N. J. (2005). Resources and transaction costs: How property rights economics furthers the resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal, 553(12), 541-553. doi:10.1002/smj.465.
https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.465...
). For Kim and Mahoney (2007)Kim, J., & Mahoney, J.T. (2007) Appropriating economic rents from resources: An integrative property rights and resource-based approach.International Journal of Learning and Intellectual Capital,4(1/2). doi: 10.1504/IJLIC.2007.013820
https://doi.org/10.1504/IJLIC.2007.01382...
, if the property rights of the resource with the potential for value creation are not fully guaranteed in a business context in which multiple partners are involved, value creation cannot happen (see also Barney and Hansen, 1994Barney, J. B., Hansen, M. H. (1994). Trustworthiness as a source of competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal, 15, 175-190.; Kim and Mahoney, 2002Kim, J., & Mahoney, J.T. (2002). Resource-based and property rights perspectives on value creation: The case of oil field unitization.Managerial and Decision Economics, 23 (4/5): 225-245. doi: 10.1002/mde.1063.
https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1063...
). Similar difficulties may arise within firms, where multiple agents that provide inputs are producing economic value jointly (teamwork) (Alchian & Demsetz, 1972Alchian, A.A., Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62,777-795.; Holmstrom, 1982Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 324-340.). Kim and Mahoney (2007)Kim, J., & Mahoney, J.T. (2007) Appropriating economic rents from resources: An integrative property rights and resource-based approach.International Journal of Learning and Intellectual Capital,4(1/2). doi: 10.1504/IJLIC.2007.013820
https://doi.org/10.1504/IJLIC.2007.01382...
argue that historical examples show that in some sectors the potential economic value creation (and rents) does not guarantee the effective creation of economic value.

2.3. Property rights

Besides TCE, also Property Rights theory attempts to understand firm boundaries and their choice of institutional arrangement. Demsetz (1967)Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. The American Economic Review, 57, 2. discussed property rights, using the neoclassical perspective to understand how property rights for specific transactions arise. According to Demsetz, property rights arise with the internalization of beneficial and harmful effects (externalities), when the gains of internalization become larger than the cost of internalization. Demsetz (1967) argues that property rights are exchanged in a transaction. Then, the value of the rights determines the value of the exchange. The problem that results from untradeable property rights is known as the common-resource problem, public-goods problem, free-rider problem, and the tragedy of the commons (Milgrom & Roberts, 1992Milgrom, P. Roberts, J. (1992). Economics of Organization & Management. Prentice-Hall, New Jersey.). According toMilgrom and Roberts (1992)Milgrom, P. Roberts, J. (1992). Economics of Organization & Management. Prentice-Hall, New Jersey., "...when many people have the right to use a single shared resource, there is an incentive for the resource be overused..." (p. 294). Considering the asset investment, if the residual returns of it are widely shared, no one has a sufficient interest to bear the cost of maintaining and increasing the value. For economic analysis, the "owning an asset" interpretation means that the residual rights of control, which is the right to make any decisions concerning the asset's use that are not explicitly controlled by law or assigned by another contract. If ownership means having residual control, then its importance must derive from the difficulty of writing contracts that specify all the control rights. Thus, concentrating the ownership rights might be the efficient way; consequently, the hierarchy form prevails.

Although TCE and property rights have been developed along different lines, both of them focus on the role of ownership as a way to avoid hold-up problems (Araujo, Dubois & Gadde, 2003Araujo, L., Dubois, A., Gadde, L-E. (2003). The multiple boundaries of the firm. Journal of Management Studies, 40(7), 1255-1277.). Then, the emergence of the firm becomes a response to hold-up problems combined with the intrinsic opportunistic nature of human actors and the specialized assets required for efficient production.

A perspective on property rights has been developed by Barzel (1982Barzel, Y. (1982). Measurement cost and the organization of markets.Journal of Law & Economics, 25(1), 27-48., 2001Barzel, Y. (2001). A theory of organizations to supersede the theory of the firm. Working Paper.,2002)Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: Economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press ., who made significant contribution to Measurement Cost Theory. In Measurement Cost Theory, transactions are decomposed into various dimensions. Each transaction dimension represents a property right exchange and can be identified by a measurement cost. This cost brings a specific value to agents involved in the transaction. According to Zylbersztajn (2005)Zylbersztajn, D. (2005). Papel dos contratos na coordenação agro-industrial: um olhar além dos mercados. Revista de Economia e Sociologia Rural, 43(3), 385-420., the specific value in the transaction can be dispersed if the property rights are not well defined, which can be difficult to measure, hence it can become difficult to contract specific attribute of transaction. Barzel (1997)Barzel, Y. (1997). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. considers the concept of property rights closely related to that of transaction costs. Transaction costs are defined byBarzel (1997)Barzel, Y. (1997). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. as "the costs associated with the transfer, capture, and protection of rights" (p.2). Barzel (2002)Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: Economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press . argues that the easier it is to measure and verify contract stipulations, the more readily the contract can be enforced. In other words, if the property rights can be well defined, the transaction will be performed by means of a formal contract. Insofar as it is difficult to measure the attributes, the transactions will be performed by agreements and extrajudicial mechanisms to protect property rights. If the measurement cost decrease, the agents will rely on contracts more than on vertical integration.

According to Zylbersztajn (2005)Zylbersztajn, D. (2005). Papel dos contratos na coordenação agro-industrial: um olhar além dos mercados. Revista de Economia e Sociologia Rural, 43(3), 385-420., although both transaction cost economics and measurement cost theory share similarities, they differ in internal logic, explicit assumptions, and key measurable variables, which has methodological implications. Therefore, the difference between the transaction cost and the measurement cost theories deals with the empirical evidence of each theory to offer explanatory motives and testable hypotheses to determine alternative institutional arrangements. Based on Barzel (1997Barzel, Y. (1997). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press., 2002)Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: Economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press ., the property rights structure is based on formal institutions, related to legal rights and the use of contracts; and the property rights defined by informal norms related to economic rights that prevail in the agreements. According to Zylbersztajn (2010)Zylbersztajn, D. (2010). Fragile social norms: (un)sustainable exploration of forest products. International Journal on Food System Dynamics, 1, 1-12., there are always aspects of property rights, which are unprotected; therefore, part of the value is subject to capture. It can be difficult to measure the transaction attributes and the contract might therefore not be executed.

