Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Joint optimization of new production, warranty servicing strategy and secondary market supply under consumer returns

Abstract

In this paper, we consider an OEM selling new products to the market offering (i) a warranty period during which defective units are dealt with at no cost for the customer, and (ii) a full refund to customers who return products that do not meet their expectations (consumer returns). The manufacturer has different options for satisfying the warranty cases as well as for utilizing the consumer returns. Warranty cases could be dealt with by repairing the defective units, replacing them with new products, or replacing them with refurbished consumer returns. Alternatively leftover new products or consumer returns can also be sold on a secondary market. We develop a model and derive the OEMs optimal decisions with respect to these options under demand uncertainty on the primary market.

warranty returns; consumer returns; refurbished products; secondary market; warranty servicing; newsvendor approach


Joint optimization of new production, warranty servicing strategy and secondary market supply under consumer returns* * Invited paper ** Corresponding author

Marc ReimannI,** * Invited paper ** Corresponding author ; Weihua ZhangII

IInstitute of Production and Operations Management, University of Graz, Austria. E-mail: marc.reimann@uni-graz.at

IISchool of Economics and Management, Beihang University. E-mail: whjessica08@sina.com

ABSTRACT

In this paper, we consider an OEM selling new products to the market offering (i) a warranty period during which defective units are dealt with at no cost for the customer, and (ii) a full refund to customers who return products that do not meet their expectations (consumer returns). The manufacturer has different options for satisfying the warranty cases as well as for utilizing the consumer returns. Warranty cases could be dealt with by repairing the defective units, replacing them with new products, or replacing them with refurbished consumer returns. Alternatively leftover new products or consumer returns can also be sold on a secondary market. We develop a model and derive the OEMs optimal decisions with respect to these options under demand uncertainty on the primary market.

Keywords: warranty returns, consumer returns, refurbished products, secondary market, warranty servicing, newsvendor approach.

1 INTRODUCTION

In many industries companies have been experiencing increasing competitiveness for manyyears. In order to survive under such conditions firms have implemented various strategies for attracting new customers as well as keeping and satisfying existing customers. These strategies include generous warranty agreements to deal with product defects as well as money-back-guarantees (MBGs) to deal with buyer's remorse. Different car manufacturers offer warranty contracts including the availability of original spare parts for a time horizon of more than 15years (see e.g. http://www.volkswagen.de/de/servicezubehoer/VolkswagenOriginalTeile/original_teile.html). Leatherman offers a 25-year guarantee for its tools (http://www.leatherman.com/support/nawarranty). Amazon.com offers a full MBG within 30 days of purchase (http://www.amazon.com/gp/help/customer/display.html?nodeId=15015721), while IKEA targets customer satisfaction with a 100 day full refund policy (http://www.ikea.com/ms/en_SG/customer_service/return_policy/)1 1 All cited URLs have been visited on January 30, 2013. .

However, these policies increase the number of returns drastically. Recent studies find that returns constitute up to 35% of sales quantities (see e.g. [7]). Thus, companies need to carefully plan their operations associated with these warranty and consumer return schemes, including coordination with the forward production and sales processes.

Different companies use different strategies towards satisfying warranty claims. While some original equipment manufacturers (OEMs) repair all defects occurring during the warranty period, others offer replacement with new units. A third strategy is to utilize used and returned products for dealing with warranty cases (c.f. e.g. [18]). This third strategy also provides the link to consumer returns. Alternative uses of these returns depend on their condition and may include resale as quasi-new directly or refurbishing and remarketing for the secondary market as discussed in [2].

There is a huge body of research on the optimal satisfaction of warranty requirements, including the question when to repair and when to replace (see e.g. [16]). However, in this literature the origin of used units is typically completely exogenous and the potential alternative dispositions of used products are not considered. On the other hand, the research on consumer returns has focused on optimal strategies to control the volume of returns (see e.g. [22]), without consideration of the following disposition of these returns. To our best knowledge there is only one paper addressing this disposition issue for consumer returns (c.f. [1]) and there is not a single paper including warranty issues in (consumer) return disposition models.

Thus, in this paper we aim at linking the optimal satisfaction of warranty claims with the optimal disposition of consumer returns. To that end, the value of a consumer return will depend on the disposition alternative chosen which will also influence the optimal strategy for dealing with warranty cases. The latter strategy will, as is common in the warranty literature, explicitly consider the relative cost of repair and replacement. A central aspect of our formal model is the consideration of demand uncertainty for new products. This also implies uncertainty about the supply of used products. The model will be based on the well-known newsvendor model (for a review see [12]), specifically on an adaptation dealing with sales-induced returns presented in [20]. In this paper we extend this model in the following way. We consider an OEM, who has to take production quantity decisions under demand uncertainty. The products are subsequently sold according to the realized demand. A certain percentage of consumers will return the products shortly after purchase for a (full) refund. For some of the other sold units a warranty event is triggered, i.e. a product is returned by a consumer as being defective. Against the background of these consumer returns and warranty claims, the OEM has to take the following decisions.Consumer returns can be refurbished/remanufactured and sold as used products. Alternatively, these consumer returns could be utilized to satisfy warranty claims. Besides, these warranty claims could also be satisfied by repair of the defective units, or by replacement with new products. This model is then used to analyze the following main questions:

  • Under what conditions is it optimal to utilize consumer returns for dealing with warranty claims?

