Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Measuring unemployment persistence of different labor force groups in the Greater São Paulo Metropolitan Area

Abstracts

This article makes use of ARFIMA models and unit root tests with structural breaks to examine the unemployment persistence of different labor forces in the Greater Metropolitan Area of São Paulo. To this purpose, not only is the region's open unemployment rate analyzed but it is also disaggregated by gender, age, color and position within the household. The period ranges from January 1985 to November 2008 and, despite using a range of estimation methods, the presence of a unit root cannot be rejected in general. The exceptions are the series related to Age 15-17 and over 40. But even in these cases the parameter "d" lies above 0.5. This is an indication that the unemployment rates in São Paulo can be defined as non stationary and the majority of the series are not mean-reverting. Therefore, the disinflation policies implemented by the Brazilian policymakers in the last two decades, as well as changes in real variables, have had long-lasting effects on the unemployment rates in São Paulo.

Unemployment; persistence; long memory; unit root


Este artigo usa modelos ARFIMA e testes de raiz unitária com quebra estrutural para examinar o grau de persistência do desemprego de diferentes estratos da força de trabalho na Região Metropolitana de São Paulo. Para tanto, a taxa agregada desta região é examinada, como também sua desagregação por gênero, idade, raça e posição dentro da família. O período de análise vai de janeiro de 1985 a novembro 2008 e, apesar do uso de diferentes métodos de estimação, a hipótese de raiz unitária não é rejeitada em geral. As duas exceções são as séries relacionadas aos trabalhadores entre 15 e 17 anos e acima dos 40 anos. Mas, mesmo nestes dois casos, o parâmetro "d" fica acima de 0,5. Isso indica que não há estacionariedade e também não há reversão a uma média de longo prazo para a maioria das séries analisadas. Portanto, as políticas econômicas de combate à inflação das últimas duas décadas, assim como mudanças em variáveis reais, têm gerado efeitos duradouros sobre a taxa de desemprego em São Paulo.

Desemprego; persistência; memória longa; raiz unitária


Measuring unemployment persistence of different labor force groups in the Greater São Paulo Metropolitan Area

Cleomar Gomes da SilvaI, * * Endereço para contato: Rua Itapeva 474, 11º andar, São Paulo - SP. E-mail: cleomar.gomes@fgv.br ; Fábio Augusto Reis GomesII, ** ** Endereço para contato: Rua Quatá 300, São Paulo - SP. E-mail: FabioARG@insper.org.br

IFundação Getulio Vargas de São Paulo

IIInsper Instituto de Ensino e Pesquisa

RESUMO

Este artigo usa modelos ARFIMA e testes de raiz unitária com quebra estrutural para examinar o grau de persistência do desemprego de diferentes estratos da força de trabalho na Região Metropolitana de São Paulo. Para tanto, a taxa agregada desta região é examinada, como também sua desagregação por gênero, idade, raça e posição dentro da família. O período de análise vai de janeiro de 1985 a novembro 2008 e, apesar do uso de diferentes métodos de estimação, a hipótese de raiz unitária não é rejeitada em geral. As duas exceções são as séries relacionadas aos trabalhadores entre 15 e 17 anos e acima dos 40 anos. Mas, mesmo nestes dois casos, o parâmetro "d" fica acima de 0,5. Isso indica que não há estacionariedade e também não há reversão a uma média de longo prazo para a maioria das séries analisadas. Portanto, as políticas econômicas de combate à inflação das últimas duas décadas, assim como mudanças em variáveis reais, têm gerado efeitos duradouros sobre a taxa de desemprego em São Paulo.

Palavras-chave: Desemprego, persistência, memória longa, raiz unitária

ABSTRACT

This article makes use of ARFIMA models and unit root tests with structural breaks to examine the unemployment persistence of different labor forces in the Greater Metropolitan Area of São Paulo. To this purpose, not only is the region's open unemployment rate analyzed but it is also disaggregated by gender, age, color and position within the household. The period ranges from January 1985 to November 2008 and, despite using a range of estimation methods, the presence of a unit root cannot be rejected in general. The exceptions are the series related to Age 15-17 and over 40. But even in these cases the parameter "d" lies above 0.5. This is an indication that the unemployment rates in São Paulo can be defined as non stationary and the majority of the series are not mean-reverting. Therefore, the disinflation policies implemented by the Brazilian policymakers in the last two decades, as well as changes in real variables, have had long-lasting effects on the unemployment rates in São Paulo.

Keywords: Unemployment, persistence, long memory, unit root.

JEL Classification: C32, E24

1 INTRODUCTION

The Greater São Paulo Metropolitan Area is one of the five most populous places in the world. According to the 2006 estimate released by IBGE, the Brazilian Bureau of Geography and Statistics, the region has a population of around 19 million people in its 55 municipalities and the city of São Paulo itself has a population of over 11 million. Therefore, the Greater São Paulo Metropolitan Area accounts for about 10% of the total Brazilian population. Such magnitude has made unemployment an important issue, especially in the last two decades. And this is due to many factors, such as a series of failed economic stabilization plans in the 1980s and in the beginning of the 1990s.

The implementation of the Real Plan, in 1994, can be considered to be the turning point in the Brazilian economy, once it was the first stabilization package that really managed to bring down inflation in the country. Nonetheless, Brazilian policymakers opted to keep an appreciated fixed exchange rate, which culminated in serious consequences to the trade balance account, level of international reserves and unemployment rates as well. All of these factors together, and a deep international crisis, forced the country to adopt a flexible exchange rate in 1999. Shortly after the exchange rate depreciation, the Brazilian central bank adopted an inflation targeting regime so as to build credibility on its intention to fight inflation and put the country back on the track.