The transaction is the principal unit of analysis, whenever the property rights are negotiated. Transactions occur within the institutional environment that impact the process of the property rights exchange. As it is the case with transaction cost theory, property rights theory assumes that the contracts are incomplete. With regard to residual control, the notion of residual returns thatMilgrom and Roberts (1992)Milgrom, P. Roberts, J. (1992). Economics of Organization & Management. Prentice-Hall, New Jersey. take into account is closely linked to contractual incompleteness. If contracts are complete, the division of the wealth in each eventuality could be 'contracted on', and there would be no economic returns that could be considered as 'residual'. These two aspects of ownership - residual control and residual return - provide incentives for the owner to maintain and increase an asset's value. The clearance and enforceable property rights that cannot be transferred easily or the information asymmetry denote the inefficiency in the transaction under market or contractual relation. If property rights are neither tradable nor secure, then owners will not invest great amounts in assets that they may lose with no compensation, or they may protect the specific assets under their own control without sharing or transacting. Then, the ownership rights should be structured with a concern to minimize the distortion in investment decision caused by the hold-up problem.

2.4. Possibilities for linking the theories

The Transaction Cost Economics (TCE) perspective has dominated the studies of make-or-buy decisions, providing ample evidence that transactions characterized by high levels of asset specificity tend to be internalized (Williamson, 1975Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications. New York: Free Press., 1985Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press ., Klein et al., 1978Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., Alchian, A.A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process.Journal of Law & Economics, 21, 30.). Much progress has been made in the analysis of vertical integration issues to understand what drives the governance decisions, such as transaction characteristics used by TCE. However, as observed Jacobides and Winter (2005)Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413. other stream of studies concerning strategy has come to discuss the boundary of firm: resource and capability-based view. This approach emphasizes the importance of resources in guiding firm action, and the management of a firm's resource and capability portfolio as the central concern of strategy (Jacobides & Winter, 2005Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413.).

In terms of competence perspective, Williamson (1999)Williamson O.E. (1999). Strategy research: Governance and competence perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 1087-1108. argues that it gives greater prominence to organization theory since it "entails coordination and learning, is based on skill, assets, and routines, and is judged in comparison with rivals" (p.1094). Both governance and competence share a lot of ground and they are needed in complementary ways to understand complex phenomena of the boundary of firm, although there are differences between them (Williamson, 1999Williamson O.E. (1999). Strategy research: Governance and competence perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 1087-1108.). Then, assessing the resources bases of firms is necessary to understand choices of scope.

Jacobides and Winter (2005)Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413. work on the theoretical framework that explains how capabilities co-evolve with transaction costs in order to better understand the firms' governance structure choices. The authors focus on firm capabilities because, as they argue, in order to understand the decision to vertical integrate (or not), it is necessary to take into account the mechanisms by which transactional and capability conditions determine the choice of vertical integration. The capabilities are observed as well in the studies made by Bigelow and Argyres (2008)Bigelow, L.S., Argyres, N. (2008). Transaction costs, industry experience and make-or-buy decisions in the population of early U.S. auto firms.Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,66, 791-807.. The production experiences obtained by firms, as well as the nature of firms' pre-entry history, affect their boundaries decisions. From this perspective, firms with longer experience are more likely to integrate vertically (since they have more experience in doing so). Argyres and Zenger (2012)Argyres, N., Zenger, T. (2012). Capabilities, transaction costs, and firm boundaries. Organization Science, 1-15. discuss the importance of the transaction cost and capabilities perspectives in studying firms' boundary decisions, considering that these perspectives are interlaced in a particular dynamic way. According to these authors (Argyres & Zenger, 2012Argyres, N., Zenger, T. (2012). Capabilities, transaction costs, and firm boundaries. Organization Science, 1-15.), "if a firm possesses a comparatively superior capability because of its unique complementarity with the firm's other assets, then ownership of this capability may both explain its historical formation and be essential to protecting the rents it generates" (p.11) Resource based view and transaction cost perspectives present complementarity logics as to drivers of firm boundaries (Augusto, Souza & Cario, 2013Augusto, C.A.; Souza, J.P.; Cario, S.A.F. (2013). Estruturas de governança e recursos estratégicos em destilarias do estado do Paraná: uma análise a partir da complementaridade da ECT e da VBR. Revista de Administração [RAUSP], 48(1), 179-195.).

The resources are related to the capabilities to create and retain value. Both TCE and resource-based view (RBV) logics motivate integration in order to protect the value created from external appropriation. More generally, in order to minimize the transaction costs associated with generating and managing the assets. The protection of value is related to property rights and transaction costs as well (Barzel, 1997Barzel, Y. (1997). Economic analysis of property rights. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.; Araujo et al., 2003Araujo, L., Dubois, A., Gadde, L-E. (2003). The multiple boundaries of the firm. Journal of Management Studies, 40(7), 1255-1277.). In the property rights approach, the firm is regarded as a set of assets under common ownership and control is equated with ownership. For Araujo et al. (2003)Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413., this view is only able to provide an answer to where the boundaries of the firm should lie, when those boundaries are related to the decision about physical asset ownership. These authors include the capabilities perspective to discuss the boundaries of firm. According to them, vertical integration leads to the development of in-house capabilities. Then, the capability assessments are firm specific and are internally governed because of capability in an asset is firm specific (Argyles & Zenger, 2012Argyres, N., Zenger, T. (2012). Capabilities, transaction costs, and firm boundaries. Organization Science, 1-15.).

Table 1
Comparative Characteristics of the Three Theories

2.5. Theoretical predictions

According to the theories used to analyze some wineries in Brazil to understand the reasons for hierarchy form, the theoretical predictions are described as following:

Transaction Cost Economics: As the level of asset specificity increases in the grape-growers-winery transaction, the likelihood that hierarchical forms are used to govern the transaction increases;

Property rights: As the level information asymmetry between the grape-grower and winery increases, the likelihood that hierarchical forms are used to govern the transaction increases;

Resource Based View: As the need to learn about (changes in) grape production methods increases and the required knowledge becomes more tacit, the likelihood that hierarchical forms are used to govern the transaction increases.