  • Under what conditions should defective products be repaired during the warranty period?

  • Under what conditions is it optimal to utilize consumer returns for resale on the secondary market?

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In the next section we discuss some related work on warranty, consumer returns and disposition of returned items. Our model is presented and analyzed in Section . Finally, conclusions and an outlook on possible model extensions are given in Section 4.

2 RELATED WORK

The disposition of returns is one of the central decisions in closed-loop supply chain management (c.f. [6], for a recent review of this area we refer to [23]). The main question is how to allocate the available returns to the different options available for the used products. In [10] returns can be allocated to a number of different and independent remanufacturing options. Given a multiple-period setting and exogenous, stochastic returns a stochastic, dynamic model is set up and analyzed. The model is of pure reverse nature, since the market for new products is not considered. In [13] the question whether to recycle or remanufacture returns is studied in a game-theoretic supplier-retailer model. Returns are again assumed to be exogenously given and stochastic, however remanufactured products are perfect substitutes for new products such that new production and remanufacturing have to be jointly optimized. Another recent paper in this stream of literature focuses on the trade-off between different cost and different revenues associated with the different disposition alternatives. Specifically, in [9] reselling remanufactured products and the utilization of returns to recover spare parts are characterized by different levels of uncertainty. While in practical applications one typically observes a focus on the disposition alternative with the largest profit margin, the optimal strategy presented in the paper prescribes a more balanced utilization of the different disposition alternatives. As in the papers mentioned above, returns are once again exogenously given. Conversely, in [5] returns are endogenously determined by previous sales of the new product. The disposition concerns the allocation of returns for remanufacturing and recycling/disposal, respectively. Remanufactured items are assumed to be perfect substitutes for new products. Additionally, the model captures the durability of components explicitly, however not in the context of warranty schemes, but rather as a function determining the remanufacturability of end-of-use returns. In [20] the optimal remanufacturing rate (and consequently the optimal disposal rate) is studied in a stochastic demand model where new and remanufactured products are perfect substitutes and returns are a function of previous sales. Particularly the possibility to store units for selling later was shown to have a significant impact on the optimal remanufacturing strategy. To our best knowledge there exists only one paper [1] that addresses the disposition decision of consumer returns by a retailer. Similarly as in [13], the disposition options of the retailer are to either resell returned units on a secondary market or to recycle returned units. Results show that the price of new products increases (and correspondingly stocking levels fall) when an MBG with resale on a secondary market is introduced. This is due to the cost associated with the MBG. However, given the discounted price of products on the secondary market, total sales volumes increase and consumers previously unserved now purchase the used products. However, none of the above mentioned papers considers the allocation of returns towards the satisfaction of warranty claims.

A detailed taxonomy for warranty policies and a comprehensive review of a variety of mathematical models of warranty with respect to consumer, manufacturer and public policy decision maker perspectives can be found in [3] and [15]. A more recent review of literature with the respect of warranty policies, warranty cost analysis, warranty and engineering, warranty and marketing, warranty and logistics and warranty management can be found in [16].

There is a long list of papers dealing with the optimal servicing of warranty contracts. Thereby the focus is typically on some trade-offs between repair and replacement of defective units. One stream of this literature highlights the associated temporal aspect. In simplified terms, the optimal strategy splits the warranty period into two phases. In the first phase, it prescribes to replace defective units while closer to the end of the warranty period repair is the preferred option (see e.g. [19]). The possibility to utilize used and repaired units for replacement was studied in [18]. Specifically, for each warranty claim, the decision is to replace with either a new or a repaired unit, and whether to discard or repair the defective unit for later use as a warranty replacement. The objective was to find the optimal cut-off value between the replacement with new items and the replacement with repaired items as well as the cut-off age determining whether a new item should be repaired and added to the collection of repaired item, so that the minimal expected warranty cost per unit sold could be obtained.

In a second stream of literature the focus is on the influence of repair cost on the optimal warranty servicing decision. In [17] an optimal repair cost limit was derived, which determined whether a repair policy or a replacement policy with a new item should be adopted to minimize expected warranty cost per unit sold. In a further extension, the number of repairs is explicitly modelled (see e.g. [11] or [25]). In some special cases the optimal policy is of the simple form to always repair when repair costs are low, and to repair each unit once and replace it upon each subsequent defect when repair costs are high. However, in general the optimal policy depends on the different problem characteristics in a more complex way and can not be expressed in such simple terms.