Theoretically, NAIRU and Hysteresis are the two main hypotheses related to the explanation of unemployment and its persistence. Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1968) proposed the Natural Rate Hypothesis, arguing that real variables determined their own behavior and, consequently, they could not be influenced permanently by nominal variables, such as inflation. As a result, unemployment would converge to its natural rate in the long run, i.e., it should be a non-integrated process, I(0), with transitory shocks. On the other hand, Blanchard and Summers (1986) showed that the insider's bargaining power in wage-setting implied that aggregate employment is a random walk process with a drift. In this case, the unemployment rate would be an integrated process, I(1), and any shock to the series would shift unemployment equilibrium permanently from one level to another. This persistence is what defines the so-called Hysteresis phenomenon.1 1 Other sources of hysteresis are: i) deterioration of skills, i.e., unemployed workers are unable to update their skills and, consequently, have their probabilities of finding a new work reduced even when demand is recovered; ii) labor-force attachment, i.e., individuals who are unemployed for long periods may adjust their standard of living to a lower level and/or may even get used to the joblessness situation and so the labor supply decreases permanently (ROMER, 2001). See Roed (1997) for other sources of hysteresis. In other words, perturbations affecting unemployment can be either transitory (NAIRU) or permanent (Hysteresis) and the degree of persistence they generate is a key determinant of the costs of disinflation policies.

As far as econometrics is concerned, the two theories stated in the previous paragraph can be evaluated by means of unit root tests, in which the order of integration d of the unemployment rate is tested. There is even the possibility to use unit root tests which take into account structural breaks. This was done in several articles such as: Neudorfer et al. (1990), Mitchell (1993), Jaeger and Parkinson (1994), Song and Wu (1998), Arestis and Mariscal (1999), Camarero and Tamarit (2004), Clement et al. (2005). For the Brazilian, there are, among others, Gomes and Gomes da Silva (2008; 2009).

However, this methodology imposes that d assumes an integer value, i.e., unemployment is either I(0) or I(1), and discards the possibility of a non-integer parameter. Auto-Regressive-Fractionally-Integrated-Moving-Average (ARFIMA) models account for this matter, allowing for a fractional difference parameter d. This methodology helps to overcome the well-known problem of low power of traditional unit roots and also helps to jointly model short-run and long-run dynamics of unemployment.

For the reasons mentioned, there has been a growing number of literature concerned about unemployment persistence. For instance, Koustas and Veloce (1996) made use of ARFIMA models to assess output and unemployment persistence for Canadian and American data. Both exhibit higher persistence in Canada when compared to the USA. Mikhail et al. (2006) revised the Canadian aggregate unemployment case using a Bayesian ARFIMA model and found evidence that persistence is stronger than previously reported by Koustas and Veloce (1996). Gil-Alana (2001a) analyzed USA, Germany, France, Italy and the UK. His results indicated more persistence in unemployment rates of Great Britain and France, when compared to Germany and the USA. In another paper, Gil-Alana (2001b) studied the unemployment evolution of nineteen countries (Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Netherlands, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, UK, USA). His results pointed out that the order of integration of most countries is higher than one, the exceptions being the USA, Japan, Austria, Italy and Canada. Gil-Alana and Brian Henry (2003) analyzed unemployment in UK and found that the order of integration of unemployment for the country is higher than 0.5 but smaller than 1, which means that it is non-stationary but with a mean-reverting behavior. Tolvi (2003) used ARFIMA models to study the unemployment persistence of different labor forces in Finland, finding less persistence in the series for females and young people than for the entire labor force and males.

However, these researches do not take into consideration that possibility that the persistence detected by the ARFIMA model can be caused by structural breaks in the series. Theoretically, the importance of analyzing such possibility has been done by Diebold and Inoue (2001), who wrote that the long-memory literature has not paid enough attention to the possibility of confusing structural breaks and long memory processes. Granger and Hyung (2004) also approached the same problem, showing that omitting occasional breaks leads to an overestimated d. For instance, Baum, Barkoulasb and Caglayanc (1999) analyzed the real exchange rate of several countries in the post-Bretton Woods era, concluding that the unit-root hypothesis is robust against both fractional alternatives and structural breaks. Asikainen (2003) did something for the Finnish and Swedish party popularity series. According to the author's findings, three series tested had structural breaks and, in two cases, the control of the breaks changed the unit root assumption to a fractional unit root.

This study attempts to fill this research gap for the Brazilian case.2 2 For the Brazilian case, we are unaware of studies comparing hysteresis and NAIRU. But there are papers related to NAIRU only. For example, Portugal and Madalozzo (2000) and Lima (2000) did not confirm the NAIRU hypothesis, which might be an indication that the hysteresis theory may be the case. To this purpose, this article makes use of unit root tests with structural breaks as well as ARFIMA models to examine the unemployment persistence of different labor forces in the Greater Metropolitan Area of São Paulo.3 3 The option for São Paulo, instead of Brazil as a whole, is due to the existence of a more complete data set for this region. The period analyzed ranges from January 1985 to November 2008 and not only is the region's open unemployment rate analyzed but it is also disaggregated by gender, age, color and position within the household. Despite using a range of estimation methods, the presence of unit root cannot be rejected in general. The exceptions are the series related to Age 15-17 and over 40. But even in these cases the parameter d lies above 0.5. This is an indication that the unemployment rates in São Paulo can be defined as non stationary and the majority of the series are not mean-reverting. Hence, all disinflation policies performed by the Brazilian policymakers in the last two decades, and also technological changes, have impacted São Paulo's labor force systematically, spreading through all kinds of workers.