3. METHODOLOGY

The research design is a multiple case study, chosen to make comparison between different real cases, thus providing more consistent insights than a single case study. The purpose of the case study method is theoretical generalization rather than statistical generalization (Yin, 1989Yin, R. K. (1989). Case study research: Design and methods. London: SAGE Publictions, Inc.;De Vaus, 2001De Vaus, D. (2001). Research design in social research. London: Sage Publications.). The objective of this study is to understand the production and transaction characteristics that lead to the choice governance form in organizations in the process of transforming grapes into wine. Three wineries were selected in order to help understand the multiple factors that influence their governance decisions. Data was gathered by means of personal interviews with owners and senior executives of the wineries. A semi-structured research instrument was used. Additionally, secondary data was collected about the Brazilian wine sector, using sources such as IBRAVIN - Instituto Brasileiro do Vinho. The three wineries are located in Vale dos Vinhedos and Vale do Rio São Francisco: Don Laurindo is located in Vale dos Vinhedos (RS); Miolo is in Vale dos Vinhedos and in Vale do Rio São Francisco; and ViniBrasil is in Vale do Rio São Francisco (Figure 1).

Figure 1
Location of the Companies Analyzed in the Case Studies

4. THE CASE OF WINE PRODUCERS IN BRASIL

By the end of 1980s, medium and large companies, and cooperatives dominated the wine industry. The grape growers supplied the wineries and only produced the grapes for the market (Schmidt, 2012Schmidt, C.M. (2012). A certificação como forma de criação e apropriação de valor no sistema agroindustrial do vinho do Vale dos Vinhedos. Cascavel, PR: EDUNIOESTE.). In terms of technology, improvement occurred in the industrial field, but the same did not happen in the viticulture sector. In the late 1980s and early 1990s, the large wineries went through economic and financial crises, and were affected by the opening of the market in the 1990s to foreign companies, which provided an environment for the increase of wine imported from 13% in 1992 to 32% in 1994 (Mello, 1995Mello, L.M.R. de. (1995). Vitinicultura no Brasil: informações estatisticas. Bento Goncalves: Embrapa/CNPUV. 67p.). Moreover, the Mercosul and the high level of tax motivated the farmers to new decisions and strategies. Thus dozens of small wineries arose in rural area. These wineries were characterized by the industrialization of wine production, which resulted in the improvement of the Brazilian fine wines quality (Falcade, 2004Falcade, I.(2004). O espaço rural e a vitivinicultura na serra gaúcha e vale dos vinhedos. Disponível em: <http://ler.letras.up.pt/uploads/ficheiros/9702.pdf>. Acesso em 14.04.2013.
http://ler.letras.up.pt/uploads/ficheiro...
).

The wine in Brazil is regulated since 1988 with the Law n. 7678 and amended with the Law 10970 in 2004, which provides regulation for production, distribution and marketing of wine and grapes.

The focus of this work is one the analysis of the upstream part of the supply chain of wine - the grape-grower and winery transaction. A supply chain is a set of commercial and financial relations which establish, among all the stages of processing a stream of exchange, located upstream and downstream, between suppliers and customers (Batalha, 2007Batalha, M. O. (Coord.). Gestão Agroindustrial.GEPAI: Grupo de Estudos e Pesquisas Agroindustriais. 3. ed São Paulo: Atlas, 2007.).

Figure 2, in general, is the systematization of the supply chain of the grape and / or wine, due to their inter-relationships. According to Garcia Filho (1999)Garcia Filho, D.P. (1999). Guia metodológico: análise diagnóstico de sistemas agrários. Convênio INCRA/FAO, Brasília, 59p. regarding the establishment of the agricultural production system, it can be defined as a combination (in time and space) of resources available for obtaining the crops and animals. A production process is a system of actions that are interrelated dynamically and are geared towards the transformation of certain elements. Thus, the input elements, the grapes, become output elements, the wine, following a process of value added.

Figure 2
Wine Supply Chain

The production itself refers to the practice of grape cultivation, corresponding to the stage of planting and harvesting (Pereira & Gameiro, 2008Pereira, E. P. e Gameiro, A. H. Sistema agroindustrial da uva no Brasil: arranjos, governanças e transações. Artigo apresentado no XLVI Congresso da Sociedade Brasileira de Economia, Administração e Sociologia Rural. Rio Branco/Acre, 2008.). Grape production in the South of Brazil, the largest producer of grapes in the country, is almost entirely focused on the manufacture of wines. Called the operation vintage harvest grape for wine making, which depends on several factors, the most important being the health and ripeness of the grapes, which defines the type of wine to be produced (Santos, Machado, Dias, Novai & Ferreira, 2007Santos, J.; Machado, A.; Dias, E.; Novai, A.; Ferreira, A.Processamento Geral dos Alimentos I - Processamento Industrial do Vinho Tinto. Instituto Politécnico de Coimbra - Escola Superior Agrária, 2007.).

4.1. Cases studies analysis

4.1.1. Miolo Wine Group

Although the Miolo winery was founded in 1989 by three brothers of Miolo's family, the company existed prior to that date, when the Miolo's family arrived in Brazil in 1897 (Dolabella & Bittencourt, 2012Dolabella, R.V.M, Bitencourt, C.C.(2012). A consolidação das competências organizacionais na vitivinicultura brasileira: o caso da vinícola Miolo. Organizações Rurais & Agroindustriais, 14(2), 174-189.). Before the foundation of the company they were only grape growers to supply wineries around their farm. The decision to start the production of wine took place because of the crisis in the Brazilian wine industry when the grapes started to have the same value as the American and hybrid grapes (Dolabella, 2006). Since 1995, sales began to grow a lot, which led the company to be the leader in the fine wine national market (P.Miolo, personal communication, March 11, 2013).

Miolo, which began producing wines from their own grapes and bottling them, also bought grapes from other 80 producers, called outgrowers, in the Vale dos Vinhedos (Dolabella, 2006). Although there is no formal contract between the Miolo and their outgrowers, the company supplied them with seeds and discounted the value of these over time and monitored the production. In the year of 2000, Miolo acquired 81 acres of land in the city of Bagé (500 km from Bento Gonçalves). The production in the lands of Bage enabled the company to reduce the number of outgrowers to 20, and the selection of these outgrowers was according to the quality, volume and adoption of planting grape in trellises. In 2006, the Miolo changed its name to Miolo Wine Group, and acquired the winery Ouro Verde in Petrolina, Vale do Rio São Francisco, where it produces sparkling wine named Terra Nova. Grapes out of its own production are used sporadically for the production of sparkling base. In case of purchasing grapes in the market, this is due to the opportunity offered by the market, when the grapes are not exported, have good quality and can be purchased at a price below its own production cost, according to Miolo (2013).

