Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

THE ELECTORAL CONNECTION IN AN OPEN-LIST PR SYSTEM: INFORMAL CONSTITUENCIES, BUDGET AMENDMENTS AND PUBLIC POLICIES IN RIO DE JANEIRO

CONEXÃO ELEITORAL EM UM SISTEMA PROPORCIONAL DE LISTA ABERTA: DISTRITOS INFORMAIS E EMENDAS AO ORÇAMENTO NO RIO DE JANEIRO

LA CONNEXION ELECTORALE DANS UN SYSTEME RPSL: LES CONSEILLERS DE LA VILLE DE RIO DE JANEIRO

Abstracts

This article aims to highlight the effects of the electoral connection on the behavior of Brazilian legislators, examining specifically the Rio de Janeiro chamber of councillors. The analysis covers the fourteen-year period from 1997 and 2010. The decisive influence of the electoral connection on the councillors’ process of decision making in relation to the financing of public policies is presented through a set of multiple regressions. The results show contrasts between the mutually excluding perspectives of comparatists and specialists in Brazil. A more diversified description of the electoral connexion in OLPR system emerge. The discoveries show that the transformation of the constituent group from several formal members into many informal groups accommodates geographical and non-geographical representations. Although focused on Brazil, this article approaches a gap in the literature about OLPR systems, which are adopted in other aspects of national elections, in places such as Peru and Colombia, and in subnational elections, as in many states from Germany.

Electoral systems; Parliamentary behavior; Electoral connection


Este artigo tem como objetivo identificar os efeitos da conexão eleitoral sobre o comportamento dos legisladores brasileiros examinando as escolhas de prioridade de políticas públicas dos vereadores cariocas no processo de alocação de recursos orçamentários. A pesquisa abrange o período de quatorze anos entre 1997 e 2010. A influência crucial da conexão eleitoral na decisão dos parlamentares é mostrada por meio de um conjunto de regressões múltiplas. Os resultados contrastam com as perspectivas mutuamente excludentes de cientistas políticos comparativistas e especialistas em Brasil. O que emerge da análise é uma realidade menos caricata e mais complexa do que aquela usualmente atribuída à conexão eleitoral no sistema proporcional de lista aberta. O distrito eleitoral multinominal formal – um município com cinquenta e dois representantes – converte-se em dezenas de distritos informais cujas fronteiras podem ser geográficas, temáticas ou ideológicas. Embora focado no Brasil, este artigo contribui para preencher uma lacuna mais ampla da literatura a respeito sistema proporcional de lista aberta, adotado por outros países em eleições nacionais, como na Colômbia e no Peru, e em eleições subnacionais, como em muitos estados federais da Alemanha.

Sistemas eleitorais; Comportamento parlamentar; Conexão eleitoral


Cet article présente les effets de la connexion électorale sur le comportement des législateurs brésiliens et plus particulièrement des députés de Rio de Janeiro, sur une période de 14 ans allant de 1997 à 2010. L’influence majeure de la connexion électorale sur la décision des députés en matière de financement des politiques publiques apparaît à travers un ensemble de régressions multiples. Les résultats contrastent avec les perspectives mutuellement excluantes des comparatistes et des spécialistes brésiliens. Une description plus diversifiée de la connexion électorale dans les systèmes RPSL émerge. Les résultats montrent que la transformation du groupe constituant de plusieurs membres officiels dans beaucoup de groupes non officiels abrite des représentations géographiques et non géographiques. Bien que centrée sur le Brésil, cette étude aborde une lacune plus vaste au niveau de la littérature sur les systèmes RPSL, qui sont adoptés dans d’autres élections nationales, comme en Colombie et au Pérou, et dans des élections sous-nationales, comme dans beaucoup d’états fédéraux allemands.

Systèmes électoraux; Comportement parlementaire; Connexion électorale


Introduction

In one sentence, the electoral connection is the mechanism linking politicians and their constituents ( Mayhew, 1974MAYHEW, D. (1974), Congress: the electoral connection. Fredericksburg. BookCrafters. ). Researchers adopting an institutionalist perspective based on the rational choice theory invariably associate the strength of the electoral connection with the incentives for legislators to cultivate a personal vote ( Mayhew, 1974MAYHEW, D. (1974), Congress: the electoral connection. Fredericksburg. BookCrafters. ; Nicolau, 2001NICOLAU, J. (2001), “A conexão eleitoral de uma família política carioca”. Revista Brasielira de Ciências Sociais , 16 (46): 180-182. Available at http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?script=sci_pdf&pi-d=S0102-69092001000200013&lng=en&nrm=iso&tlng=pt, consulted in 21 September 2010.
http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?script=s...
; Pereira and Mueller, 2003PEREIRA, C. e MUELLER, B. (2003), “Partidos fracos na arena eleitoral e partidos fortes na arena legislativa: a conexão eleitoral no Brasil”. Dados , 43 (4). Available at www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.p...
; Norris, 2004NORRIS, P. (2004), Electoral engineering: voting rules and political behavior . Massachusetts,Harvard University/Cambridge University Press. ; Gallagher, 2005GALLANGHER, M. (2005), “Conclusion”, in Michael Gallagher and Paul Mitchell, (eds.), The politics of electoral systems . Oxford, Oxford Scholars Online. Available at https://shib-idp.ucl.ac.uk/idp/profile/Shibboleth/SSO?shire=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fShibboleth.sso%2fSAML%2fPOST&target=ezp.2aHR0cDovL3BhLm94Zm9yZGpvdXJuYWxzLm9yZy8-&time=1286156244&providerId=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fshibboleth, consulted in 14 April 2009.
https://shib-idp.ucl.ac.uk/idp/profile/S...
).

No one questions the powerful influence of the electoral connection in open-list proportional representation (OLPR) systems. Surprisingly, though, it remains yet to be systematically tested. Thus so far neither comparativists ( Norris, 2004NORRIS, P. (2004), Electoral engineering: voting rules and political behavior . Massachusetts,Harvard University/Cambridge University Press. ; Shugart, 2005SHUGART, M. S. (2005), “Comparative electoral systems research: the maturation of a field and new challenges ahead”, in Michael Gallagher and Paul Mitchell (eds.), The Politics of Electoral Systems . Published to Oxford Scholars On-line. Available at https://shib-idp.ucl.ac.uk/idp/profile/Shibboleth/SSO?shire=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fShibboleth.sso%2fSAML%2fPOST&target=ezp.2aHR0cDov-L3BhLm94Zm9yZGpvdXJuYWxzLm9yZy8-&time=1286156244&providerId=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fshibboleth, consulted in 14 April 2009.
https://shib-idp.ucl.ac.uk/idp/profile/S...
) nor area specialists specifically interested in Brazilian politics have given this issue the attention it deserves ( Nicolau, 2001NICOLAU, J. (2001), “A conexão eleitoral de uma família política carioca”. Revista Brasielira de Ciências Sociais , 16 (46): 180-182. Available at http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?script=sci_pdf&pi-d=S0102-69092001000200013&lng=en&nrm=iso&tlng=pt, consulted in 21 September 2010.
http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?script=s...
; 2007)NICOLAU, J. (2007), “O sistema eleitoral de lista aberta no Brasil”, in Jairo Nicolau andTmothy Power (eds.), Instituições representativas no Brasil: balanço e reforma . Belo Horizonte, Editora da UFMG, pp. 97-122. . Despite espousing completely different perspectives, scholars in both fields fail to consider the same fundamental point: the electoral connection assumes multiple configurations in OLPR systems. 1 1 The Brazilian OLPR system adds together all the strongest incentives for legislators to cultivate a personal vote. Unlimited reelection is allowed, parties may launch a rather large numbers of candidates, candidate selection process takes place far from the central leadership and campaigns – including fund raising strategies – are run as individual enterprises. More important, regarding the ballot structure, the personal vote alone determines the place of each candidate on the party list.