Refund policies are seldom included in warranty models. In [14] a policy of reducing consumer dissatisfaction was dealt with. Specifically, the model captured the possibility of a money-back guarantee or a renewable free-replacement warranty for a customer experiencing a failure early in the warranty period. However, the further disposition of these failed and repaired items was not considered there.

Contrary to that most of the literature on consumer returns has focused on the optimal refund policy. One main question deals with the extent of the refund to be offered to consumers. While a full refund can be seen as a signal of the OEMs confidence with product quality and maystimulate sales, it also invites opportunistic behavior by consumers. In [4] the influence of factors such as the salvage value of products or the potential mismatch between product characteristics and consumer preferences is analyzed. Optimal strategies to control sales volumes and return quantities are suggested in [21] and [22]. Besides pricing and refund decisions, the information of consumers concerning product characteristics is highlighted as an important decision variable. The former paper shows that due to cost effects the optimal information strategy will never eliminate returns completely. The second paper focuses on competition between different manufacturers. An unexpected result from this study is that under competition the optimal refund can be lower than in a monopoly setting. Overall, these results suggest that firms need to develop efficient strategies for handling their returns. Refund policy, reverse logistics network and marketing efforts to improve the match between the product properties and customer needs were jointly addressed in a single-period model in [24]. In [8] the effects of false failure returns (products without any defect) are studied in a game-theoretic model. The negative impact of such returns on the manufacturer's profitability are quantified and a contract incentivizing the retailer to reduce false failure returns is proposed. None of these papers considers the furtherdisposition of returns.

3 THE MODEL

We consider an OEM that serves a primary market with new products. Market demand D1 is uncertain, but we assume that the OEM knows the probability density function (PDF) and cumulative distribution function (CDF) fD1(·) and FD1(·), respectively. The sales price on the market for new products is p1 and the production cost is c1. For a given supply quantity q1, the OEM will incur expected sales SD1(q1) and an expected inventory of leftover goods ID1(q1). Clearly, SD1(q1)+ID1(q1) = q1.

The OEM offers a money-back guarantee for products returned shortly after the purchase (e.g. up to 4 weeks after purchase). A certain percentage of the customers r > 0 may make use of this option such that the expected consumer returns are r S(q1). For these returns a full refund is given. The OEM can quality-check and refurbish these products. The refurbishing cost is c2.

The OEM also offers a warranty scheme under which consumers can return failed or broken products over a longer time period (e.g. up to 2 years). This happens with a probability w > 0, such that the expected number of warranty returns is w S(q1). The OEM can decide to repair those units at a per-unit cost of c4. Alternatively, the OEM could use (part of) its leftover new products ID1(q1) or (part of) its refurbished products for dealing with those warranty claims. Failed or broken products that are replaced in such a way have to be recycled and yield a per-unit salvage value v.

Finally, a secondary market exists where leftover new products or refurbished products can be sold. Contrary to the primary market we assume that the secondary market clears at the price p2, i.e. all the supply can be sold. Moreover, the primary and the secondary market are completely separated and serve disjoint segments of customers.

Let us briefly discuss the relationship between the different prices and costs defined above. Clearly we need p1 > c1 to operate on the primary market at all. We also assume c1 > c4, i.e. new production is more expensive than repair, since otherwise we would never repair. Further, we need c1 > p2 since otherwise all new products not sold to the primary market could be profitably sold on the secondary market and new production would be unbounded.Next, we need c4 > c2 since otherwise we would never use any refurbished unit towards satisfaction of warranty claims. Additionally, we assume that p2 - c2 > v which implies that selling to the secondary market is always preferred over recycling. Summarizing, we get p1 > c1 > {c4,p2} > {c2,v}. The relationship between the repair cost c4 and the sales price on the secondary market p2 is less clear, and below we will see that this relationship is one of the main drivers of the optimal strategy. Finally, c1 > c4+v as otherwise it would be profitable to produce new units just for dealing with warranty claims.

To finish the description of the model notation let us define the decision variables. Let the number of refurbished units used for sale on the secondary market be q2. The number of leftover, new units used for sale on the secondary market is denoted by q6. Analogously, the number of refurbished (or leftover, new) units utilized towards satisfaction of warranty claims are given by q3 (q5). Finally, the number of broken or failed products that are repaired under the warranty scheme are given by q4.