A TCE perspective: motives for vertical integration

According to the respondent of our interview, although Miolo buys the grapes from these known 20 outgrowers, if they decide no longer work with the Miolo, it would not be a big concern to the company, because the quantity purchased of them is small, around 500 tons/year, which represents 4% of the total. Because of the asset specificity (Williamson, 1991aWilliamson, O.E. (1991a). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quaterly, 36, 269-296.), such as temporal specificity, locational specificity, brand name capital, efficiency of production presented in the hierarchy arrangement justifies the preference of Miolo. The company maintains relationships with 20 selected outgrowers at that time because they were able to adapt to Miolo's requirements. Miolo offers full support for the 20 outgrowers supplying the seeds and technical assistance throughout the production process in order to obtain grapes with the required quality. There is a social aspect that Miolo and these outgrowers built a trust relation, what allow a relation without a written contract. In terms of TCE, as the reputation has been built between the parties, there is no need for all the specifications in the contract or even a contract, which decreases the ink costs.

A RBV perspective: ability to vertically integrate

Although Miolo purchases grapes from its 20 outgrowers, the wine branded Lote 43 is produced only from the grapes of its own production. This wine is named Lote 43 because it was the land that the Miolo's family received when they arrived in the Vale dos Vinhedos. Considering the RBV, the value is created on the production of the wine Lote 43 since it is direct related to the grapes produced in the Lote 43 and cannot be imitable. This specific wine for Miolo generates a competitive advantage for Miolo, using Barney's study (1991)Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120. doi:10.1177/014920639101700108.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206391017001...
. Moreover, the complex process of producing wine is related to the knowledge and skills of Miolo that is intangible assets, which are difficult to be transferred or traded. Then, the centralized control ownership into an integrated firm is justified thorough RBV theory, besides the TCE related to the asset specificity.

A property rights theory perspective: measurement problems are not an issue

In terms of Property Rights Theory, if the property rights were well defined, they could be easily traded. As Miolo has the residual control, then it is difficult to write the contract specifying all the control rights prevailing the informal contracts with its 20 outgrowers. The government (National Supply Company - CONAB) establishes the price of each grape variety. The process to obtain the quality required for the production of a particular type of wine depends on the sugar and acidity contained in the grape that can be evaluated in the laboratory, beyond the time of harvest. However, the monitoring of grape production is complex and not easily to be transferred. As Miolo prioritizes quality of grapes, it offers financial incentives to its 20 outgrowers. The company evaluates the characteristics of the grapes received and classifies them as following: 2A, 1A, 1B, 1C. According to the classification, Miolo pays a bonus on the value of the CONAB price. This bonus varies as following: 2A - plus 100% of the value of CONAB; 1A - plus 70% of the value of CONAB; 1B - plus 30% of the value of CONAB; 1C - do not buy. In this case, the attributes of transaction are defined and the measurement costs decreases. Then, Miolo can perform contracts with its 20 outgrowers than vertical integration instead, analyzed according to Barzel's studies (1982Barzel, Y. (1982). Measurement cost and the organization of markets.Journal of Law & Economics, 25(1), 27-48., 2001Barzel, Y. (2001). A theory of organizations to supersede the theory of the firm. Working Paper., 2002)Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: Economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press ..

A combined perspective

Analyzing Miolo's strategy from a governance and competence perspective, the company tends to vertical integration since competence implies coordination and learning and it is based on skill, assets, and routines. Miolo has acquired knowledge for wine production process since the experience in the wine field is before the foundation of the company, when Miolo's family only cultivated grapes. This experience makes the Miolo Wine Group more likely to integrate vertically the grape production for its wine because of resource/capability view and TCE, based on Bigelow and Argyres (2008)Bigelow, L.S., Argyres, N. (2008). Transaction costs, industry experience and make-or-buy decisions in the population of early U.S. auto firms.Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,66, 791-807.. Although Miolo brought grapes from 80 outgrowers, the winery decided to invest in its own land to increase its grape production. It has continued to purchase grapes from only 20 outgrowers, which is not very significant considering the size of the company. The decision to become more vertically integrated, according to its historical context, is because Miolo has superior productive capabilities in comparison with its outgrowers, based on Jacobides and Winter (2005)Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413.. Moreover, based on Jacobides and Winter (2005), Miolo's knowledge accumulation lead gains from its specialization in wine production process and it might imply the success in its products trade. Miolo owns the residual rights of control to produce its wine according to its requirement. These residual rights are difficult to be expressed into a contract (Milgrom & Roberts, 1992Milgrom, P. Roberts, J. (1992). Economics of Organization & Management. Prentice-Hall, New Jersey.); then Miolo is more likely vertically integrated.

4.1.2. Don Laurindo Winery

Don Laurindo is a small family company, producing both grapes and wine. It has only nine employees, all of which are members of the Brandelli family that founded the company. The company is located within the main wine production region of Rio Grande do Sul, Vale dos Vinhedos, close to the cities of Bento Gonçalves and Garibaldi. There, Don Laurindo owns 15 hectares of vineyards from which it produces 120.000 bottles of wine each year. For its wine production, the company uses only grapes from its own vineyards. The company markets its wines almost exclusively within Brazil; just 2% of its production is exported(1) (1) Its main export markets are Canada, the Czech Republic and Mexico. .

The company's history goes back to the late 19th century, when the current owners' great grandfather, Marcelino Brandelli, emigrated from Italy to Brazil. This was a period in which Rio Grande do Sul attracted many immigrants from Italy. Brazil's federal government incentivized the immigrants to come to the state by offering them favorable terms to purchase land. The Italians were mainly offered land within the Serra Gaúcha region, where Vale dos Vinhedos is located. When Mr. Brandelli arrived there in the 1880s, he relied on substance farming to support him-self. He also started to grow vineyards in order to make wine for family consumption.

Mr. Brandelli's offspring purchased additional land for commercial grape production, while continuing the patriarch's tradition of making wine for friends and family. This modus operandi, where the Brandelli family commercialized its grapes but not its wines, continued until the beginning of the 1990s. During the systemic crisis that plagued Brazilian`s wine industry in this period, the family`s main customer stopped procuring grapes while earlier several of its smaller customers had already gone bankrupt. Subsequently, the family started its own winery - Vinhos Don Laurindo LTDA. As of today, the company markets all of its grape production to its own internal winery. The winery uses the grapes to produce 90.000 liters of wine each year. Ninety percent of this is red wine, while the remaining 10 percent is white wine (including sparkling wine). A couple of its wines are certified as "Origin Controlled Denomination". (A.Brandelli, personal communication, March 11, 2013).