For comparativists, the intrinsic territorial overlapping of multi-member constituencies strongly discourages the emergence of geographic-based representation. Instead, candidates seek electoral support in non geographic social segments ( Loewenberg and Kim, 1978LOEWENBERG, G. & KIM, C. L. (1978), “Comparing the representativeness of parliaments”. Legislative Studies Quarterly , 3 (1): 27-49. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/439678, consulted in 5 July 2010.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/439678...
; Jewell and Loewenberg, 1979JEWELL, M. E. & LOEWENBERG, G. (1979), “Editors’ introduction: toward a new model of legislative representation”. Legislative Studies Quarterly , 4 (4): 485-499. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/439402, consulted in 1 June 2010.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/439402...
; Lancaster, 1986LANCASTER, T. D. (1986), “Electoral structures and pork barrel politics”. International Political Science Review/Revue Internationalede Science Politique , 7 (1): 67-81. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1600916,consulted in 5 July 2010.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1600916...
; Carey and Shugart, 1995CAREY, J. M. & SHUGART, M. S., (1995), Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: a rank ordering of electoral formulas”. Electoral Studies , 14 (4): 417-439. Available at http://cedar.olemiss.edu/courses/pol628/careyshugart95.pdf, consulted in 11 January 2010.
http://cedar.olemiss.edu/courses/pol628/...
). Social segments, then, such as the workers of a certain category or the followers of a given religion, are what make up the cons- tituencies of legislators. Therefore, the electoral connection involves pursuing issue-based policies rather than pleasing specific geographic areas.

In contrast, for scholars working on Brazil, candidates confine their search for votes within clear, yet informal, geographic boundaries. Therefore, it is a few geographic areas that make up a legislator’s actual constituency rather than the scattered members of a particular social segment. The distributive literature on the U.S. House of Representatives is by far the main reference from which they build up their studies ( Mainwaring, 1991MAINWARING, S. (1991), “Politicians, parties, and electoral systems: Brazil in comparative perspective”. Comparative Politics , 24 (1): 21-43. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/422200, consulted in 8 September 2010.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/422200...
; Lemos, 2001LEMOS, L. B. S. (2001), “O congresso brasileiro e a distribuição de benefícios sociais no período 1988-1994: uma análise distributivista”. Dados , 44 (3): 561-605. ; Samuels, 2002SAMUELS, D. J. (2002), “Pork barreling is not credit claiming or advertising: campaign finance and the sources of the personal vote in Brazil”. The Journal of Politics , 64 (3): 845-863. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1520116, consulted in 14 April 2009.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1520116...
; AmorimNeto and Santos, 2002; Pereira and Mueller, 2003PEREIRA, C. e MUELLER, B. (2003), “Partidos fracos na arena eleitoral e partidos fortes na arena legislativa: a conexão eleitoral no Brasil”. Dados , 43 (4). Available at www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.p...
; Pereira and Mueller, 2004PEREIRA, C. & MUELLER, B. (2004), “The cost of governing: strategic behavior of the president and legislators in Brazil’s budgetary process”. Comparative Political Studies , 37 (781). Available at http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/37/7/781, consulted in 2 June 2009.
http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstr...
; Pereira and Rennó, 2007PEREIRA, C. e RENNÓ, L. (2007),“O que é que o reeleito tem? O retorno: o esboço de uma teoria da reeleição no Brasil”. Revista de Economia Política , 27 (4): 664-683. Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rep/v27n4/a10v27n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rep/v27n4/a10v2...
). Hence, it is by no means unexpected to see them applying the concept of geographic-based representation – the core of the distributive perspective on the American first-pass-the-post system – to understand the behaviour of legislators in Brazil ( Samuels, 2002SAMUELS, D. J. (2002), “Pork barreling is not credit claiming or advertising: campaign finance and the sources of the personal vote in Brazil”. The Journal of Politics , 64 (3): 845-863. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1520116, consulted in 14 April 2009.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1520116...
; Pereira and Mueller, 2004PEREIRA, C. & MUELLER, B. (2004), “The cost of governing: strategic behavior of the president and legislators in Brazil’s budgetary process”. Comparative Political Studies , 37 (781). Available at http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/37/7/781, consulted in 2 June 2009.
http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstr...
; Pereira and Rennó 2007PEREIRA, C. e RENNÓ, L. (2007),“O que é que o reeleito tem? O retorno: o esboço de uma teoria da reeleição no Brasil”. Revista de Economia Política , 27 (4): 664-683. Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rep/v27n4/a10v27n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rep/v27n4/a10v2...
; Avelino and Biderman, 2009AVELINO, G. & BIDERMAN, C. (2009),“Obras e votação municipal de candidatos a deputado federal no estado de São Paulo: alguns resultados preliminares”, in Magna Inácio and Lucio Rennó (orgs.), Legislativo brasileiro em perspectiva comparada , Belo Horinzonte, Editora da UFMG, pp. 294-334. ).

The fragility of the assumptions of both experts on Brazil and comparativists resides in their exclusivist nature. A simple inspection of the territorial distribution of votes in Brazilian legislative elections reveals that OLPR system’s allow for the emergence of both geographic and non geographic-based representation. Research shows that candidates may opt to geographically restrict their campaigns, concentrating their votes in a few specific areas or to invest on a certain social segment widely dispersing their votes ( Fleischer, 1976FLEISCHER, D. V. (1976), “Concentração e dispersão eleitoral: um estudo da distribuição geográfica do voto em Minas Gerais, 1966-1974. Revista Brasileira de Estudos Políticos , 43. ; Dias, 1991DIAS, J. L. M. (1991), O jogo e os jogadores: legislação eleitoral e padrões de competição política . Master dissertation, Rio de Janeiro, Iuperj. ; Kuschnir, 2000aKUSCHNIR, K., (2000a). Eleições e representação no Rio de Janeiro. RelumeDumará/ Núcleo de Antropologia da Política da UFRJ. ; Kinzo et al., 2003KINZO, M. D. G.; Martins Jr., J. P. & Borin, I. (2003),“Padrões de competição eleitoral na disputa para a Câmara paulistana: 1992-2000”. Novos Estudos Cebrap , 65: 45-56. ; Carvalho, 2003CARVALHO, N. R. (2003), E no início eram as bases: geografia política do voto e comportamento legislativo no Brasil . Rio de Janeiro, Revan. ; Ames, 2005AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. ). Therefore, the formal single multi-member constituency would turn into many informal constituencies as candidates and sitting members draw within it different geographic, thematic and ideological borders. The electoral connection would then assume multiple configurations according to different territorial distributions of votes.

In this paper I set myself the goal of teasing out the effects of the electoral connection on Brazilian legislators’ behaviour. In order to do so, I look at the Rio de Janeiro City Council (RJCC) over a fourteen-year period, which covers four legislative sessions between 1997 and 2010. I focus on the targeting choices of councillors when they have the chance to decide which policies they want to see implemented. Instead of adopting one of the two views seen in the previous paragraphs, I expect to see the targeting choices of councillors varying on the different characteristics of their informal constituencies.

More precisely, I examine councillors´ amendments to the Annual Budget Proposal (ABP). The ABP offers a unique chance for legislators to fund the policies they want to see implemented. I expect to see councillors channelling funds to either narrow or broad targets, depending on the characteristics of their informal constituencies.

Rather than narrowly aiming to help filling in a gap in the studies on Brazilian politics, this paper addresses a broader lacuna in the literature on OLPR systems. This is an endeavour of special concern to other Latin American countries such as Colombia and Peru, which also have post-authoritarian regimes built on OLPR systems.