By assuming risk-neutrality of the OEM we can define the objective of maximizing expected profit as

Further, given the model description above any feasible solution has to satisfy the following three constraints (besides the trivial non-negativity constraints of the decision variables):

Let us now consider constraints (3) and (4). Given our assumptions about the cost structure, particularly the relationship p2 > c2 > 0, it is reasonable that it can never be optimal not to use all of the consumer returns since we can always increase q2 for a certain gain of p2 - c2 > 0. The same conclusion can be drawn concerning the leftover, new products since we can always make a certain additional per-unit profit of p2 by increasing q6. Thus, in an optimal solution both constraints will be satisfied with equality and we can reduce the number of explicit decision variables by expressing q2 and q6 as

q2 = r SD1(q1) - q3,

and

q6 = ID1(q1) - q5,

respectively. Then we can re-write the objective of maximizing expected profits π as

under the constraints

3.1 Analytical results on the structural properties of the optimal strategy

It is easy to verify that the objective function is jointly concave and the constraints are convex in the decision variables. Thus, we can apply the KKT conditions to characterize an optimal solution.

Let λw and λr denote the shadow prices of constraints (6) and (7), respectively. Let λi denote the shadow price of the non-negativity constraint of decision variable qi.

The optimal level of new production q1 is given by

From the FOCs of the remaining three decision variables we get

The following proposition and its corollary characterize the main result by providing insights into the OEMs strategy towards satisfaction of warranty claims, as well the disposition of consumer returns.

Proposition 1. The OEMs optimal strategy is given by one of the following five scenarios:

I Repair only for warranty claims, secondary market is served

λ3 = λ5 > 0, λ4 = 0 ⇒ λr = 0, λw = c4 = p2- v3, i.e. c4 < p2 - v

q4 = w SD1(q1), 0 = q3 + q5 < q1 -(1 - r) SD1(q1)

II Repair and replacement for warranty claims, secondary market may or may not be served

λ3 = λ4 = λ5 = 0, λr = 0 ⇒ λw = c4 = p2 - v, i.e. c4 = p2 - v

q3 + q4 + q5 = w SD1(q1), q3 + q5< q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1)

III Repair and replacement for warranty claims, secondary market is not served

λ3 = λ4 = λ5 = 0, λr > 0 ⇒ λw = c4 = p2 - v + λr, i.e. c4 > p2 - v

q3 + q4 + q5 = w SD1(q1), q3 + q5 = q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1)

w > r

IV Replacement only for warranty claims, secondary market is not served

λ3 = λ5 = 0, λ4 > 0, λr > 0 ⇒ λw = c4 - λ4 = p2 - v + λr, i.e. c4 > p2 - v

q3 + q5 = w SD1(q1), q3 + q5 = q1 -(1 - r) SD1(q1)

w > r

V Replacement only for warranty claims, secondary market is served

λ3 = λ5 = 0, λ4 > 0, λr = 0 ⇒ λw = c4 - λ4 = p2 - v, i.e. c4 > p2 -v

q3 + q5 = w SD1(q1), q3 + q5 < q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1)

Corollary 1. Depending on the cost of repair c4 and the relationship between consumer returns r and warranty claims w the OEM will

a) choose repair as the exclusive option for dealing with defective units under the warranty scheme if and only if c4 < p2 - v,

b) decide not to repair any defective units, but rather replace all returns under the warranty scheme whenever c4> p2 - v and r > w - , and

c) decide not to serve the secondary market whenever c4> p2 - v and r < w - , which implies that r < w.

All proofs are given in the appendixappendix.b) Obviously, the strategy of replacement only for warranty claims is possible in Scenarios II, III, IV and V. According to Scenario II, we obtain c4 = p2 - v and w SD1(q1) < q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1). From Scenarios III and IV, we know c4 > p2 - v and w SD1(q1) = q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1). Finally, we have c4 > p2 - v and w SD1(q1) < q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1) based on Scenario V. Hence, we learn that the OEM would like to replace all defective unites rather than repair them under the conditions c4> p2 - v and w SD1(q1) < q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1), i.e. c4> p2 - v and r > w - .. Part a) of Corollary 1 implies that all available leftover new products and all consumer returns are directed to the secondary market, since the gain of sending a unit to the secondary market p2 - v exceeds the gain from not having to repair a unit c4. In the opposite case, i.e. when c4 > (p2 - v) it is clear that all available units should be earmarked for satisfying warranty claims to avoid costly repair as much as possible. If the number of warranty claims is large it may not be possible to replace all defective units and some repair may be necessary. In such a situation part c) of Corollary 1 occurs and the secondary market is not served at all. Finally, when the amount of consumer returns is rather high such that it is possible to completely avoid repair, case b) shown in Corollary 1 arises. Note that in this setting the OEM is indifferent to the actual allocation of new (q5) and refurbished (q3) units towards satisfaction of warranty claims.

Proposition 2 further characterizes the OEMs optimal strategy by describing the impact of the consumer return rate r and warranty cost c4 on the optimal new production quantity q1.