A TCE perspective: motives for vertical integration

The transaction attributes demand uncertainty and temporal asset specificity help to explain why the company integrated into wine production. The main purpose of the company in taking this step was to guarantee its survival during adverse market conditions. This decision was more or less forced on the company because of these two TCE factors; integration helped the company to economize on transaction costs resulting from uncertainty and temporal asset specificity.

Demand uncertainty was the main factor in the company decision. Market conditions can certainly be characterized as uncertain when Don Laurindo integrated into wine production. As it is explained above, the Brazilian wine industry was affected by a crisis in the beginning of the 1990s. This perhaps especially affected Don Laurindo, as its main customer stopped procuring its grapes. Thus, it not only faced the prospect of low grape-prices and uncertainty about future demand, it had also lost its main marketing channel. To understand the company decision to make its own wine, note that the company would have been less affected by demand uncertainty as an integrated grape grower-winery operation than as an independent grape grower. Grapes have to be harvested within a certain period and cannot be stored, unlike wine. Therefore, an integrated grape grower-winery has more control over the time at which it markets its (wine) output as it can hold inventory when demand is low(2) (2) Note that companies are not able to hold inventory if they face strong liquidity constraints (i.e., when they need to sell of inventory to generate cash). Differential liquidity constraints amongst industry participants may therefore explain why some of them were not able to withstand the crisis. . As an independent grape grower, Don Laurindo was not able to hold inventory. Integrated helped the company to reduce its exposure to uncertainty.

While the above-mentioned market conditions were an obvious factor in Don Laurindo's decision to start marketing its own wines, the role of asset specificity was subtler. At present, grape grower-winery relations in the Vale dos Vinhedos region do not seem to be characterized by asset specificity related concerns. There are multiple wineries within the region and grape growers can easily switch from one winery to another as most wineries use similar types of grape-inputs. However, during the crisis, temporal specificity (e.g., see Williamson, 1991aWilliamson, O.E. (1991a). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quaterly, 36, 269-296.) could have affected grape grower-winery transactions. Especially, wineries might have used the above-mentioned temporal constraints that affect grape production to opportunistically renegotiate transaction terms. They would certainly be in position to do this; grape growers would have had fewer alternatives to market their grapes than during normal market conditions, as several wineries faced difficulties. Forward integration into wine production reduces a grape-grower's exposure to such temporal related opportunism. While retailers may also attempt to renegotiate transaction terms, temporal constraints play a more limited role as the winery can store its output. Vertical integrated therefore also helped to reduce the company`s exposure to demand risk of opportunism, in line with TCE`s predictions.

A RBV perspective: ability to vertically integrate

The crisis not only had a downside. With various wineries now experiencing difficulties, the wine market was also less crowded than before. The company saw this as an opportunity to leverage its human resources and start marketing its own wines, using its high quality grapes and knowledge about wine-production to make exclusive wines. The company was able to forward integrate because the family honed the tacit knowledge or skill of making high quality wine over various generations. Thus, while demand uncertainty forced the company to take action, the reason it was able to start producing its wine was that the company already possessed the human resources to do it. In other words, while TCE factors helps us to understand the company`s motive to vertically integrate, RBV helps us to understand why the company was in position to do this.

RBV helps to explain not only why the company was able to integrate into wine production, but also why the company is still organized in this manner. The Brandelli family has a long tradition in the production of grapes (and wine) and this cannot be easily replicated in the market. According to the management of Don Laurindo, it is not difficult to find high-quality grape producers in Vale dos Vinhedos, as also external grape growers possess the required human and physical resources to produce high quality grapes. However, they lack the required tacit knowledge about how producing the grapes with the specific characteristics Don Laurindo requires for its particular wines. This knowledge, embedded deeply within the norms and routines of the organization, cannot be easily codified and communicated to external grape growers.

A property rights theory perspective: measurement problems are not an issue

PRT appears, at first, less relevant than the other two theories for explaining the firms choice of governance form. For example, according to the management of Don Laurindo, it is not difficult to measure grape quality (e.g., laboratory analysis can reveal the acid levels of the grapes). Therefore, no material information asymmetries exist between grape producers and wine producers about the quality of the grapes. If the company did use external suppliers, shirking or quality cheating by those suppliers would not be a problem; the suppliers could be paid based on the quality of the delivered grapes. For example, Don Laurindo could give the suppliers bonuses if the grapes meet or exceed its requirements (as Miolo does).

However, issues with regard to residual control rights over the production process do affect the company choice of procurement form. While many aspects of the production process could be specified in advance in contracts with external grape growers (e.g., type of grapes to use, type of technology), such contracts would limit the company ability and rights to make adjustments to the process when it so desires. Internal procurement gives the company full control over how the production process is organized and it can make adjustments to that process whenever it wants.

A combined perspective

The Don Laurindo case showed that, as Williamson (1999)Williamson O.E. (1999). Strategy research: Governance and competence perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 1087-1108. observed, the TCE and RBV perspectives are complementary. While a TCE perspective help to explain why Don Laurindo vertically integrated into wine-production, a RBV perspective explains why the company was in a position to do so. Furthermore, both perspectives combine well with the Property-Rights (PR) perspective in this case. PR helps to explain why Don Laurindo remains fully vertically integrated; i.e., it sheds light on why the winery-part of the company does not procure grapes (also) from external grape-grower.

From a TCE perspective, high temporal asset specificity and demand uncertainty increased the company`s costs of transacting with external wineries. Vertical integration into wine-production reduced those costs. From a RBV perspective, the knowledge and experience Don Laurindo had acquired over various generations about wine-production over various generations meant that the company already had the required competences to make high-quality wines. Based on a study of Bigelow and Argyres (2008)Bigelow, L.S., Argyres, N. (2008). Transaction costs, industry experience and make-or-buy decisions in the population of early U.S. auto firms.Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,66, 791-807. that combines RBV with TCE, it is observed that the experience of Don Laurindo in wine production makes the company more likely to move from being a mere grape-producer to being also a wine producer. Because Don Laurindo is vertical integrated, this governance structure affects the knowledge development process and allows it to also develop and leverage its superior capabilities in wine-making, according toJacobides and Winter (2005)Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413.. From a PR perspective, the company remains vertically integrated rather than, for example, spinning-of the grape-production part of its business, because of difficulties in fully specifying residual control rights over the grape-production process. Sourcing grapes from external grape-growers is furthermore not a desirable option for Don Laurindo because such grape-growers lack the tacit knowledge to produce the specific grapes that the companies require for the production of its fine wines. Therefore, Don Laurindo remains integrated also because of the superior capability of its internal-grape grower vis-à-vis external growers to make the grapes it needs (see also Argyres & Zenger, 2012Argyres, N., Zenger, T. (2012). Capabilities, transaction costs, and firm boundaries. Organization Science, 1-15.).