In addition, I consider this paper to be an important step forward in our knowledge of the workings of local politics in Brazil. Despite the significant role of the subnational levels of government, the national Chamber of Deputies catches a far disproportionate amount of attention from scholars, causing state and municipal legislatures to be largely neglected. Again, this contribution might also benefit the study of local politics elsewhere since other countries also hold local and state elections under OLPR systems, such as those held in the Colombian cities of Bogotá, Cali and Medellín ( García Sánchez, 2003GARCÍA-SÁNCHEZ, M. – (2003), ¿ Ciudadaníaavergonzada? Democracia local y construcción de ciudadanía. El caso de las juntas administradoras locales de Bogotá . Universidad Nacional de Colombia, Instituto de Estudios Políticos y Relaciones Internacionales. Available at http://biblioteca.clacso.edu.ar/subida/clacso/becas/20101117124348/garcia.pdf.ori:, consulted in 17 January 2011.
http://biblioteca.clacso.edu.ar/subida/c...
) and in several German federal states ( Pitrová, 2008PITROVÁ, M. (2008), “Municipalities in the Federal Republic of Germany”. The Journal of the Central European Political Science Association , 1 (4): 60-75. Available at http://www.politicsince.eu/documents/file/2008_06.pdf, consulted in 19 December 2012.
http://www.politicsince.eu/documents/fil...
).

Apart from these first introductory words, this paper is divided into five sections. In the next section I provide a discussion of the main references in the study of the electoral connection in Brazil. In the third section I present my variables and the hypotheses I am testing. I dedicate the forth section to set out the methods. Finally, in the fifth and sixth sections, respectively, I carry out my empirical analysis, followed by my conclusions.

The electoral connection in Brazil

Despite not carefully examined, the alleged effects of the electoral connection are, yet, frequently an essential component of explanatory models. As a rule, it is assumed that the behaviour of Brazilian legislators gravitates fundamentally around local, geographically fragmented interests ( Samuels, 2002SAMUELS, D. J. (2002), “Pork barreling is not credit claiming or advertising: campaign finance and the sources of the personal vote in Brazil”. The Journal of Politics , 64 (3): 845-863. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1520116, consulted in 14 April 2009.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1520116...
; Pereira and Mueller, 2004PEREIRA, C. & MUELLER, B. (2004), “The cost of governing: strategic behavior of the president and legislators in Brazil’s budgetary process”. Comparative Political Studies , 37 (781). Available at http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/37/7/781, consulted in 2 June 2009.
http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstr...
; Pereira and Rennó, 2007PEREIRA, C. e RENNÓ, L. (2007),“O que é que o reeleito tem? O retorno: o esboço de uma teoria da reeleição no Brasil”. Revista de Economia Política , 27 (4): 664-683. Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rep/v27n4/a10v27n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rep/v27n4/a10v2...
; Avelino and Biderman, 2009AVELINO, G. & BIDERMAN, C. (2009),“Obras e votação municipal de candidatos a deputado federal no estado de São Paulo: alguns resultados preliminares”, in Magna Inácio and Lucio Rennó (orgs.), Legislativo brasileiro em perspectiva comparada , Belo Horinzonte, Editora da UFMG, pp. 294-334. ). Moreover the explanatory models often do not include any variable capable of measuring the characteristics of legislators’ constituencies. The need to meet the constituents’ narrow geographic-based interests is usually taken for granted as the only conceivable goal and deemed as uniform for all legislators ( Mainwaring, 1991MAINWARING, S. (1991), “Politicians, parties, and electoral systems: Brazil in comparative perspective”. Comparative Politics , 24 (1): 21-43. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/422200, consulted in 8 September 2010.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/422200...
; Lemos, 2001LEMOS, L. B. S. (2001), “O congresso brasileiro e a distribuição de benefícios sociais no período 1988-1994: uma análise distributivista”. Dados , 44 (3): 561-605. ; AmorimNeto and Santos, 2002; Pereira and Mueller, 2003PEREIRA, C. e MUELLER, B. (2003), “Partidos fracos na arena eleitoral e partidos fortes na arena legislativa: a conexão eleitoral no Brasil”. Dados , 43 (4). Available at www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.p...
).

To date Ames (2005)AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. , in particular, Carvalho (2003)CARVALHO, N. R. (2003), E no início eram as bases: geografia política do voto e comportamento legislativo no Brasil . Rio de Janeiro, Revan. and Amorim Neto and Santos (2003)AMORIM NETO, O. e SANTOS, F. (2003),“O segredo ineficiente revisto: o que propõem e o que aprovam os deputados brasileiros”. Dados , 46 (4). Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a02v46n4.pdf, consulted in 11 January 2010.
http://www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a02...
are the only political scientists to insofar consider and test the versatile character of the electoral connection in Brazil. 2 2 In contrast, Brazilian anthropologists have advanced significantly in understanding the relations between legislators and their constituents ( Kuschnir, 2000a ; 2000b ; 2001; Lopez, 2004 ; Santos, 2005 ; Siqueira, 2009 ; Garcez et al. , 2009 ).

Ames (2005)AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. is the first to use the different patterns of vote distribution as an explanatory variable of legislators’ behaviour. 3 3 The Deadlock of Democracy in Brazil (2005) was first published in 2001. The book is a collection of papers produced from the late 1980s onwards. He works with three defining elements of the informal constituencies: (1) vote distribution, the extent of scatteredness/concentration of votes; (2) their living standards; and (3) the degree of competition within them, which is named as dominance. 4 4 Despite considering the living standards, Ames (2005) emphasises the importance of vote distribution and dominance. However innovative when shedding light on the existence of informal constituencies, Ames circumscribes his analysis to the usual limited approach adopted by experts interested in Brazil, leaving aside a priori the possibility that legislators may engage in broad scope initiatives. In other words, the informal constituencies are defined and measured but its influence on the behaviour of legislators is left unexplored. 5 5 Ames (2005) , as well as the other authors mentioned in this section, looks at the national Chamber of Deputies, whose members´ formal constituencies are the state whole territory.

Amorim Neto and Santos (2003)AMORIM NETO, O. e SANTOS, F. (2003),“O segredo ineficiente revisto: o que propõem e o que aprovam os deputados brasileiros”. Dados , 46 (4). Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a02v46n4.pdf, consulted in 11 January 2010.
http://www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a02...
go a step further ( Lemos, 2001LEMOS, L. B. S. (2001), “O congresso brasileiro e a distribuição de benefícios sociais no período 1988-1994: uma análise distributivista”. Dados , 44 (3): 561-605. ; Amorim Neto and Santos, 2002AMORIM NETO, O. e SANTOS, F. (2002), “A produção legislativa do congresso: entre a paróquia e a nação”, in Luiz Werneck Vianna (org.), A democracia e os três poderes no Brasil. Belo Horizonte/Rio de Janeiro, Iuperj/Faperj/Editora da UFMG. ; Ames, 2005AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. ). Working with vote distribution and dominance, taken from Ames (2005)AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. , they distance themselves from the previous studies by admitting the possibility that legislators might lean towards broad policies issues, depending on the characteristics of their informal constituencies.

Accordingly, more dominant legislators and legislators who concentrate more votes in a few municipalities would be closer to their constituents and, therefore, more able to claim credit for the delivery of local, particularised benefits. Conversely, less dominant legislators and legislators whose votes are fairly dispersed throughout their formal constituency would be closer to non geographic segments and, therefore, more able to claim credit for the enactment of broad public policies.

Two set of logit multiple regressions are used. One set of regressions measures the chance of a legislator to submit at least one national proposal, whereas the other measures the chance of a legislator to submit at least one parochial proposal, which targets a single municipality.

The findings partially corroborate the expected effects of the electoral connection. The model for the national proposals, though, yields some puzzling, unexplained, results, as it shows increasing geographic vote concentration leading to increasing chances of submitting a proposal, which contradicts the expectations.