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the econometric methodology. Section 3 presents the data. Section 4 summarizes the results and section 5 concludes the article.

2 ECONOMETRIC METHODOLOGY

2.1. ARFIMA Models

Define Xi,t = 1, if individual i is unemployed in period t and Xi,t = 0, otherwise. Thus, if i = 1,...,N, aggregate unemployment can be defined as an aggregation of a panel data information of the kind:

As usual, suppose that Xi,t follows a Markov Process with transition probabilities given by:

where is the probability of changing from regime s to regime k in period t, and e refers to being employed while u refers to being unemployed.4 4 Obviously, these probabilities depend on individual characteristics. But, as we are working with aggregate data, we are modeling a type of representative agent for each labor force group. Therefore, the assumption that probabilities do not depend on i makes sense. The probabilities depend on t due to aggregate shocks, such as those coming from monetary policy. Finally, if for each period the Markov Process is ergodic, then:

where is the probability of becoming unemployed plus the probability of continuing unemployed.

Applying the ARFIMA methodology to the unemployment rate is equivalent to modeling the probability above, with special interest in measuring its degree of persistence. Therefore, suppose that {ut, t = 1, 2, ..., T} is the observed unemployment time series that follows the model:

where et is a covariance stationary process and d can be any real number. If this the case, the operator (1 - L)-d can be represented by the filter:

where λ0 = 1, λj = (1/j!)(d+j-2)(d+j-3)···(d+1)(d) and, as a result,

Notice that the parameter d plays a central role in explaining the impact of past shocks on ut. In fact, if et is a white noise, equation (6) gives the impulse response functions of ut. Whilst the impulse-response coefficients for a stationary ARMA process decay geometrically, the ARFIMA process has a slower (hyperbolic) decay. Because of this feature, fractionally integrated processes can be useful in modeling time series with long memory.

In the ARFIMA framework5 5 The reader may refer to Granger and Joyeux (1980) and Hosking (1981) for a complete understanding of the fractionally integrated models. , the higher the order of integration of the series, the higher its persistence will be. In fact, if 0 < d < 0.5, the series is stationary and mean-reverting. If 0.5 < d < 1, the series is non-stationary but still mean-reverting (the effects of shocks are long-lasting). Finally, when d > 1, the series is non-stationary and non-mean-reverting (GIL-ALANA, 2001a).

In order to estimate the parameter d the Nonlinear Least Squares Method (NLS) - sometimes referred to as the Approximate Maximum Likelihood Method - is used.6 6 As the series to be examined seem to be non-stationary, the Exact Maximum Likelihood methodology is not suitable because it is seriously downward biased for values of 'd' close to 0.5 and larger than 0.5. But with the sample sizes used in this paper, the NLS estimation does not suffer from these biases and it is more suitable for our examination. The NLS estimator is based on the maximization of the following likelihood function:

where the residuals are obtained by applying the ARFIMA(p, d, q) to ut and the vectors Φ and Θ represent the p autoregressive and the q moving-average parameters, respectively.7 7 The econometric package used for the estimations is Doornik and Ooms' (2001) OxMetrics and the numerical method used to maximize the likelihood function is BFGS.

2.2. Structural Breaks

Besides examining whether the disaggregated unemployment rate series have long memory properties, we have to check whether these series have structural breaks. This is important once, as mentioned, one may conclude that a series has a long memory process when it is influenced by structural breaks.

In order to examine the order of integration of the unemployment series, we follow the same procedure applied in Gomes and Gomes da Silva (2008). We first apply unit root tests, such as ADF and KPSS. However, since Perron (1989), it is well known that ADF tests can fail to reject a false unit root due to misspecification of the deterministic trend. In fact, Perron (1989, 1997) and Zivot and Andrews (1992) extend the ADF test considering an exogenous and an endogenous break to avoid this problem. But these types of tests also have some drawbacks once they derive their critical values assuming no break(s) under the null hypothesis, which lead to a spurious rejection of the null hypothesis in the presence of a unit root with breaks (LEE; STRAZICICH, 2001).

Therefore, we decided to make use of an endogenous two-break LM unit root test proposed in Lee and Strazicich (2003). In contrast to the ADF-type tests, the properties of these LM tests are unaffected by breaks under the null. According to the LM (score) principle, a unit root test statistic can be obtained from the following regression:

where: i) is a de-trended series such that ; ii) is a vector of coefficients in the regression of Δut on ΔZt and , where Zt is defined below; iii) u1 and Z1 are the first observations of ut and Zt, respectively. iv) (where i = 1,...,k) terms are included as necessary to correct for serial correlation; v) Zt is a vector of exogenous variables defined by the data generating process. Considering two changes in level and trend, Zt is described by , where Djt = 1 for t > TBj + 1, j = 1,2, and zero otherwise, = t for t > TBj + 1, j = 1, 2, and zero otherwise, and TBj stands for the time period of the breaks. Note that the test regression (8) involves ΔZt instead of Zt so that ΔZt becomes [1,B1t,B2t,D1t,D2t], where Bjt = ΔDjt and Djt = , j = 1,2.

The unit root null hypothesis is described in equation (8) by φ = 0 and the test statistics is defined as . For the null hypothesis (Φ = 0), = t-statistic. To endogenously determine the location of the two breaks (λj = TBj/T, j = 1,2) we use the LMτ = . As in Lee and Strazicich (2003), we use critical values that correspond to the location of the breaks, (λj = TBj/T, j = 1,2)

3 DATA

The data used in the analysis are the seasonally adjusted monthly unemployment rates of different labor forces in the Greater Metropolitan Area of São Paulo. The time series are the following: i) male; ii) female; iii) white; iv) non-white; v) head of the household; vi) other members of the household; vii) workers aged 15 to 17, 18 to 24, 25 to 39 and over 40; viii) aggregate open unemployment rate. The data were obtained from SEADE (Fundação Sistema Estadual de Análise de Dados) and the sample period ranges from 1985:01 to 2008:11, giving a total of 287 observations.