Proposition 2. The optimal new production quantity q 1 of the OEM

a) is always decreasing when the rate of consumer returns r increases,

b) is non-decreasing whenever c4 > p2 - v and r < , and is non-increasing with increasing repair cost c4otherwise.

Part a) of Proposition 2 is rather straightforward. The MBG associated with the consumer returns increases the cost of new products and consequently the OEM is induced to reduce its optimal supply q1. Note that this is in line with the findings from [1].

Concerning part b) of Proposition 2, a similar argument holds for repair cost c4 when c4< p2 - v (in which case repair is the only warranty servicing option). When c4 > p2 - v two opposing effects occur. By increasing q1 the OEM induces an increase in the number of warranty cases to deal with, but also increases the number of consumer returns which can be used for dealing with warranty cases. Reducing q1 will obviously reduce both the warranty claims and the consumer returns. The stronger of these two effects will determine whether the OEM expands or contracts its new production q1. According to Proposition 2 part b) the consumer return effect is stronger and the OEM increases q1 whenever r < . In the opposite case, the reduction in warranty claims is more important and the OEM will reduce q1.

Finally, let us analyze the relationship between Scenarios III, IV and V, which can occur when c4 > p2 - v. For explicitly deriving the preconditions for these three scenarios to occur we need to specify the expected sales function SD1(q1). To keep the analysis simple let us assume that D1 ~ U[0,b1], i.e. demand for new products is uniformly distributed with minimum and maximum values of 0 and b1, respectively. Then the expected sales are given by SD1(q1) = q1- . Using this we can rewrite the constraints (6) and (7) as functions of r. The results are given in the following proposition.

Proposition 3. Let NV = (p1 - p2) - w (p2 - v) - (c1 - p2), DV = (p1 - p2) - w (p2 - v) and ZV = p1 - p2 + c2. Let NIII = (p1 - p2) - w c4 - (c1 - p2), DIII = (p1 - p2) - w c4 - [c4 - (p2 - v)] and ZIII = p1 - c4 + c2 - v. The existence of Scenarios III, IV and V is given by the following conditions:

a) Scenario V exists whenever r1 < r < r2, where

b) Scenario III exists whenever r < r1or r > r2, where

Note, that the existence of Scenario V is completely independent of repair cost c4 (as long as c4 > p2 - v) while the existence of Scenario III depends on c4. Furthermore, the region defined by Scenario III (and implicitly Scenario IV) may be disjoint over the return rate r. This result implies that under certain parameter constellations the secondary market will be served for intermediate values of r, but will not be served for small or large values of r. Here a similar effect as described above for Proposition 2 part b) is at work. When r is small, all the consumer returns are used for replacing repair as a warranty servicing strategy. As r increases, the OEM reduces q1 such that less warranty claims arise. On the other hand the increase in r to some extent counterbalances the reduction in q1 such that the number of consumer returns may even rise. This opens the opportunity for the OEM to serve the secondary market. Finally, when r gets too high, the decrease in q1 is no longer balanced by r and the number of consumer returns falls. As a consequence the OEM once again seizes to serve the secondary market to use all the returns for servicing warranty.

Unfortunately the expressions for r1,2 are rather complex and their further analysis does notprovide easily comprehensible findings in terms of the thresholds. Thus, below we will use some numerical examples to provide more insights into the effect of variations in the problem characteristics on the optimal strategy.

3.2 Numerical results on the structural properties of the optimal strategy

As shown through the analytical results, the return rate r, and the repair cost c4 are two of the main drivers of the optimal strategy. Hence, below we will provide numerical results as a function of these two problem characteristics. Figure 1 shows the overall optimal strategy as a function of repair cost c4 and consumer returns r for a level of warranty claims w = 0.2 and different values of new production cost c1.







First of all, we observe the trivial effect that with increasing cost c1 the OEM will accept less consumer returns from Figure 1. Further, the numerical results reconfirm that regardless of the consumer return rate r and the new production cost c1 repair is the only option for dealing with warranty claims when c4 < p2 - v (Scenario I).

More interestingly, for c4 > p2 - v the figure nicely visualizes the change in the OEMs strategy as c1 changes. When c1 is rather small (Figure 1a), the production quantity q1 and corresponding sales SD1(q1) are large enough to be able to deal with all warranty claims through replacement and to use the remaining returns for serving the secondary market. As c1 increases, the resulting contraction of new production q1 induces the OEM to give up the secondary market when r is small. Rather all the returns are used to replace as many warranty claims as possible (Scenarios III and IV in Figure 1b).

As c1 increases further, the OEMs strategy is characterized by the effect described when discussing Proposition 3, see Figure 1c. Additionally, Figure 2 provides information about all the decision variables as a function of r for a level of repair cost c4 = 65, which is slightly above the threshold p2 - v.