The inclusion of vote distribution and dominance clearly enhances the analysis. Nevertheless, when building their parochial proposals model, Amorim Neto and Santos (2003)AMORIM NETO, O. e SANTOS, F. (2003),“O segredo ineficiente revisto: o que propõem e o que aprovam os deputados brasileiros”. Dados , 46 (4). Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a02v46n4.pdf, consulted in 11 January 2010.
http://www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a02...
do not worry to check the matches between the target of the proposals and the legislator’s top municipalities in terms of vote distribution and dominance. In other words, we do not know if the legislators are targeting the municipalities in which they perform better or if they are, instead, targeting any municipality regardless of their degree of dominance or vote concentration. To precisely measure the effect of the electoral connection, though, we should not take into account all the parochial proposals but only those targeting the municipalities considered as making up the legislator’s informal constituency.

Carvalho (2003)CARVALHO, N. R. (2003), E no início eram as bases: geografia política do voto e comportamento legislativo no Brasil . Rio de Janeiro, Revan. later confirms the significant role of dominance on the submission of national proposals, tested alongside the effect of government coalition membership and ideology. More importantly though, when looking at the local initiatives, Carvalho (2003)CARVALHO, N. R. (2003), E no início eram as bases: geografia política do voto e comportamento legislativo no Brasil . Rio de Janeiro, Revan. does check the matches between their targets and the legislator’s top municipalities regarding the degree of vote concentration. The indicator, in fact, informs the percentage of the budget amendments targeting the top fifteen municipalities. 6 6 Carvalho (2003) uses his own indicators of dominance, distinct from Ames’ (2005) .

The effect of dominance on the indicator score of each individual legislator is tested and confirmed, using an ordinary least square regression model. As expected, increasing degree of dominance leads to increasing shares of the budget amendments targeting the top municipalities.

However, Carvalho (2003)CARVALHO, N. R. (2003), E no início eram as bases: geografia política do voto e comportamento legislativo no Brasil . Rio de Janeiro, Revan. does not include vote distribution, living standards or ideology in his explanatory model. These three elements would certainly widen and enhance the analysis. Furthermore, his decision to base his indicator on the percentage of the number of budget amendments might be misleading. For instance, two different amendments, equally counted as one, may have disparate values, as one may fund the construction of a big barrage and the other, the paving of a small rural road. For this reason, it would be better to build the indicator using the value, not the number, of the amendments, which is how I proceed as shown in the next section.

Variables & hypotheses

The executive is responsible for drafting theAnnual Budget Proposal (ABP) and sending it to the legislature. Once in the legislature, the ABP, which estimates the revenue and sets the expenditures for the following fiscal year, may be changed before submitted to a final vote. In contrast with the members of the National Congress, there are no quotas for individual councillors in Rio de Janeiro regarding the amount of funds they are allowed to reallocate. The funds are channelled to either local or non-territorial targets. These two targets are, each, the basis for my two dependent variables. Local funds measures for each councillor the amount of funds in reais that is reallocated to her top neighbourhoods whereas non-territorial funds measures for each councillor the amount of funds in reais that is reallocated to non-territorial targets. 7 7 Since 1995 each member of the National Congress has an individual quota of funds to reallocate through budget amendments ( Pereira and Mueller, 2004 ).

Because a great number of councillors choose not to amend the ABP, my dependent variables present highly right skewed distributions. Given its statistical features, my data demands the use of a zero-inflated negative binomial (Zinb) regression model. Zinb models are two-part models. On the one hand, a binary component estimates the probability of a zero count, which here means the chance that a legislator will not reallocate any budget fund at all. On the other hand, a negative binomial component estimates the positive counts, which means the change in the amount of budget fund that a legislator reallocates, excluding those who have not submitted any amendment. The negative binomial component constitutes the core of my analysis.

Count model

Building on the work of Ames (2005)AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. , I test the effect of (1) vote distribution , (2) dominance and (3) living standards on the behaviour of councillors when submitting amendments to the ABP.

Vote distribution

Formally all fifty-one councillors in Rio de Janeiro represent the same single at-large citywide constituency. However, the existence of different territorial distributions of votes suggests otherwise. In the 2000 election, for instance, councillor Luis Carlos Aguiar got almost half of his sixteen thousand votes from the two suburban neighbourhoods of Cordovil and Parada de Lucas alone, which comprises an area of six square kilometres (km2) or 0.5% of the municipal territory. On the other hand, in that same year, councillor Carlos Bolsonaro exhibited a completely different pattern of vote distribution. His 16,053 votes are much more dispersed, with a maximum of 1,002 or 6.2% garnered in Copacabana.

Each of these two patterns of vote distribution should create a different set of incentives leading, therefore, to different behaviours. On the one hand, there is a well defined geographic circumscription in the north of the city; on the other, there is a thematic/ideological non geographic space. As expected, councillor Bolsonaro is indeed known for defending far-right political views and for standing as the representative of the military while councillor Aguiar likes to picture himself as the local benefactor of his small bailiwick. The first fits the model proposed by comparativists while the second proves that the transplantation of the distributive archetype from first-pass-the-post systems to Brazil does, if not always, also make sense.

Accordingly councillors whose votes are reasonably scattered should reallocate greater amount of budget funds to non-territorial targets. Given their pattern of vote distribution, instead of a few specific neighbourhoods, they would see non geographic social segments as their constituencies. Conversely, councillors who concentrate large shares of their votes in a few neighbourhoods are more likely to target these same neighbourhoods with local benefits. Given their pattern of vote distribution they would see their top neighbourhoods as their constituencies, instead of non geographic social segments.

From what has been specified, I derive the following hypotheses:

H1 The more dispersed the votes of a councillor, the greater the amount of funds reallocated to non-territorial targets.

H2 The more votes a legislator concentrates in a few neighbourhoods, the greater the amount of funds reallocated to these same neighbourhoods.

Dominance

Aguiar, in fact, reigns comfortably in his suburban stronghold, as no other councillor is firmly established in that area. Thus, in this case, the analogy with the representatives of single-member constituencies of FPTP systems is far from inadequate. However, most of his peers are not as dominant as he is. The clash between councillors Aspásia Camargo and Andrea Gouvêa Vieira demonstrates this.

These two councillors received similar amounts of votes in the 2008 election, respectively 31,880 and 28,213. They, too,concentrated much of their votes – 42.1% and 43.1% – in the five neighbourhoods in which they performed better. The similarity between them includes their main sources of votes,as the map below shows the overlapping of their vote distribution.

The comparison between Aguiar, on the one hand, and Camargo and Vieira, on the other, takes us to the second defining element of the informal constituencies: the competition from fellow members of the legislature in the areas in which legislators perform better, in other words, the degree of a councillor´s dominance over a territory. Distinct degrees of dominance should lead legislators to behave differently. For dominant councillors like Aguiar the status of local benefactor is reasonably safe from challengers. Conversely, the local leadership of councillors such as Camargo and Vieira is much more precarious.

Essentially, increasing degrees of dominance would bring councillors closer to the distributive mode of behaviour as their ability for claiming credit for the delivery of particularised benefits increases. In contrast, for councillors at the low end of the dominance scale, claiming credit for the delivery of local benefits would be anything but feasible. Because they lack the power to affirm any territorial leadership, they would more frequently engage in non geographic initiatives.

From what has been specified, I derive the following hypotheses:

H3 The less dominant a councillor, the greater the amount of funds reallocated to non-territorial targets.

H4 The more dominant a councillor, the greater the amount of funds reallocated to her top neighbourhoods.