4.1.3. ViniBrasil (Global Wines/Dão Sul)

ViniBrasil was founded in June 2003, started by a top Portuguese wine company, Dão Sul. It is located in the Vale do Rio São Francisco, which in itself makes an interesting story as the vast majority of wineries producing fine wines in Brazil are located in the Vale dos Vinhedos - RS. ViniBrasil grows its grapes in a challenging environment (close to the equator) using innovative management practices such as controlled irrigation and year-round harvesting (Bell, Neves, Thomé e Castro & Shelman, 2010Bell, D., Neves, M. F., Thomé e Castro, l., Shelman, M. (2010). Vinibrasil: New latitude wines. Harvard Business School. Case 509-003.).

The company currently has a total production area of ​​2000 hectares, with 200 hectares of grapes, as well as an experimental area for testing new varieties and combinations. The winery produces about 1 million liters of wine/year, with 84 permanent employees (J.Santos, personal communication, March 14, 2013).

The ViniBrasil positioned itself as a winery producing differentiated wine-products in Brazil. The price for the final consumer is equivalent to the price of fine wines in the market, and even below some of the wine products from Argentina and Chile (Bell et al, 2010Bell, D., Neves, M. F., Thomé e Castro, l., Shelman, M. (2010). Vinibrasil: New latitude wines. Harvard Business School. Case 509-003.) and its product portfolio consists of the following brands: Rio Sol, Paralelo 8 Tenants, Vinha Maria, Matuto and Adega do Vale. Paralelo 8 is the highest quality wine of ViniBrasil.

A TCE perspective: motives for vertical integration

Similar to Don Laurindo case, the transaction attributes demand uncertainty and temporal asset specificity. These characteristics help to explain the ViniBrasil decision to produce the grapes in-house. ViniBrasil opted to have total control of production since its foundation. Then, the company produces its own grapes in order to acquire the characteristics required for its wine production. Santos (2013) observes the fact that having its own grape production, the company eliminates demand problems since it controls what will produce. Currently, the company is guaranteed with a stock production for a year of sales.

Site specificity is one of the most important assets for ViniBrasil, because its wine is characterized as unique wine with qualities related to the location. The ViniBrasil invested in brands, highlighting specific characteristics of the region and its wines. For example, the Rio Sol is a brand that blends the idea of the São Francisco River with the sun, which explains the geographical location of the winery - the border of the São Francisco River, 8 degrees south latitude. The region at this latitude is the exception to produce commercial wines, as well as being one of the new frontiers wineries in the world. Also the slogan used by the company highlights this feature, "New Latitude, New Attitude" (p.12) according toBell's et al. study (2010)Bell, D., Neves, M. F., Thomé e Castro, l., Shelman, M. (2010). Vinibrasil: New latitude wines. Harvard Business School. Case 509-003., that means that produce wines overcoming technical paradigms, such as the use of irrigation in a semi-arid region.

A RBV perspective: ability to vertically integrate

ViniBrasil has invested in innovation, breeding of grapes, because the company believed that it would not be easy to find suppliers of grapes in the Vale do Rio São Francisco with the same characteristics as those produced by ViniBrasil. The expertise of the production process has been developed over the years since the region has a particular climate in comparison with other producing regions in Brazil.

The workers have few job options in Vale do Rio São Francisco what make favorable for ViniBrasil. The number of permanent employees increases in the company and some of them have been working in ViniBrasil since its foundation. This aspect is extremely important because the company has been developing its human resources over the years. It is understood that vertical integration enables the company to control the entire process and prevents it from being imitated. They have been investing for many years in grapes adapted to the Vale do Rio São Francisco, and they created an intangible asset that is difficult to be copied or even switched.

A property rights theory perspective: measurement problems are not an issue

ViniBrasil wants to ensure that all the investment it has made ​​over the years, such as in innovation, improvement of grape seeds adapted to the region, and irrigation, is secure. The company is interested in appropriating the value created. Thus, for the firm, vertical integration allows the company to create value and also to keep the value created. Furthermore, the winery has the residual control rights over the production process. Similar to Don Laurindo, ViniBrasil can make adjustments to its production process whenever it is necessary. Since there are no suppliers with the ViniBrasil requirements, they need to be developed and this process of development involves knowledge transfer and higher investments in irrigation. Moreover, ViniBrasil would need to monitor these suppliers. On the other hands, these suppliers could require part of the residual control rights. Sharing the knowledge with the suppliers, ViniBrasil could fail to appropriate the value generated through the brand related to its location.

A combined perspective

ViniBrasil invested in capability improvement in the particular climate of Vale do Rio São Francisco. According to Jacobides and Winter (2005)Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413., the development of capabilities depends on how integrated a firm is. ViniBrasil made specific investments and created superior capability to cultivate grapes for its wine in a Brazilian region that is radically different from other grape producing regions. Because of its superior capability, outside suppliers with comparable capability do not exist; therefore, ViniBrasil continues to be integrated (Argyres & Zenger, 2012Argyres, N., Zenger, T. (2012). Capabilities, transaction costs, and firm boundaries. Organization Science, 1-15.). ViniBrasil possesses its own grape production process for providing specific grapes to its wine that developed a superior capability in comparison with outside grape producers. It is observed that capability resource view and TCE perspectives are complementary. Besides the resource/capability resource based view, ViniBrasil has the residual control rights and does not want to share the knowledge to other suppliers what makes this winery for vertical integration choice.

5. FINAL REMARKS

In this paper we studied governance decisions in the Brazilian wine industry. Especially, we examined the types of governance forms three wineries used to procure their grapes. We analyzed the governance decisions through three different theoretical lenses: TCE, PRT, and RBV. We used the cases to illustrate that, in isolation, each of the theories yields insufficient insights into the motives and ability for firms to select and use hierarchical governance forms. Table 2 summarizes the main results of the study.