For small and large r the OEM does not serve the secondary market (Scenarios III and IV), while for intermediate values of r the OEM not only serves the secondary market but also uses replacement as the sole warranty servicing strategy (Strategy V). These effects are nicely highlighted in Figures 2b and c.

While the effect concerning the secondary market has been discussed above in the context of Proposition 3, the optimal warranty servicing strategy deserves some focus here. When looking at Figure 2c we observe that for small r repair and replacement form the optimal approach towards warranty claims. With increasing r repair is reduced and eventually completely stopped. This behavior is induced by the increase in available consumer returns as shown in Figure 2a. While q1, and consequently the number of warranty claims w SD1(q1) continuously fall with increasing r, the number of consumer returns r SD1(q1) first increases and then falls. This latter fall in the number of consumer returns also triggers another strategy switch, where the OEM eventually starts to use repair as part of its warranty servicing strategy again. In this case the amount of available returns is no longer sufficient to cover all warranty claims.

Returning to Figures 1d, e and f, we observe that with a further increase of c1 the OEM seizes to serve the secondary market at all (when c4 > p2 - v). Ultimately, the OEM will not even be able to satisfy all warranty claims by replacement and will always have to repair at least a fraction of the warranty claims (Figure 1f).

To conclude our results concerning the structural properties of the OEMs optimal strategy, let us revisit and visualize the result from Proposition 2. Figure 3 shows the optimal new production quantity q1 as a function of repair cost c4 for different levels of r.


Clearly, q1 falls as r increases as prescribed by Proposition 2 and also shown in Figure 2a. Concerning the relationship between q1 and c4 we see huge differences when comparing the various consumer return rates r. From the left part of the figure we observe that for very small r the OEM first reduces its output of new products. As soon as c4 > p2 - v the OEM expands its production and finally produces more new products than if repair costs were zero. Therefore, the consumer return effect described above in the discussion of Proposition 2 is dominant. For intermediate values of r (r = 0.07, r = 0.075, r = 0.17 and r = 0.175, note that these values correspond to the switching points from Strategies III/IV to Strategy V and back, see Figure 1c) new production essentially smoothes out at a lower level when c4 > p2 - v. In these cases, reducing the warranty claims is more important and q1 does not increase. Finally, from the right part of Figure 3 we observe that when r is high another bifurcation occurs. For r = 0.19 the consumer return effect takes over again. New production first falls, then rises and finally stabilizes, albeit at a level smaller than when c4 = 0. Finally, when r = 0.195, q1 falls over the entire range of c4 implying that once again reducing warranty claims is the OEMs priority.

In closing this section let us briefly comment on the performance implications of changes in r and c4. It is quite clear that increases in the rate of consumer returns or the repair cost will always have detrimental effects on expected profits. This is exemplarily shown in Figure 2d.

4 CONCLUSION

In this paper we analyzed an OEMs optimal strategy for dealing with consumer returns under the requirement of servicing warranty. Using our model we characterized the different warranty servicing strategies, repair only, replacement only and the mixed approach. Further, we have shown under which conditions the OEM serves the secondary market. We find that the allocation of refurbished consumer returns is crucial but exhibits a non-trivial relationship between the secondary market and warranty servicing. Most interestingly and counter-intuitively our main findings show that when repair cost is within an intermediate range, the OEM may switch from a replacement only warranty servicing strategy to a mixed strategy including repair when the rate of consumer returns increases. As mentioned, this is due to a contraction in the new production quantity.

The link between warranty and consumer returns gives rise to a couple of interesting extensions of our model. One such extension deals with the OEMs optimal quality/durability choice for its new products. When increased R & D effort can help reducing warranty claims, while increased marketing (consumer information) effort can help reduce consumer returns, the question is how to optimally allocate the effort to these two strategies. Further, it is interesting to understand the conditions when either of the strategies is preferred.

Another important extension of the model concerns the temporal aspect related to consumer returns and warranty claims. As mentioned, consumer returns occur within up to 90 days after purchase, while warranties can extend over years. In [7] the necessity of fast reverse processes has been emphasized to account for the rapid reduction in value of returned, used products. In terms of our model this captures the trade-off between selling refurbished products on the secondary market and keeping them in stock for using them towards satisfying warranty claims at a later point in time. Besides inventory cost, the reduced value of such refurbished products will clearly influence the optimal strategy concerning the use of refurbished products towards warranty.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

This work has been supported by funds of the Oesterreichische Nationalbank (Anniversary Fund, project number: 14974). The authors gratefully acknowledge this financial support. The authors would like to thank Mike Galbreth and Gernot Lechner for valuable comments on the setup and framing of the model. Thanks also go to Gerald Senarclens de Grancy for help with the Figures.