Living standards

The third main defining element of the informal constituencies is the living standards of the neighbourhoods which contribute the greatest to the legislator’s votes. For example, considering the 2000 election, councillors Aguiar and Leila do Flamengo both concentrated large shares of votes in a few neighbourhoods. These neighbourhoods were also fairly safe from outsiders. Their living standards were starkly different though, as seen in the following map. Aguiar’s top neighbourhoods scored 0.79 on the Human Development Index (HDI) whereas Leila do Flamengo’s scored 0.95.

It is plausible to expect that differences in the living standards of the top neighbourhoods influence the behaviour of legislators. Constituents in poorer neighbourhoods are, at one time, less well served by and more dependent on the provision of public services. Understandably, demands for the proper provision of basic public services are more frequent and dramatic in low HDI neighbourhoods.

Therefore, councillors whose top neighbourhoods have low living standards are subject to greater pressure regarding the solution of eminently local immediate needs, which would draw them near the logic of distributive policies ( Diniz, 1982DINIZ, E. (1982), Voto e máquina política . Rio de Janeiro, Paz e Terra. ; Kuschnir, 2000aKUSCHNIR, K., (2000a). Eleições e representação no Rio de Janeiro. RelumeDumará/ Núcleo de Antropologia da Política da UFRJ. ; 2000bKUSCHNIR, K. (2000b). O cotidiano da política . Rio de Janeiro, Jorge Zahar. ). In contrast, the inhabitants of high income neighbourhoods usually do not need to knock on the doors of the RJCC to have the potholes on the local public ways taken care of. Thus, free from worrying with the proper delivery of basic public services, these constituents can more frequently centre their demands on broad-scope policies and issues.

From what has been specified, I derive the following hypotheses:

H5 The higher the living standards of the top neighbourhoods of a councillor, the greater the amount of funds reallocated to non-territorial targets.

H6 The lower the living standards of the top neighbourhoods of a councillor, the greater the amount of funds reallocated to these same neighbourhoods.

I am also testing for interactive effects between vote distribution , dominance and living standards . I have a series of two-way interactive terms and one three-way interactive term.

I expect vote distribution , dominance and living standards to influence on one another’s effects. For instance, as set out in H2, the larger the shares of votes a councillor concentrates in her top neighbourhoods, the greater the amount of funds reallocated to these same neighbourhoods. As I contend, this relationship is further reinforced or attenuated by living standards and dominance . High dominance and low living standards would reinforce the effect of high vote distribution scores on local funds while low dominance and high living standards would attenuate it. The same applies to the remaining possible different interaction terms both in terms of their effect on local and non-territorial funds . Thus, for instance, the heavier emphasis on non-territorial funds of fairly non dominant councillors is strengthened by high living standards and/or small sum of votes concentrated in the top neighbourhoods.

Other independent variables

Besides my three main independent variables, there are five additional independent variables – provision of social services , seniority , number of votes , population size and party ideology . Consonant with the literature on candidate-centric system, I expect party ideology to play no significant role.

The other four independent variables should not affect councillors’ behaviour – whether leaning more towards broad or narrow targeting choices. I expect to see them affecting the amount of budget funds being reallocated but not their targeting choice.

Specifically, in regard to seniority , along with the years served in the legislature comes an increasing familiarity with the legislative process, which should benefit more senior councillors when seizing the opportunity to amend the ABP. Thus, increasing seniority should lead to increasing amount of budget funds being reallocated. Similarly, population size , which measures for each councillor the size of the population living in the top neighbourhoods, should have a positive relationship with the amount of reallocated budget funds. Thus, the greater the population size , the greater the pressure for the funding of public policies and, therefore, the greater the amount of reallocated budget funds. Conversely, as far as number of votes is concerned, more vulnerable councillors should work harder to retain and expand their constituencies, which should lead to increasing amount of budget funds being reallocated. Then, the smaller the number of votes received in the past election, the greater the amount of reallocated budget funds.

By its turn, the provision of social services should lead to decreasing amount of reallocated budget funds. The running of social centres has been portrayed in the media as a powerful political strategy. Through NGOs, councillors provide health and child care, education and job training to constituents, among other benefits. The use of such expedient is far from uncommon ( Souza, 2004SOUZA, R. B. (2004), Clientelismo e Voto em Campos dos Goytacazes . Master dissertation, Campos dos Goytacazes, Centro de Ciência do Homem, Universidade Estadual do Norte Fluminense (UENF).Available at http://www.royaltiesdopetroleo.ucam-campos.br/index.php?cod=4, consulted in 2 March 2010.
http://www.royaltiesdopetroleo.ucam-camp...
; Garcez et. al. , 2009GARCEZ, L. S.; MARTINS, M. & VIEIRA, P. S. (2009), “Conexão política em espaços urbanos: estudos etnográficos sobre atuações de parlamentares na cidade do Rio de Janeiro”. Ponto Urbe , 5. Available at http://www.pontourbe.net/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=17:conexao-politica-em-espacos-urbanos-estudos-etnograficos-sobre-atuacoes-de-parlamentares-na-cidade-do-rio-de-janeiro&catid=7:graduacao-em-campo&Itemid=12, consulted in 12 September 2010.
http://www.pontourbe.net/index.php?optio...
). For many councillors the provision of social services is fundamental for their electoral survival. Keeping the social service machines well greased and running smoothly demands a good deal of resources ( Siqueira, 2009SIQUEIRA, R. A. S. (2009), “Mediações políticas: estudo do cotidiano de um vereador carioca”. Sociedade e Cultura , 12: 45-54. Available atredalyc.uaemex.mx/pdf/703/70312338006.pdf, consulted in 12 September 2010.
atredalyc.uaemex.mx/pdf/703/70312338006....
). As a result, because of the effort put on polishing their main arms, councillors who run social centres sideline legislative initiatives, such as amending the ABP.

Binary model

I include eight variables in the binary component of my model. These are all dummy variables. Five of them indicate the different regions of the city: (1) South Zone Centro & North Zone ; (2) Suburbs ; (3) Ilha do G overnador ; (4) Barra & Jacarepaguá ; and (5) West Zone . Each of these five regions provides their inhabitants with a sense of a shared identity. These different identities are found in councillors’ speeches delivered on the RJCC floor and in the strategies and languages employed in political and electoral campaigns ( Kuschnir, 2000aKUSCHNIR, K., (2000a). Eleições e representação no Rio de Janeiro. RelumeDumará/ Núcleo de Antropologia da Política da UFRJ. ; 2000bKUSCHNIR, K. (2000b). O cotidiano da política . Rio de Janeiro, Jorge Zahar. ). Several councillors are notoriously – and self-proclaimed – strongly associated with certain regions. The city administration, too, uses them to divide the municipal territory into different planning areas.

Two other variables refer to freshness: freshers and freshers with relatives . In this case the reference group are non fresher councillors. Finally, there is a dummy variable for the membership of the Committee of Finances, Budget and Fiscal Oversight (CFBFO). Notwithstanding its lesser importance in the analysis, the binary component addresses the interesting question of what determines the chance of a legislator to submit at least one budget amendment.

In sum, as far as region is concerned, I expect to see a distinct behaviour among councillors whose votes are found mainly in South Zone, Centro & North Zone . This is the region from which Kuschnir’s (2000a)KUSCHNIR, K., (2000a). Eleições e representação no Rio de Janeiro. RelumeDumará/ Núcleo de Antropologia da Política da UFRJ. ideological councillors come. Accordingly, ideological councillors champion “universalist” approaches underpinned by modern notions of citizenship, regarding their terms in office as “instruments” for the “organised” and “politically aware” sectors of society. In comparison with their fellow legislators, these councillors should be more likely to reallocate at least some non-territorial funds and more likely not to reallocate any local funds .

In regard to freshness, freshers should be more likely not to reallocate any funds while no significant difference should be seen between freshers with relatives and non freshers . Lastly, councillors with no experience in the CFBFO should be more likely not to submit any budget amendments.