Table 2
Comparative Characteristics of the Three Theories Applied to the Wineries Cases

The table shows how the different theoretical perspectives are complementary. While TCE and PRT are mainly useful for identifying the motives companies have to vertically integrate, RBV is more useful for identifying whether companies have capabilities to integrate or undertake a certain production activity (in this case wine-production). Studies that would have used only a single theoretical perspective to analyze these transactions would have given only a limited insight in the companies` governance decisions in each case. For example, a study that would analyze the Don Laurindo case only from a TCE perspective would not be able to explain why the company remains vertically integrated. That is because the TCE factors that led the company to integrate into wine production (demand uncertainty and temporal asset specificity) are no longer present. Likewise, a RBV analysis of the case would not be able to explain why the company, if it had the capabilities to make fine wines, it did not integrate earlier into wine production; i.e., it would only be able to explain why the company was able to integrate, but notwhen it choose to do so. Furthermore, a PR analysis of the case would be able to explain why the company remains integrated, but not be able to explain why it integrated in the first place. This is because the difficulty the wine-part of the company had in specifying control rights of the grape-production process only arose after the company integrated into wine production.

While some studies argue for integrating the different theoretical perspectives, we would not go so far. In our opinion, combining the various perspectives is a sufficient and a more productive way forward. In the former (integrating theoretical perspectives), a shared theoretical language would need to be developed (e.g., changing `asset specificity` for `idiosyncratic competences`) and possible inconsistencies in the different theoretical perspectives would need to be overcome (e.g., situations in which one perspective argues for integration and another perspective argues against). In the latter (combining theoretical perspectives), researchers simply attempt to study the subject of their analysis from various angles. Whenever the perspectives offer conflicting recommendations, the researcher opportunistically uses the perspective, which best help to explain the studied phenomenon. And, more importantly, the researcher attempts to leverage the best of each perspective; that is the researchers attempts to use the various perspectives to explain different aspects of the studied phenomenon (e.g., to use TCE for studying the motivation of a company to integrate, and to use RBV for studying its ability to integrate). Our study suggests that future research into this complex interaction among the three different theories is well warranted to explain the hierarchical governance form.

  • Sistema de Avaliação: Double Blind Review
    Editor Científico: Nicolau Reinhard
  • We thank The Center for Organization Studies CORS-USP for the financial support for the research on these three wineries. We thank Prof. Maria Sylvia Macchione Saes and Prof. Daniel Friel for the motivation and important comments for this research.
  • (1)
    Its main export markets are Canada, the Czech Republic and Mexico.
  • (2)
    Note that companies are not able to hold inventory if they face strong liquidity constraints (i.e., when they need to sell of inventory to generate cash). Differential liquidity constraints amongst industry participants may therefore explain why some of them were not able to withstand the crisis.