Figure 1 shows the evolution of unemployment in the São Paulo Metropolitan Area. The rates of unemployment of other members of household, female and nonwhite workers8 8 As a matter of fact, nonwhite workers have usually unemployment rates higher than whites, even when qualification differences are taken into consideration. are the highest. On the other hand, male, white and head of household workers have lower rates. Figure 2 shows the rates of unemployment of different age groups of workers. It is clear that youngsters have higher unemployment rates than older workers9 9 In fact, higher unemployment rates are usually a characteristic of workers with high school level. . Hence, what the two figures suggest is that the Real Plan did not have a negative effect on employment until the end of 1995. From then on, there was an increase in unemployment, which lasted until the end of 1998. From the beginning of 1999, the period of adoption of a flexible exchange rate followed by the implementation of the inflation targeting regime, unemployment rates became instable again and, after 2003, they started to show some decrease.



Table 1 helps us to analyze unemployment behavior more carefully. It reports the unemployment mean and growth rates considering full and sub samples of the series. Looking at the full sample, unemployment amongst youngsters aged between 15 and 17 has the highest mean, followed by workers aged between 18 and 24 and other members of household. On the other hand, the head of household's unemployment rate is the lowest, which is expected once these workers have a higher opportunity cost of waiting for a better job offer when they do lose their jobs. As for workers over 40 years of age, their rate of unemployment is also low because they are very experienced, which increases their marginal product. White workers have a lower rate of unemployment than non-whites, which is a common finding even when human capital accumulation is taken into account. Finally, the unemployment rate of males is much lower than of females.

As for the sub-samples, they were divided taking into consideration the beginning of the Real Plan and the implementation of the inflation targeting system. In all cases the average unemployment rate increased from one period to another. Such behavior can be explained by technological advances, which need skills that the majority of Brazilian workers do not have, and also by economic policies aimed at controlling inflation. Comparing the period 1985:01-1994:06 (sub-sample 1) to the period 1994:07-1998:12 (sub-sample 2), the series that exhibited the highest growth rates were Age 40+ (57.92%) and Head of Household (48.66%). Comparing sub-sample 2 with sub-sample 3 there was a decrease in the growth rates in relation to the previous comparison. Age 40+ (18,50%), Age 15-17 (25.44%) and Age 18-24 (25.51%) are the ones that showed the highest growth rates. The last column on Table 1 compares the period before the implementation of the Real Plan with the period after the introduction of the inflation targeting system. The unemployment growth rate related to workers aged 40 or more (87.13%) calls our attention once it is almost twice the growth rate of open unemployment.

4 RESULTS

First of all, it is advisable to plot the sample autocorrelations and investigate them carefully. They are reported, in levels and in first differences, on Table 2. In levels, the values begin at 0.98 or 0.99 and then decay very slowly. In fact, at lag 18 all of them are still above 0.70, which is very high. There is no doubt this slow decay shown in the autocorrelations is consistent with a non-stationary process. In first differences, all of the series show some significant autocorrelations at the first lags and in the majority of the other lags. When a series, say xt, is fractionally integrated and d < 1 , the first difference operator causes overdifference of the series. In this case, we should expect that the first autocorrelations have negative values. However, we do not find this pattern, except for Age 15-17.

4.1 Conventional Unit Root Tests

As mentioned by Schwert (1989), usual unit root tests, such as ADF, may not be useful if the series contains a moving average component with coefficient close to -1. Therefore, it is important to consider such specification before performing tests for the presence of a unit root in a pure autoregressive process. Column A of Table 3 reports the MA components for all the unemployment series (and their corresponding standard errors). As one can see, there is no MA component close to -1 and, therefore, we can move forward and apply the usual unit root tests.

As a benchmark, we start by estimating ADF, PP and KPSS10 10 See Dickey and Fuller (1979), Phillips and Perron (1988) and Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt and Shin (1992). unit root tests for all series. The results are reported, respectively, in columns B, C and D of Table 3. Using a 5% level of significance, the ADF estimations cannot reject the unit root hypothesis for all the rates of unemployment and the Phillips-Perron estimations reject the unit root hypothesis for only the Age 15-17 series. Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt and Shin (1992) see a drawback to testing unit root as a null hypothesis once this null is usually accepted, unless there is strong evidence against it. As a result, the authors propose a unit root test (KPSS) in which the null hypothesis is stationarity against an alternative hypothesis of non-stationarity. The KPSS results indicate that at a level of significance of 1% or 5% there is rejection of the null for all series. Despite the fact that KPSS alternative hypothesis is unit root, this test has power against a fractional unit root (Asikainen, 2003). In this perspective, the KPSS results may be viewed as an evidence in favor of unit root or fractional integration.

However, Baillie et al. (1996) argued that when the KPSS rejects the null hypothesis and the reason is fractional integration, the PP test should reject the unit root null hypothesis, which is the case only for the series Age 15-17. Thus, following Baillie's et al. (1996) procedure we would come to the conclusion that the majority of the series tested have a unit root as there is rejection of the null in all KPSS tests and only one rejection in the PP estimations. But, as mentioned above, ADF and PP-type tests have lower power to make a distinction between unit root and near unit root processes.11 11 In fact, regarding fractionally integrated processes, Diebold and Rudebusch (1991) show that ADF tests can mistakenly lead to the conclusion that a time series is non-stationary. Even though, in this phase, we may come to the conclusion that the series analyzed seem to be I(1), there is still a chance that some confusion can be made between a long memory process and a structural break. And these are our next analysis.