Methods

My analysis covers four legislative sessions – 1997-2000, 2001-2004, 2005-2008 and the first two years of the 2009-2012. In the legislative sessions of 1997-2000 and 2001-2004, there were forty-two seats in the RJCC. This number went up to fifty in the following legislative session of 2005-2008 and finally to fifty-one in the legislative session of 2009-2012. However, the total number of councillors serving in each legislative session has been greater than the number of seats in the council as substitutes are sworn in to replace main office holders who take a leave of absence or do not finish their terms. Hence, the total number of councillors serving in each of the four legislative sessions is respectively 53, 52, 66 and 56.

My unit of analysis is all the councillors who have served in the RJCC for at least one year during the budgetary process. In order to increase the number of observations, I am pooling all councillors from the four legislative sessions into a single time-series cross-section (TSCS) dataset. My unit of observation is councillors per year. Thus, individual councillors appear in the dataset as many times as the number of years they have served between January 1997 and December 2010. For instance, then, a councillor who served six years appears six times in the dataset.

I run several different models: a basic model, without any interaction terms, and some additional ones, testing the interactive effects among vote distribution , dominance and living standards ( Aiken and West, 1996AIKEN, L. S. & West, S. G. (1996), Multiple regression: Testing and interpreting interactions . Newbury Park, Sage. ; Jaccard and Tuttisi, 2003JACCARD, J. & TUTTISI, R. (2003), Interaction effects in multiple regression. Thousand Oaks, CA. Sage. ; Greene, 2010GREENE, W. (2010), “Testing hypotheses about interaction terms in nonlinear models”. Working paper. Available at http://w4.stern.nyu.edu/economics/docs/workingpapers/2009/Interaction-Terms-in-Nonlinear-Models.pdf, consulted in 24 August 2012.
http://w4.stern.nyu.edu/economics/docs/w...
; Hilbe, 2011HILBE, J. M. (2011), Negative binomial regression . Cambridge,Cambridge University Press. ). I am working with two dependent variables, as I explain in the next section. Therefore, I run two sets of regressions.

Given the non normal distribution of my two dependent variables I cannot use an ordinary least squares (OLS) regression model to run my analysis. At first, a Poisson model, instead, seems as the appropriate solution. However, the mean and variance values of neither of my dependent variables are the same. The overdispersion seen in both cases, as variance exceeds the mean, constitutes a violation of the Poisson distribution. Thus, considering the presence of overdispersion, the distribution that best fits the data is the negative binominal. Moreover, because of the excessive number of zeros, I resort to a Zinb model ( Lambert, 1992LAMBERT, D. (1992). “Zero-Inflated poisson regression, with an application to defects in manufacturing”. Technometrics , 34 (1): 1-14. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1269547, consulted in 19 May 2012.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1269547...
).

Likewise to Poisson models, negative binominal models are used for the analysis of non-negative count data. The zero-inflated version is a two-part model: there are a binary component – either logit or probit –, that estimates the probability of a zero count, and a negative binomial component that estimates the positive counts. Typically, and this is the approach I follow, the count and the binary portions have different covariates. The covariates in the binary component are the covariates thought as having a direct bearing on zero counts ( Hilbe, 2011HILBE, J. M. (2011), Negative binomial regression . Cambridge,Cambridge University Press. ).

The use of a negative binominal model requires some adjustments. Firstly I divide the values of my dependent variables by one thousand. This transformation diminishes the risk of numerical overflow during the calculation of the coefficients, as some of the observations counted millions of reais in reallocated funds ( Greene, 2012GREENE, W. (2012). Limdep Version 10. Econometric Modeling Guide. Plainview, NY. Econometric Software, Inc. ). Secondly, I round off the values, turning them into integers.

Also, carrying out a regression analysis using TSCS data demands additional care, as it often allows for temporally and spatially correlated errors and heteroscedasticity ( Beck and Katz, 1995BECK, N. & KATZ, N. J. (1995), “What to do (and not to do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data”. The American Political Science Review , 89 (3): 634-647. ). In regard to my data in particular, it might be argued that the way councillors behave in a certain year is dependent on the way they behaved in the past. Also, there might be a particular circumstance in a given year that affects all councillors’ behaviour. Tackling these issues demands the addition of the lagged dependent variable – yi , t -1 – in the set of the regressors – x i , t –, the inclusion of dummy variables for each year and the use of robust standard errors.

In total, I would have 638 observations. The actual number of observation is smaller, though. The addition of the lagged dependent variable reduces the number of observations because newcomers have no previous year’s record of budget funds reallocation. Therefore these observations have to be dropped. Moreover, the elimination of outliers further reduces the number of observations. Once such cases were treated I ended up with 461 observations in my local funds regressions and 466 in my non-territorial funds regressions.

Measuring the dependent variables

Local Funds and Non-territorial Funds

Local funds measures the amount of budget funds a legislator reallocates to her top neighbourhoods whereas non-territorial funds measures the amount of budget funds a legislator reallocates to non-territorial targets.

In most cases coding the assigned target of the funds is a straightforward task. A great majority of the funds are channelled either to specific neighbourhoods – local funds – or to the city or a social segment – non-territorial funds . There are exceptions, though, as budget amendments might also target an Administrative Region (AR) or Planning Area (PA).

The PAs are the broadest administrative level. The ARs come next. They make up an intermediary level between the PAs and the neighbourhoods. In total, there are 10 APs, 34 ARs and 140 neighbourhoods. Because the PAs cover large territories, I code the funds going to a PA as non-territorial funds . The ARs are not as wide, though. Therefore, I code as local funds the funds going to an AR in which at least one of the councillor’s top 5 neighbourhoods is located.

Measuring the independent variables

Vote Distribution

Vote distribution is a continuous variable. It measures, for each councillor, the extent to which her votes are more or less evenly scattered throughout the city. Constructing it involves two steps. In the first step, for every councillor in each neighbourhood, I calculate Cij , the percentage that neighbourhood j contributes to councillor i ’s total vote citywide.

As I contend, given their electoral importance, councillors might convert some neighbourhoods into their informal constituency. It is reasonable to suppose that neighbourhoods with great shares of a councillor’s total vote should comprise her informal constituency. Generally Cij shows little dispersion. On average 122 of the 140 neighbourhoods contribute, each, with 1% or less of the councillors’ total vote Neighbourhoods concentrating such small fractions of councillors’ total vote can hardly be thought as relevant per se and hence may well be considered not part of an informal constituency. In contrast, on average councillors find 19.1% of their total vote in their top neighbourhood and slightly more than half of this amount, 9.8%, in their second top neighbourhood. Together the top five ranked neighbourhoods add to nearly 45% of the councillors’ total vote. 8 8 In fact, there are 159 rather than 140 neighbourhoods in Rio de Janeiro. However, not all of them have polling stations in their territory, which means that people are registered in nearby neighbourhoods. I decided to deal with this issue by joining together the neighbourhoods without any polling stations and the more similar contiguous neighbourhoods in terms of their living standards, measured as their score on the Human Development Index (HDI). For instance, the neighbourhood of Gardênia Azul, which does not have any polling station, is contiguous to Jacarepaguá, Freguesia, Cidade de Deus and Anil. Its HDI score in 2000 was 0.77 while Jacarepaguá’s was also 0.77 and Freguesia’s, Cidade de Deus’ and Anil’s were respectively 0.90, 0.75 and 0.91. Since Gardênia Azul and Jacarepaguá have the same HDI score, they have been joint together in the dataset and treated as one neighbourhood. The neighbourhoods without any polling stations and the neighbourhoods with which they were combined – in parenthesis – are the following: Complexo do Alemão (Ramos), Complexo da Maré (Bonsucesso), Engenheiro Leal (Cavalcanti), Gamboa (Centro), Gardênia Azul (Jacarepaguá), Grumari (Recreio dos Bandeirantes), Itahangá (Barra da Tijuca), Jacarezinho (Jacaré), Joá (Barra da Tijuca), Manguinhos (Bonsucesso), Parque Anchieta (Ricardo de Albuquerque), Parque Colúmbia (Acari), Pitangueiras (Cacuia), Praça da Bandeira (Tijuca), Praia da Bandeira (Cocotá), Rocinha (São Conrado), Sampaio (Jacaré), Senador Vasconcelos (Santíssimo) and Vasco da Gama (São Cristóvão).