Received November 6, 2013

Accepted November 9, 2013

Proof of Proposition 1. We first observe from (10) and (11) that λ3 = λ5. Next, one of the three decision variables q3, q4, q5 has to be strictly positive (unless q1 = 0) to satisfy constraint (6), i.e. at least one λi = 0, i ∈ {3,4,5}. Together with our assumptions p2 - v > 0 and c4 > 0 this implies that λw > 0 in any feasible solution. Further, λr λ3λ5 can't be positive according to the constraint (7) since the conditions q3 = 0, q5 = 0 and q3 + q5 = q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1) can not hold at the same time. Note that q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1) is positive except for q1 = 0. Finally, we are left with five scenarios in total satisfying these conditions and by combining the KKT conditions, we readily obtain Proposition 1.

Proof of Corollary 1. a) Plainly, in Scenario I repair is the only option for warranty claims. That is to say, if and only if c4 < p2 - v, the OEM will choose repair as the exclusive option for dealing with defective units under the warranty scheme.

c) Clearly, Scenarios II, III and IV are related to the situation that the secondary market is not served. For these three scenarios we respectively obtain the conditions c4 = p2 - v and w SD1(q1) > q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1), the conditions c4 > p2 - v and w SD1(q1) > q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1) and the conditions c4 > p2 - v and w SD1(q1) = q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1). In sum, we know whenever c4> p2 - v and w SD1(q1) > q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1), i.e. c4> p2 - v and r < w - , hold, the OEM decides not to serve the secondary market. □

Proof of Proposition 2. We can write [1 - FD1(q1)] in Scenarios I, II, III, IV and V, respectively as: , , , , .

a) In Scenarios I, II and V, the coefficient of r is given by -(p1 - p2) - c2 < 0. In Scenario III the coefficient of r is -(p1 - p2) - c2 + (c4 - p2 + v) = -p1 - c2 + c4 + v < - p1 - c2 + c1 < 0. And in Scenario IV the coefficient of r is -(p1 - p2) - c2 + (c4 - λ4 - p2 + v) < - p1 - c2 + c4 - λ4 + v = - p1 - c2 + λw + v < - p1 - c2 + c4 + v < - p1 - c2 + c1 < 0. So denominators of 1 - FD1(q1) in all five scenarios decrease when r increases. It means that for all five scenarios 1 - FD1(q1) increases when r increases. As a result, q1 is always decreasing when the rate of consumer returns r increases.

b) Similarly, it is clear to observe that in Scenarios I and II q1 decreases with increasing repair cost c4 and in Scenario V q1 is not affected by the repair cost c4. Let us consider the derivative of FD1(q1) with respect to c4 for Scenarios III and IV. The derivative of FD1(q1) with respect to c4 in Scenarios III and IV are

and

respectively. Obviously, when r < , FD1(q1) is positive in Scenarios III and IV. That is to say, in Scenarios III and IV q1 increases with increasing repair cost c4 if r < and otherwise decreases. In sum, q1 is non-decreasing whenever c4 > p2 - v and r < , and is non-increasing with increasing repair cost c4 otherwise. □

Proof of Proposition 3. When D1 ~ U[0, b1], we know FD1(q1) = and SD1(q1) = q1- .

a) In Scenario V we have λw = p2 - v and λr = 0. So we obtain

Then we can rewrite w SD1(q1) < q1 – (1 – r) SD1(q1) as (w + 1 – r)(2 – ) < 2, i.e. ZV r2 – [2DV – NV – (1 – w) ZV] r + w (2DV – NV) – NV < 0. Hence, the existence condition of Scenario V follows.

b) In Scenario III we have λw = c4 and λr = c4 – (p2 – v). So we obtain

Then we can rewrite w SD1(q1) > q1 – (1 – r) SD1 (q1) as (w + 1 – r)(2 – ) > 2, i.e. ZI I I r2 – [2DI I I – NI I I – (1 – w) ZI I I ] r + w (2DI I I – NI I I) – NI I I> 0. Hence, the existence condition of Scenario III follows. □