4.2 UNIT ROOT TESTS WITH STRUCTURAL BREAKS

As mentioned previously, in order to examine the order of integration of the unemployment series we decided to make use of an endogenous two-break LM unit root test proposed in Lee and Strazicich (2003). Table 4 reports these results. The unit root null hypothesis is rejected for the series related to Age 15-17 (at 10%) and Age 18-24 (at 5%). These two results are different from what was found in the ADF unit root tests. However, the result for Age 15-17 is in line with the PP test. As for the estimations related to Age 18-24, there is some controversy. However, once an omitted broken trend can lead to erroneous conclusions, the unit root tests with structural breaks are more reliable.

As for the other series, we cannot reject the unit root hypothesis. This means that, so far, we would come to the conclusion that majority of rates of unemployment examined in this research have a unit root, which seems to be the reason behind the non stationarity found in both ADF and KPSS results. But we have to move one step further and analyze our data based on ARFIMA estimations.

Lastly, we notice that the break dates endogenously estimated have some pattern. In general the first break is located either in the end of the 1980s or 1990s. Indeed, in the end of 1980s the unemployment rates decreased, but with the opening of the economy they started to increase again. In addition to that, around 1997 the negative effects of Real Plan over the real variables began to take place. As for the second break, it is usually associated with Lula's election in 2002.12 12 Of course, this analysis cannot be viewed as a causality test.

4.3 ARFIMA Results

We start our analysis by checking the autocorrelations of the series in level and first-differences. However, there is a more precise way to find out whether a series is fractionally integrated or not, which is the point estimation of d, the decay rate. Then, we estimate ARFIMA (0, d, 0) models and report them in Table 5. This is a common procedure as it shows whether ARFIMA estimations without any AR or MA component generate d parameters close to a unit root. In general the value of d is close to 1 (or even larger than 1). The only exception is the series Age 15-17 and this is no surprise as it showed some sign of stationarity in the unit root tests. The null hypothesis d = 0, is rejected for all series, at 5% level. On the other hand, the null hypothesis d = 1 is rejected in four cases: Open, Age 15-17, Male and Other Members. However, only in the case related to the series Age 15-17 the estimated coefficient is lower than 1. This means that, so far, there is strong evidence in favor of persistence caused by long memory or a perfect unit root. But we have to ask whether this procedure is overestimating the parameter d due to the omission of occasional structural breaks.

In order to answer this question we have to check whether the series have structural breaks and whether these breaks influence our results. Based on the break dates selected by Lee and Strazicich's (2003) unit root test, we employ the procedure due to Granger & Hyung (2004), which is based on the residuals of the following regression: ut = β'Zt + εt, where Zt contains the deterministic terms of Lee and Strazicich's (2003) unit root test (see section 2.2). After that, we estimate an ARFIMA (0, d, 0) model for each series. As we do not use any AR component in the estimation, it is expected that the parameters d be close to or equal to 1 if there is a unit root. If the long memory is caused by the omitted structural breaks, we expect lower values of d.

Table 5 reports the results of the ARFIMA (0, d, 0) models based on the residuals related to Granger & Hyung's (2004) procedure. First of all, notice that the point estimation of d decreases for all series. Thus, it seems that the omission of occasional breaks in the previous analysis leads to overestimated coefficients. However, in all cases we still reject the null hypothesis d = 0. Indeed, in the majority of the cases the parameters d estimated are close to 1. When we test whether d = 1, this hypothesis is rejected at 5% level only for the series Age 15-17 and Age 40+. Let's analyze these two series more deeply. The lowest coefficient, d = 0.711, is the one related to the series Age 15-17, which indicates long memory. An important reminder is that the first difference operator of this series seems to over-differentiate the series (see the autocorrelation table 2) and the unit root tests also showed signs of stationarity. The second lowest coefficient was 0.796 from Age 40+, which is an unexpected result. But we can stick to it once ARFIMA models exhibit a higher power than unit root tests.

In summary, except for these two series, it seems that the slow decay of simple autocorrelations is due to a pure unit root process. But one result holds for all rates of unemployment examined: all of them are persistent.

5 FINAL REMARKS

This article examined the persistence phenomenon in the unemployment rates of different labor forces in the Greater Metropolitan Area of São Paulo by means of unit root tests with structural breaks as well as ARFIMA models. The region's open unemployment rate was analyzed as well as the series disaggregated by gender, age, color and position within the household.

The purpose was to examine whether the unemployment rates followed a perfect unit root or a long memory process. In other words, the aim was to measure the persistence of different labor force groups in the Greater São Paulo Metropolitan Area.

For the period ranging from January 1985 to November 2008, the overall results show that all the unemployment rates analyzed have clear signs of non-stationarity. To be more precise, in general, we did not reject the unit root hypothesis. The exceptions were Age 15-17 and Age 40+, which exhibit long memory (0 < d < 1). In terms of economic policy, these findings mean that all the economic decisions made by the Brazilian policymakers in the past twenty years, as well as changes in real variables, have probably affected the labor forces of São Paulo in a heterogeneous fashion, but in all cases their effects are persistent. Hence, disinflation policies are important and necessary but their negative impacts should also be measured appropriately and cared for.

REFERENCES

ARESTIS, P.; MARISCAL, I. Unit roots and structural breaks in OECD unemployment. Economic Letters, v. 65, p. 149-156, 1999.