For the purpose of my analysis, the fifth top neighbourhood, which has a Cij score of nearly 4% of the total vote, seems as a reasonable reference for drawing the line to calculate how concentrated the votes of a councillor are. Moreover, all councillors would increasingly tend, beyond this point, to equally value the neighbourhoods, as there is little and decreasing dispersion around the mean Cij score.

So for each councillor, vote distribution is measured by calculating the share of her total vote that comes from her top 5 neighbourhoods.

Dominance

Dominance is a continuous variable. The way I operationalise it is slightly adapted from Ames (2005)AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. . Dominance measures the extent to which a councillor dominates her top 5 neighbourhoods. The five neighbourhoods used to calculate councillors’ vote distribution are also the reference for assessing councillors’ dominance .

I proceed in two steps. First, for every councillor in each of her top 5 neighbourhoods, I measure Dij , councillor i ’s dominance score in neighbourhood j . In order to do so, I identify all councillors who have neighbourhood j ranked among their top 5 neighbourhoods. I then calculate Dij as councillor i ’s share of the total vote cast in neighbourhood j for all councillors who have neighbourhood j ranked among their top five neighbourhoods.

In the second step, I calculate the dominance score for each councillor across her top 5 neighbourhoods. I sum the five Dij scores, weighted by the share each neighbourhood contributes to councillor i ’s vote in her top 5 neighbourhoods. Hence, the higher a councillor’s dominance score, the more she dominates her five best neighbourhoods, instead of sharing them with fellow legislators.

Living standards

Living standards is a continuous variable. I use the Human Development Index (HDI) as my measurement of living standards . The HDI, which varies from 0 to 1, is widely known as the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP) index for assessing human development around the world. The higher the score, the greater the human development.

I assess, for every councillor, the HDI of her top 5 neighbourhoods. As I proceed with dominance, here I sum the five HDI scores, weighted by the share each neighbourhood contributes to councillor i ’s total vote in her top 5 neighbourhoods.

In regard to the other independent variables, Table 1 explains their coding, measuring and expected effects on the dependent variables. 9 9 Appendix 1 explains the coding, measuring and expected effects of the independent variables on the dependent variables in the binary model.

Table 1
Independent Variables – Count Model 10 10 Regarding Party Ideology, Kinzo (1993) and Rodrigues (1995) arrive at fairly similar categorisations: left – PT, PDT, PSB,PSol, PCdoB; centre-left – PMDB, PPS, PV; centre-right – PHS, PL/PR, PMN, PRB, PRTB, PSC, PSDB, PSDC, PTB, PTC, PTdoB, PTR; right – PPB, PFL/Democratas, Prona.

Empirical analysis

The count models

Since zero-inflated negative binomial (Zinb) models are two-part models, I first approach the results of the count component. Next, I discuss the figures coming out of the binary component.

I have nine different models for each of my two dependent variables. The first, Model I, is the basic model, in which there are no interaction terms. The other models all include one or more interaction terms.

I present the results in Tables 2 and 3 . As far as non-territorial funds is concerned, I show the results just for Models I, IV and IX, as the others have yield significant, although small, impact only for the variable vote ( Long, 1997LONG, J. S. (1997), Regression models for categorical and limited dependent variables. Thousand Oaks, CA. Sage. ). 11 11 It is not possible to perform the Vuong test, which indicatesthe more appropriate model – the Zinb or the standard negative binomial – using robust standard errors. Therefore I separately ran the nine models with standard errors, including the Vuong test. The scores, all significant at the 0.01 level, are between 3.45 and 3.48 for the non-territorial funds regressions and 2.48 and 3.39 for the local funds regressions. Thus numbers clearly favour the Zinb model.

Table 2
Zero-inflated Negative Binomial Models – Count Component – Non-territorial Funds
Table 3
Zero-inflated Negative Binomial Models – Count Component – Local Funds

As hypothesised, the conformation of different informal constituencies is paramount to explaining how councillors choose to amend the Annual Budget Proposal. All in all the analysis confirms the impact of the electoral connection. More important, it confirms the multiple configurations of the electoral connection in OLPR systems. Dominance , living standards and vote distribution significantly affect the amending choices of legislators in Rio de Janeiro. The variation in these three indicators – taken on their own or as interaction terms – tells us where the different members of the RJCC place their emphasis when funding public policies.

Vote distribution , on its own, plays a critical role on both local and non-territorial funds . The fewer the votes a councillor concentrates in her top 5 neighbourhoods, the more she prioritises the funding of broad-scope public policies whereas the more votes a councillor concentrates in her top 5 neighbourhoods, the greater her emphasis on reallocating funds to particular geographic areas. Specifically, considering Model I, for every additional 1.0 point in the vote distribution score, the amount of funds a councillor reallocates to her top 5 neighbourhoods increases by 0.8%, holding all other variables constant. The effect on non-territorial funds is exactly the same but runs in the opposite direction: for every 1.0 point decrease in the vote distribution score, the amount of funds a councillor reallocates to non geographic targets increases by 0.8%. 12 12 The percentage change in the expected amount of funds reallocated is found using the formula 100*[ (expß) -1] ( Long, 1997 , p. 228; Hilbe, 2011 ). The same formula is applied to interpret the logit models.

On the one hand, legislators whose votes are reasonably scattered across the city put their terms in office at the service of the non geographic representation of social segments. As such, they use their budget amendments to fund broad-scope public policies, attaching no special interest to their top 5 neighbourhoods. For comparativist scholars these councillors are the archetype of legislators in OLPR systems, in which the essential territorial overlapping of multi-member constituencies would strongly dampen the emergence of geographic-based representation ( Loewenberg and Kim, 1978LOEWENBERG, G. & KIM, C. L. (1978), “Comparing the representativeness of parliaments”. Legislative Studies Quarterly , 3 (1): 27-49. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/439678, consulted in 5 July 2010.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/439678...
; Jewell and Loewenberg, 1979JEWELL, M. E. & LOEWENBERG, G. (1979), “Editors’ introduction: toward a new model of legislative representation”. Legislative Studies Quarterly , 4 (4): 485-499. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/439402, consulted in 1 June 2010.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/439402...
; Lancaster, 1986LANCASTER, T. D. (1986), “Electoral structures and pork barrel politics”. International Political Science Review/Revue Internationalede Science Politique , 7 (1): 67-81. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1600916,consulted in 5 July 2010.
http://www.jstor.org/stable/1600916...
; Carey and Shugart, 1995CAREY, J. M. & SHUGART, M. S., (1995), Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: a rank ordering of electoral formulas”. Electoral Studies , 14 (4): 417-439. Available at http://cedar.olemiss.edu/courses/pol628/careyshugart95.pdf, consulted in 11 January 2010.
http://cedar.olemiss.edu/courses/pol628/...
).

On the other hand, councillors who concentrate large shares of votes in a specific area of the city turn their terms in office into a tool of geographic-based representation. The five neighbourhoods where they perform better are what make up their de facto constituencies. Given the chance to influence the funding of government programmes, they choose to tailor the ABP in accordance with the needs of their geographic informal constituency. Moreover, the effect of vote distribution becomes stronger as this informal constituency becomes fairly free from fellow legislators’ incursions. This relationship is clearly seen in the interaction between vote distribution and dominance .