REFERENCES

  • Alchian, A.A., Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs and economic organization. American Economic Review, 62,777-795.
  • Alchian, A. (1984). Specificity, specialization and coalitions.Journal of Economic Theory and Institutions, 140(3), 34-49.
  • Araujo, L., Dubois, A., Gadde, L-E. (2003). The multiple boundaries of the firm. Journal of Management Studies, 40(7), 1255-1277.
  • Argyres, N., Zenger, T. (2012). Capabilities, transaction costs, and firm boundaries. Organization Science, 1-15.
  • Augusto, C.A.; Souza, J.P.; Cario, S.A.F. (2013). Estruturas de governança e recursos estratégicos em destilarias do estado do Paraná: uma análise a partir da complementaridade da ECT e da VBR. Revista de Administração [RAUSP], 48(1), 179-195.
  • Barney, J. (1991). Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Journal of Management, 17(1), 99-120. doi:10.1177/014920639101700108.
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639101700108
  • Barney, J. B. (2001). Is the resource-based "view" a useful perspective for strategic management research? Yes. The Academy of Management Review, 26, 41-56.
  • Barney, J. B., Hansen, M. H. (1994). Trustworthiness as a source of competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal, 15, 175-190.
  • Barney, J.B., Arikan, A.M. (2001). The resource-based view: Origins and implications. In Hitt, M.A., Freeman, R.E., Harrison, J.S. (2001).Handbook of Strategic Management Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
  • Barzel, Y. (1982). Measurement cost and the organization of markets.Journal of Law & Economics, 25(1), 27-48.
  • Barzel, Y. (1997). Economic analysis of property rights Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
  • Barzel, Y. (2001). A theory of organizations to supersede the theory of the firm. Working Paper
  • Barzel, Y. (2002). A theory of the state: Economic rights, legal rights, and the scope of the state Cambridge: Cambridge University Press .
  • Batalha, M. O. (Coord.). Gestão Agroindustrial.GEPAI: Grupo de Estudos e Pesquisas Agroindustriais. 3. ed São Paulo: Atlas, 2007.
  • Bell, D., Neves, M. F., Thomé e Castro, l., Shelman, M. (2010). Vinibrasil: New latitude wines. Harvard Business School Case 509-003.
  • Bigelow, L.S., Argyres, N. (2008). Transaction costs, industry experience and make-or-buy decisions in the population of early U.S. auto firms.Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,66, 791-807.
  • Coase, R. H. (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386-404.
  • Coase, R. H. (1960). El problema del costo social. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, (october), 1-44.
  • Conner, K.R. (1991). A historical comparison of resource- based theory and five schools of thought within industrial organization economics: Do we have a new theory of the firm? Journal of Management,17, 121-154.
  • De Vaus, D. (2001). Research design in social research London: Sage Publications.
  • Demsetz, H. (1967). Toward a theory of property rights. The American Economic Review, 57, 2.
  • Dolabella, R.V.M, Bitencourt, C.C.(2012). A consolidação das competências organizacionais na vitivinicultura brasileira: o caso da vinícola Miolo. Organizações Rurais & Agroindustriais, 14(2), 174-189.
  • Embrapa. Embrapa Uva e Vinho. (2007). Disponível em: http://sistemasdeproducao.cnptia.embrapa.br/FontesHTML/Uva/UvaNiagaraRosadaRegioesTropicais/index.htm. Acesso em 20.02.2008
    » http://sistemasdeproducao.cnptia.embrapa.br/FontesHTML/Uva/UvaNiagaraRosadaRegioesTropicais/index.htm. Acesso em 20.02.2008
  • Falcade, I.(2004). O espaço rural e a vitivinicultura na serra gaúcha e vale dos vinhedos. Disponível em: <http://ler.letras.up.pt/uploads/ficheiros/9702.pdf>. Acesso em 14.04.2013.
    » http://ler.letras.up.pt/uploads/ficheiros/9702.pdf
  • Foss, K., Foss, N. J. (2005). Resources and transaction costs: How property rights economics furthers the resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal, 553(12), 541-553. doi:10.1002/smj.465.
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.465
  • Garcia Filho, D.P. (1999). Guia metodológico: análise diagnóstico de sistemas agrários Convênio INCRA/FAO, Brasília, 59p.
  • Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J.E. ,Kumar, N.(2006). Make, buy, or ally: A transaction cost theory meta-analysis. The Academy of Management Journal, 49(3), 519-543.
  • Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. Bell Journal of Economics, 13, 324-340.
  • IBRAVIN (2013a). História do vinho no Brasil. Disponível em:http://www.ibravin.org.br/historia-do-vinho-no-brasil.php> Acesso em 25 de marco de 2013.
    » http://www.ibravin.org.br/historia-do-vinho-no-brasil.php
  • IBRAVIN (2013b). Principais regiões produtoras. Disponível em:http://www.ibravin.org.br/regioesprodutoras.php Acesso em 25 de marco de 2013.
    » http://www.ibravin.org.br/regioesprodutoras.php
  • Jacobides, M.G., Winter, S.G. (2005). The co-evolution of capabilities and transaction costs: Explaning the institutional structure of production. Strategic Management Journal, 26, 395-413.
  • Kim, J., & Mahoney, J.T. (2002). Resource-based and property rights perspectives on value creation: The case of oil field unitization.Managerial and Decision Economics, 23 (4/5): 225-245. doi: 10.1002/mde.1063.
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1063
  • Kim, J., & Mahoney, J. T. (2005). Property rights theory, transaction costs theory, and agency theory: An organizational economics approach to strategic management. Managerial and Decision Economics, 26, 223-242. doi:10.1002/mde.1218.
    » https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.1218
  • Kim, J., & Mahoney, J.T. (2007) Appropriating economic rents from resources: An integrative property rights and resource-based approach.International Journal of Learning and Intellectual Capital,4(1/2). doi: 10.1504/IJLIC.2007.013820
    » https://doi.org/10.1504/IJLIC.2007.013820
  • Klein, B., Crawford, R. G., Alchian, A.A. (1978). Vertical integration, appropriable rents, and the competitive contracting process.Journal of Law & Economics, 21, 30.
  • Koenig, C.L.C., Sousa, R.N.L., Watanabe, K., Wever, M. The fine wine industry in Brazil: The cases of Miolo, Don Laurindo, and ViniBrasil Wineries. In: Ménard, C.; Saes, M.S.M., Silva, V.L.S., Raynaud, E.(Eds) Challenges to Economic Organization. Plural Forms São Paulo: Atlas , p. 225-241, 2014.
  • Madhok, A. (2002). Reassessing the fundamentals and beyond: Ronald Coase, the transaction cost and resource-based theories of the firm, and the institutional structure of production. Strategic ManagementJournal, 23: 535-550.
  • Mello, L.M.R. de. (1995). Vitinicultura no Brasil: informações estatisticas Bento Goncalves: Embrapa/CNPUV. 67p.
  • Milgrom, P. Roberts, J. (1992). Economics of Organization & Management Prentice-Hall, New Jersey.
  • Pereira, E. P. e Gameiro, A. H. Sistema agroindustrial da uva no Brasil: arranjos, governanças e transações Artigo apresentado no XLVI Congresso da Sociedade Brasileira de Economia, Administração e Sociologia Rural. Rio Branco/Acre, 2008.
  • Peteraf, M. A. (1993). The cornerstones of competitive advantage: a resource-based view. Strategic Management Journal14(3), 179-91.
  • Protas, J.F. (2008). A produção de vinhos finos: um flash do desafio brasileiro. Agropec. Catarin, 21(3),1.
  • Rindfleisch, A., Heide, J.B. (1997). Transaction cost analysis: Past, present and future applications. Journal of Marketing, (61:4), October, pp. 30-54.
  • Rumelt, R. P. (1984). Towards a strategic theory of the firm. In: Richard B. Lamb, ed. Competitive Strategic Management New Jersey: Englewood Cliffs, 1984, p.556-570.
  • Santos, J.; Machado, A.; Dias, E.; Novai, A.; Ferreira, A.Processamento Geral dos Alimentos I - Processamento Industrial do Vinho Tinto Instituto Politécnico de Coimbra - Escola Superior Agrária, 2007.
  • Schmidt, C.M. (2012). A certificação como forma de criação e apropriação de valor no sistema agroindustrial do vinho do Vale dos Vinhedos Cascavel, PR: EDUNIOESTE.
  • Simon, H.A. (1957). Models of man: Social and rational. mathematical essays on rational human behavior in a social setting John Wiley &Sons, New York, NY.
  • Teece, D. J., & Pisano, G. (1994). The dynamics capabilities of firms. Industrial and Corporate Change, 3(3), 537-556.
  • Wernerfelt B. (1984). A resource-based theory of the firm.Strategic Management Journal, 5(2), 171-180.
  • Whinston, M.D. (2003). On the transaction cost determinants of vertical integration. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 19(1), 1-23.
  • Williamson, O.E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies: Analysis and antitrust implications New York: Free Press.
  • Williamson, O.E. (1979). The governance of contractual relations.Journal of Law and Economics, (22:2), October, 233-261.
  • Williamson, O.E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. Firms, markets, relational contracting New York: Free Press .
  • Williamson, O.E. (1991a). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discrete structural alternatives. Administrative Science Quaterly, 36, 269-296.
  • Williamson, O.E. (1991b). Economic institutions: spontaneous and intentional governance. Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, 7, January, pp. 159-187.
  • Williamson, O.E. (1996). The mechanism of governance New York; Oxford: Oxford University Press.
  • Williamson O.E. (1999). Strategy research: Governance and competence perspectives. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 1087-1108.
  • Williamson, O. E. (2005). The economics of governance. The American Economic Review, 95(2), 1-18.
  • Yin, R. K. (1989). Case study research: Design and methods London: SAGE Publictions, Inc.
  • Zylbersztajn, D. (2005). Papel dos contratos na coordenação agro-industrial: um olhar além dos mercados. Revista de Economia e Sociologia Rural, 43(3), 385-420.
  • Zylbersztajn, D. (2010). Fragile social norms: (un)sustainable exploration of forest products. International Journal on Food System Dynamics, 1, 1-12.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Jan-Mar 2016

History

  • Received
    01 Jan 2014
  • Accepted
    20 Aug 2015
Departamento de Administração da Faculdade de Economia, Administração e Contabilidade da Universidade de São Paulo Avenida Professor Luciano Gualberto, 908, sala F184, 05508-900 São Paulo / SP Brasil, Tel./Fax 55 11 3818-4002 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: rausp@usp.br