  • [1] AKCAY Y, BOYACI T & ZHANG D. 2013. Selling with money-back guarantees: The impact on prices, quantities, and retail profitability. Production & Operations Management, forthcoming.
  • [2] BLACKBURN JD, GUIDE JR VDR, SOUZA GC & VAN WASSENHOVE LN. 2004. Reverse supply chains for commercial returns. California Management Review, 46: 622.
  • [3] BLISCHKE WR & MURTHY DNP. 1992. Product warranty management I: A taxonomy for warranty policies. European Journal of Operational Research, 62: 127148.
  • [4] DAVIS S, GERSTNER E & HAGERTY M. 1995. Money back guarantees in retailing: Matching products to consumer tastes. Journal of Retailing, 71: 722.
  • [5] GEYER R, VAN WASSENHOVE LN & ATASU A. 2007. The economics of remanufacturing under limited component durability and finite product life cycles. Management Science, 53: 88100.
  • [6] GUIDE JR VDR & VAN WASSENHOVE LN. 2009. The evolution of closed-loop supply chain research. Operations Research, 57: 1018.
  • [7] GUIDE JR VDR, SOUZA GC, VAN WASSENHOVE LN & BLACKBURN JD. 2006. Time value of commercial product returns. Management Science, 52: 12001214.
  • [8] FERGUSON ME, GUIDE VDR JR. & SOUZA GC. 2006. Supply chain coordination for false failure returns. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 8: 376393.
  • [9] FERGUSON ME, FLEISCHMANNM & SOUZA GC. 2011. A profit-maximizing approach to disposition decisions for product returns. Decision Sciences, 42: 773798.
  • [10] INDERFURTH K, DE KOK AG & FLAPPER SDP. 2001. Product recovery in stochastic remanufacturing systems with multiple reuse options. European Journal of Operational Research, 133: 130152.
  • [11] ISKANDAR BP, MURTHY DNP & JACK N. 2005. A new repair-replace strategy for items sold with a two-dimensional warranty. Computers & Operations Research, 32: 669682.
  • [12] KHOUJA M. 1999. The single-period (news-vendor) problem: literature review and suggestions for future research. Omega, 27: 537553.
  • [13] LI X, LI Y & CAI X. 2011. Quantity decisions in a supply chain with early returns remanufacturing. International Journal of Production Research, 50: 21612173.
  • [14] MURTHY DNP, DJAMALUDIN I & WILSON RJ. 1995. A consumer incentive warranty policy and servicing strategy for products with uncertain quality. Quality and reliability engineering international, 11: 155163.
  • [15] MURTHY DNP & BLISCHKE WR. 1992. Product warranty management III: A review of mathematical models. European Journal of Operational Research, 63: 134.
  • [16] MURTHY DNP & DJAMALUDIN I. 2002. New product warranty: A literature review. International Journal of Production Economics, 79: 231260.
  • [17] MURTHY DNP & NGUYEN DG. 1988. An optimal repair cost limit policy for servicing warranty. Mathematical and Computer Modelling, 11: 595599.
  • [18] NGUYEN DG & MURTHY DNP. 1986. An optimal policy for servicing warranty. Journal of the Operational Research Society 37: 10811088.
  • [19] NGUYEN DG & MURTHY DNP. 1989. Optimal replace-repair strategy for servicing items sold with warranty. European Journal of Operational Research, 39: 206212.
  • [20] REIMANN M & LECHNER G. 2012. Production and Remanufacturing Strategies in a Closed Loop Supply Chain: A Two-Period Newsvendor Problem, in T.M. Choi (Ed.): Handbook of Newsvendor Problems: Models, Extensions and Applications, International Series in Operations Research and Management Science, Springer, NY, 219247.
  • [21] SHULMAN JD, COUGHLAN AT & SAVASKAN RC. 2009. Optimal restocking fees and information provision in an integrated demand-supplymodel of product returns. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 11: 577594.
  • [22] SHULMAN JD, COUGHLAN AT & SAVASKAN RC. 2011. Managing consumer returns in a competitive environment.Management Science, 57: 347362.
  • [23] SOUZA GC. 2013. Closed-loop supply chains: A critical review, and future research. Decision Sciences, forthcoming.
  • [24] YALABIK B, PETRUZZI NC & CHHAJED D. 2005. An integrated product returns model with logistics and marketing coordination. European Journal of Operational Research, 161: 162182.
  • [25] ZUO MJ, LIU B & MURTHY DNP. 2000. Replacement-repair policy for multi-state deteriorating products under warranty. European Journal of Operational Research, 123: 519530.

appendix

.

b) Obviously, the strategy of replacement only for warranty claims is possible in Scenarios II, III, IV and V. According to Scenario II, we obtain c4 = p2 - v and w SD1(q1) < q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1). From Scenarios III and IV, we know c4 > p2 - v and w SD1(q1) = q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1). Finally, we have c4 > p2 - v and w SD1(q1) < q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1) based on Scenario V. Hence, we learn that the OEM would like to replace all defective unites rather than repair them under the conditions c4> p2 - v and w SD1(q1) < q1 - (1 - r) SD1(q1), i.e. c4> p2 - v and r > w - .

  • *
    Invited paper
    **
    Corresponding author
  • 1
    All cited URLs have been visited on January 30, 2013.
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      16 Dec 2013
    • Date of issue
      Dec 2013

    History

    • Received
      06 Nov 2013
    • Accepted
      09 Nov 2013
    Sociedade Brasileira de Pesquisa Operacional Rua Mayrink Veiga, 32 - sala 601 - Centro, 20090-050 Rio de Janeiro RJ - Brasil, Tel.: +55 21 2263-0499, Fax: +55 21 2263-0501 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
    E-mail: sobrapo@sobrapo.org.br