ASIKAINEN, A. Long memory and structural breaks in Finnish and Swedish party popularity series. University of Helsinki - Department of Economics, 2003. (Discussion Papers n. 586).

BAILLIE, R. T.; CHUNG, C.; TIESLAU, M. A. Analyzing inflation by the fractionally integrated Arfima-Garch Model. Journal of Applied Econometrics, v. 11, n. 1, p. 23-40, 1996.

BAUM, C. F.; BARKOULASB, J. T.; CAGLAYANC, M. Long memory or structural breaks: can either explain nonstationary real exchange rates under the current float? Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, v. 9, n. 4, p. 359-376, 1999.

______. FRACIRF: Stata module to compute impulse response function for fractionally-integrated time-series. Boston College Dept. of Economics, 2000. (Statistical Software Component Series n. S414004).

BLANCHARD, O.; SUMMERS, L. Hysteresis and the European unemployment problem. In: Fischer, S. (Ed.). NBER Macroeconomics Annual. Cambridge: MIT Press, 1986.

CAMARERO, M.; TAMARIT, C. Hysteresis vs. natural rate of unemployment: new evidence for OECD countries. Economic Letters, v. 84, p. 413-417, 2004.

CLEMENT, J.; LANASPA, L.; MONTANÉS, A. The unemployment structure of the US States. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, v. 45, p. 848-868, 2005.

DICKEY, D. A.; FULLER, W. A. Distribution of the estimators for auto-regressive time series with a unit root. Journal of the American Statistical Association, v. 74, p. 427-431, 1979.

DIEBOLD, F. X.; RUDEBUSCH, G. D. On the power of Dickey-Fuller tests against fractional alternatives. Economics Letters, v. 35, p. 155-160, 1991.

DIEBOLD, F. X.; INOUE, A. Long memory and regime switching. Journal of Econometrics, v. 105, p. 131-159, 2001.

DOORNIK, J. A.; OOMS, M. A package for estimating, forecasting and simulating Arfima Models: Arfima package 1.01 for Ox. Nuffield College - Oxford Discussion Paper, 2001.

FRIEDMAN, M. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review, v. 58, p. 1-17, 1968.

GIL-ALANA, L. A. The persistence of unemployment in the USA and Europe in terms of fractionally ARIMA models. Applied Economics, v. 33, p. 1263-1269, 2001a.

______. Measuring unemployment persistence in terms of I(d) statistical models. Applied Economics Letters, v. 8, p. 761-763, 2001b.

______; BRIAN HENRY, S. G. Fractional integration and the dynamics of UK unemployment. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, v. 65, p. 221-239, 2003.

GOMES, F. A. R.; GOMES DA SILVA, C. . Hysteresis versus natural rate of unemployment in Brazil and Chile. Applied Economics Letters, v. 15, p. 53-56, 2008.

______. Hysteresis versus NAIRU and convergence vs divergence: the behavior of regional unemployment rates in Brazil. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, v. 49, p. 308-322, 2009.

GRANGER, C. W. J. Long memory relationships and the aggregation of dynamic models. Journal of Econometrics, v. 14, p. 227-238, 1980.

______; Joyeux, R. An introduction to long memory time series and fractional differencing. Journal of Time Series Analysis, v. 1, p. 15-29, 1980.

______.; HYUNG, N. Occasional structural breaks and long memory with an application to the S&P 500 absolute stock returns. Journal of Empirical Finance 11, p. 399-421, 2004.

HOSKING, J. R. M. Modeling persistence in hydrological time series using fractional differencing. Water Resources Research, v. 20, p. 1898-1908, 1981.

JAEGER, A.; PARKINSON, M. Some evidence on hysteresis in unemployment rates. European Economic Review, v. 38, p. 329-342, 1994.

KOUSTAS, Z.; VELOCE, W. Unemployment hysteresis in Canada: an approach based on long-memory time series models. Applied Economics, v. 28, p. 823-831, 1996.

KWIATKOWSKI, D.; PHILLIPS, P. C. B.; SCHMIDT, P.; SHIN, Y. Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root: how sure are we that economic time series are non stationary? Journal of Econometrics, v. 54, p. 159-178, 1992.

LEE, J.; STRAZICICH, M. C. Break point estimation and spurious rejections with endogenous unit root tests. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, v. 63, p. 535-558, 2001.

______. Minimum LM unit root test with two structural breaks. The Review of Economics and Statistics, v. 85, p. 1082-1089, 2003.

LIMA, E. The NAIRU, unemployment and the rate of inflation in Brazil. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA, 2000. (Working Paper 753).

MIKHAIL, O.; EBERWEIN, C. J.; HANDA, J. Testing for persistence in aggregate and sectoral Canadian unemployment. Applied Economics Letters, v. 12, p. 893-898, 2005.

______. Estimating persistence in Canadian unemployment: evidence from a Bayesian ARFIMA. Applied Economics, v. 38, p. 1809-1819, 2006.

MITCHELL, W. F. Testing for unit roots and persistence in OECD unemployment. Applied Economics, v. 25, p. 1489-1501, 1993.

NEUDORFER, P.; PICHELMANN, K.; WAGNER, M. Hysteresis, NAIRU and long-term unemployment in Austria. Empirical Economics, v. 15, p. 217-229, 1990.

PERRON, P. The great crash, the oil price shock, and the unit root hypothesis. Econometrica, v. 57, p. 1361-401, 1989.

______. Further evidence on breaking trend functions in macroeconomic variables. Journal of Econometrics, v. 80, p. 355-385, 1997.

PHELPS, E. Money-wage dynamics and labor-market equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy, v. 76, p. 678-711, 1968.

PHILLIPS, P. C. B.; Perron, P. Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression. Biometrika, v. 75, p. 335-346, 1988.

PORTUGAL, M.; MADALOZZO, R. Um modelo de NAIRU para o Brasil. Revista de Economia Política, v. 20, p. 26-47, 2000.

ROED, K. Hysteresis in unemployment. Journal of Economic Surveys, v. 11, p. 389-418, 1997.

ROMER, D. Advanced macroeconomics. 2nd. ed. New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2001.

SCHWERT, G. Tests for unit roots: a Monte Carlo investigation. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, v. 7, n.2, p. 147-159, 1989.

SONG, F. M.; WU, Y. Hysteresis in unemployment: Evidence from OECD countries. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, v. 38, p. 181-192, 1998.

TOLVI, J. Unemployment persistence of different labor force groups in Finland. Applied Economics Letters, v. 10, p. 455-458, 2003.

ZIVOT, E.; ANDREWS, D. W. K. Further evidence on the great crash, the oil-price shock and the unit root hypothesis. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, v. 10, p. 251-270, 1992.

(Recebido em outubro de 2007. Aceito para publicação em abril de 2009).

  • ARESTIS, P.; MARISCAL, I. Unit roots and structural breaks in OECD unemployment. Economic Letters, v. 65, p. 149-156, 1999.
  • ASIKAINEN, A. Long memory and structural breaks in Finnish and Swedish party popularity series University of Helsinki - Department of Economics, 2003. (Discussion Papers n. 586).
  • BAILLIE, R. T.; CHUNG, C.; TIESLAU, M. A. Analyzing inflation by the fractionally integrated Arfima-Garch Model. Journal of Applied Econometrics, v. 11, n. 1, p. 23-40, 1996.
  • BAUM, C. F.; BARKOULASB, J. T.; CAGLAYANC, M. Long memory or structural breaks: can either explain nonstationary real exchange rates under the current float? Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money, v. 9, n. 4, p. 359-376, 1999.
  • ______. FRACIRF: Stata module to compute impulse response function for fractionally-integrated time-series. Boston College Dept. of Economics, 2000. (Statistical Software Component Series n. S414004).
  • BLANCHARD, O.; SUMMERS, L. Hysteresis and the European unemployment problem. In: Fischer, S. (Ed.). NBER Macroeconomics Annual Cambridge: MIT Press, 1986.
  • CAMARERO, M.; TAMARIT, C. Hysteresis vs. natural rate of unemployment: new evidence for OECD countries. Economic Letters, v. 84, p. 413-417, 2004.
  • CLEMENT, J.; LANASPA, L.; MONTANÉS, A. The unemployment structure of the US States. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, v. 45, p. 848-868, 2005.
  • DICKEY, D. A.; FULLER, W. A. Distribution of the estimators for auto-regressive time series with a unit root. Journal of the American Statistical Association, v. 74, p. 427-431, 1979.
  • DIEBOLD, F. X.; RUDEBUSCH, G. D. On the power of Dickey-Fuller tests against fractional alternatives. Economics Letters, v. 35, p. 155-160, 1991.
  • DIEBOLD, F. X.; INOUE, A. Long memory and regime switching. Journal of Econometrics, v. 105, p. 131-159, 2001.
  • DOORNIK, J. A.; OOMS, M. A package for estimating, forecasting and simulating Arfima Models: Arfima package 1.01 for Ox. Nuffield College - Oxford Discussion Paper, 2001.
  • FRIEDMAN, M. The role of monetary policy. American Economic Review, v. 58, p. 1-17, 1968.
  • GIL-ALANA, L. A. The persistence of unemployment in the USA and Europe in terms of fractionally ARIMA models. Applied Economics, v. 33, p. 1263-1269, 2001a.
  • ______. Measuring unemployment persistence in terms of I(d) statistical models. Applied Economics Letters, v. 8, p. 761-763, 2001b.
  • ______; BRIAN HENRY, S. G. Fractional integration and the dynamics of UK unemployment. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, v. 65, p. 221-239, 2003.
  • GOMES, F. A. R.; GOMES DA SILVA, C. . Hysteresis versus natural rate of unemployment in Brazil and Chile. Applied Economics Letters, v. 15, p. 53-56, 2008.
  • ______. Hysteresis versus NAIRU and convergence vs divergence: the behavior of regional unemployment rates in Brazil. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, v. 49, p. 308-322, 2009.
  • GRANGER, C. W. J. Long memory relationships and the aggregation of dynamic models. Journal of Econometrics, v. 14, p. 227-238, 1980.
  • ______; Joyeux, R. An introduction to long memory time series and fractional differencing. Journal of Time Series Analysis, v. 1, p. 15-29, 1980.
  • ______.; HYUNG, N. Occasional structural breaks and long memory with an application to the S&P 500 absolute stock returns. Journal of Empirical Finance 11, p. 399-421, 2004.
  • HOSKING, J. R. M. Modeling persistence in hydrological time series using fractional differencing. Water Resources Research, v. 20, p. 1898-1908, 1981.
  • JAEGER, A.; PARKINSON, M. Some evidence on hysteresis in unemployment rates. European Economic Review, v. 38, p. 329-342, 1994.
  • KOUSTAS, Z.; VELOCE, W. Unemployment hysteresis in Canada: an approach based on long-memory time series models. Applied Economics, v. 28, p. 823-831, 1996.
  • KWIATKOWSKI, D.; PHILLIPS, P. C. B.; SCHMIDT, P.; SHIN, Y. Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root: how sure are we that economic time series are non stationary? Journal of Econometrics, v. 54, p. 159-178, 1992.
  • LEE, J.; STRAZICICH, M. C. Break point estimation and spurious rejections with endogenous unit root tests. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, v. 63, p. 535-558, 2001.
  • ______. Minimum LM unit root test with two structural breaks. The Review of Economics and Statistics, v. 85, p. 1082-1089, 2003.
  • LIMA, E. The NAIRU, unemployment and the rate of inflation in Brazil Rio de Janeiro: IPEA, 2000. (Working Paper 753).
  • MIKHAIL, O.; EBERWEIN, C. J.; HANDA, J. Testing for persistence in aggregate and sectoral Canadian unemployment. Applied Economics Letters, v. 12, p. 893-898, 2005.
  • ______. Estimating persistence in Canadian unemployment: evidence from a Bayesian ARFIMA. Applied Economics, v. 38, p. 1809-1819, 2006.
  • MITCHELL, W. F. Testing for unit roots and persistence in OECD unemployment. Applied Economics, v. 25, p. 1489-1501, 1993.
  • NEUDORFER, P.; PICHELMANN, K.; WAGNER, M. Hysteresis, NAIRU and long-term unemployment in Austria. Empirical Economics, v. 15, p. 217-229, 1990.
  • PERRON, P. The great crash, the oil price shock, and the unit root hypothesis. Econometrica, v. 57, p. 1361-401, 1989.
  • ______. Further evidence on breaking trend functions in macroeconomic variables. Journal of Econometrics, v. 80, p. 355-385, 1997.
  • PHELPS, E. Money-wage dynamics and labor-market equilibrium. Journal of Political Economy, v. 76, p. 678-711, 1968.
  • PHILLIPS, P. C. B.; Perron, P. Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression. Biometrika, v. 75, p. 335-346, 1988.
  • PORTUGAL, M.; MADALOZZO, R. Um modelo de NAIRU para o Brasil. Revista de Economia Política, v. 20, p. 26-47, 2000.
  • ROED, K. Hysteresis in unemployment. Journal of Economic Surveys, v. 11, p. 389-418, 1997.
  • ROMER, D. Advanced macroeconomics 2nd. ed. New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin, 2001.
  • SCHWERT, G. Tests for unit roots: a Monte Carlo investigation. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, v. 7, n.2, p. 147-159, 1989.
  • SONG, F. M.; WU, Y. Hysteresis in unemployment: Evidence from OECD countries. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, v. 38, p. 181-192, 1998.
  • TOLVI, J. Unemployment persistence of different labor force groups in Finland. Applied Economics Letters, v. 10, p. 455-458, 2003.
  • ZIVOT, E.; ANDREWS, D. W. K. Further evidence on the great crash, the oil-price shock and the unit root hypothesis. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, v. 10, p. 251-270, 1992.
  • *
    Endereço para contato: Rua Itapeva 474, 11º andar, São Paulo - SP. E-mail:
  • **
    Endereço para contato: Rua Quatá 300, São Paulo - SP. E-mail:
  • 1
    Other sources of hysteresis are: i) deterioration of skills, i.e., unemployed workers are unable to update their skills and, consequently, have their probabilities of finding a new work reduced even when demand is recovered; ii) labor-force attachment, i.e., individuals who are unemployed for long periods may adjust their standard of living to a lower level and/or may even get used to the joblessness situation and so the labor supply decreases permanently (ROMER, 2001). See Roed (1997) for other sources of hysteresis.
  • 2
    For the Brazilian case, we are unaware of studies comparing hysteresis and NAIRU. But there are papers related to NAIRU only. For example, Portugal and Madalozzo (2000) and Lima (2000) did not confirm the NAIRU hypothesis, which might be an indication that the hysteresis theory may be the case.
  • 3
    The option for São Paulo, instead of Brazil as a whole, is due to the existence of a more complete data set for this region.
  • 4
    Obviously, these probabilities depend on individual characteristics. But, as we are working with aggregate data, we are modeling a type of representative agent for each labor force group. Therefore, the assumption that probabilities do not depend on
    i makes sense.
  • 5
    The reader may refer to Granger and Joyeux (1980) and Hosking (1981) for a complete understanding of the fractionally integrated models.
  • 6
    As the series to be examined seem to be non-stationary, the Exact Maximum Likelihood methodology is not suitable because it is seriously downward biased for values of 'd' close to 0.5 and larger than 0.5. But with the sample sizes used in this paper, the NLS estimation does not suffer from these biases and it is more suitable for our examination.
  • 7
    The econometric package used for the estimations is Doornik and Ooms' (2001) OxMetrics and the numerical method used to maximize the likelihood function is BFGS.
  • 8
    As a matter of fact, nonwhite workers have usually unemployment rates higher than whites, even when qualification differences are taken into consideration.
  • 9
    In fact, higher unemployment rates are usually a characteristic of workers with high school level.
  • 10
    See Dickey and Fuller (1979), Phillips and Perron (1988) and Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt and Shin (1992).
  • 11
    In fact, regarding fractionally integrated processes, Diebold and Rudebusch (1991) show that ADF tests can mistakenly lead to the conclusion that a time series is non-stationary.
  • 12
    Of course, this analysis cannot be viewed as a causality test.
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      04 Jan 2010
    • Date of issue
      Dec 2009

    History

    • Accepted
      Apr 2009
    • Received
      Oct 2007
    Departamento de Economia; Faculdade de Economia, Administração, Contabilidade e Atuária da Universidade de São Paulo (FEA-USP) Av. Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 908 - FEA 01 - Cid. Universitária, CEP: 05508-010 - São Paulo/SP - Brasil, Tel.: (55 11) 3091-5803/5947 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
    E-mail: estudoseconomicos@usp.br