Using the results seen in Model VII, Figure 5 shows the partial effect of dominance*vote distribution on local funds , holding all other variables at their mean. The partial effect on local funds is plotted on the y-axis as a function of dominance . In addition, each curve measures the partial effect at a selected vote distribution score. The distance between them reveals the change in the partial effect of local funds vis-à-vis changes in vote distribution . 13 13 The analysis of interaction terms coefficients in nonlinear models deserves extra caution. As Greene (2010) warns us, the interpretation of the magnitude of the effect on the dependent variable based on the value of the coefficient may frequently be unreasonable and misleading. Instead, graphically representing the partial effect of the interaction term is more informative, which is how I proceed.

Figure 5
The Interaction of Dominance and Vote Distribution

On the top right corner of the graph are the councillors with the highest scores in vote distribution and dominance . These councillors resemble, to a reasonable extent, the legislators of first-pass-the-post systems and their single-member constituencies. For most of the scholars working on Brazil, these are the councillors brought into the models.On average they reallocate R$ 2,130 thousand local funds, which is 354% larger than the amount of R$ 470 thousand reallocated by the councillors found on the lower end of the vote distribution and dominance scales.

Additionally, the interaction term dominance* living standards significantly affects how councillors behave in regard to local funds .Using the results seen in Model VII again, Figure 6 shows the partial effect of dominance*living standards on local funds , holding all other variables at their mean. The partial effect on local funds is plotted on the y-axis as a function of dominance . In addition, each curve measures the partial effect at a selected HDI score. The distance between them reveals the change in the partial effect of local funds vis-à-vis changes in living standards .

Figure 6
The Interaction of Dominance and Living Standards

As seen in Figure 6 , non dominant councillors with wealthy top 5 neighbourhoods are found on one side, reallocating the least amount of local funds , whereas dominant councillors in less prosperous areas are found on the other, reallocating the most local funds .

The amount of local funds increases 12% for every 0.05 decrease in the HDI score. Also, the amount of local funds increases 13% for every 0.1 increase in the dominance score. A simultaneous change involving a decrease of 0.05 on the HDI and an increase of 0.1 on the dominance score leads to a 29% increase in the amount of local funds . Comparing the extremes, on average, a councillor with a 0.75 HDI score and a 0.95 dominance score reallocates an amount of local funds 401% larger than a councillor with a 0.95 HDI score and a 0.05 dominance score.

In fact, the effect of dominance*living standards is consonance with the deeply rooted imagine of the bailiwick or curral eleitoral and the practices intimately associated with it: local leaders holding sway over small poor portions of a territory solely sustained by pork barrel politics.

Although hardly threatened by challengers, dominant legislators nurture a strong depedency on the executive. This is because the budget in Brazil, at all three government levels, is not mandatory. Therefore, even though the ABP must pass in the legislature, the decision on whether or not the budget – including the budget amendments – is implemented belongs to the executive. Thus the executive chooses which programmes is implemented, when to implement them and how much money is used in their implementation. In one sentence, the executive, alone, decides on a case-by-case basis which of the budget amendments is implemented. This discretionary power is a potent tool vis-à-vis the legislature as it allows the executive to induce legislators to cooperate ( Pereira and Mueller, 2003PEREIRA, C. e MUELLER, B. (2003), “Partidos fracos na arena eleitoral e partidos fortes na arena legislativa: a conexão eleitoral no Brasil”. Dados , 43 (4). Available at www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.p...
; 2004; Ames, 2005AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. ). 14 14 The Constitutional Amendment no86, promulgated on the 17th of March, 2015, made the implementation of the budget amendments sponsored by individual legislators mandatory ( Brasil, 2015 ).

As the argument goes, there is a chain involving constituents’ demands for public services → legislator → executive → constituents’ demands heard → pro-government voting on the floor. This dependency is further reinforced in the cases of dominance over areas where living standards are low. It is also found among non dominant legislators who, still, concentrate large share of their votes in a few neighbourhoods.

Former Mayor Cesar Maia (1993-1996; 2001-2004; 2005-2008) explains how this series of exchanges among citizens, legislators and the executive provides the mayor a rather powerful mechanism for forging alliances in the legislature:

The councillors whose electoral fate is tied to a few neighbourhoods came onboard in the following day of the inauguration. (...) This does not mean that they will always vote in my favour. You need to give them public works in their area, in their neighbourhoods. This means renewing their loyalty, not gaining loyalty forever ( Marques, 2009MARQUES, F. M. C. (2009), Grupo César Maia: líderes, partidos e política no Rio de Janeiro . Rio de Janeiro, Publit. , p. 59, own translation).

Along those same lines, councillor Rosa Fernandes offers her view of the phenomenon to journalist Sidney Rezende in October 2012. Fernandes concentrates much of her votes in the suburban region of the Great Irajá, where she is largely dominant.

Former Mayor Cesar Maia wanted to marshal the opposition in the council, against Mayor Eduardo Paes. Accordingly, Maia approached me, as we were both affiliated with the same party. But I am too dependent on the executive. I cannot afford to be in the opposition. (...) I am always an ally of the executive. There is no other option. I base my career on the delivery of benefits to a certain area. This is how I work and this is how my constituents expect me to work ( Rezende, 2012REZENDE, S. (2012), “SRZD entrevista a vereadora que ‘fecha’ com o subúrbio carioca”. SRZD Blog [ on-line ].Available at http://www.sidneyrezende.com/noticia/189079+srzd+entrevista+a+vereadora+que+fecha+com+o+suburbio+carioca, consulted in 12 December 2012.
http://www.sidneyrezende.com/noticia/189...
, own translation). 15 15 Sidney Rezende (2009) has also interviewed councillor Dr. Carlos Eduardo, in 2009. Dr. Carlos Eduardo, a physician, whose votes are fairly well distributed across the entire city, is a member of the government coalition. However, in stark contrast with Fernandes, during the whole ten-minute interview, he mentions no other topic than the city public health care system and its deficiencies, showing no special interest in any specific geographic area. The interview is available at http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=97auw86xLw0 , accessed in 21/12/2012.

The relationship between living standards and local funds is anything but unreasonable as councillors who perform better in areas with low living standards probably face more pressing demands for the proper delivery of public services. Unsurprisingly too the relationship between living standards and non-territorial funds runs in the opposite direction: the higher the HDI of the top 5 neighbourhoods, the greater the amount of non-territorial funds a councillor reallocates.

This effect is strengthened when living standards interacts with vote distribution and dominance .The next graphs represent the three-way interaction effect of living standards * dominance*vote distribution . The graphs show living standards at three different HDI scores: 0.75, 0.85 and 0.95. The partial effect on non-territorial funds is plotted on the y-axis as a function of dominance . Each curve measures the partial effect at a selected vote distribution score. The distance between them shows the change in the partial effect of non-territorial funds vis-à-vis changes in vote distribution , holding all other variables at their mean. 16 16 In the presence of interaction, the main effects, such as those of vote distribution and living standards in Model IX, are no longer meaningful; instead, the interpretation should focus on the interaction terms ( Mitchell, 2012 , chapter 6).

The reallocation of non-territorial funds clearly increases as dominance and vote distribution scores decrease. It is evident, too, how the interaction effect between dominance and vote distribution is further reinforced across the board as living standards goes up from a 0.75 to a 0.95 HDI score.Therefore, together, changes in living standards , dominance and vote distribution have a significant impact on non-territorial funds .

In short, non dominant legislators whose votes are widely dispersed over the territory of mainly wealthy areas centre their effort in funding non geographic public policies. Far from more urgent demands for state action, these councillors see themselves as representatives of social segments or ideological platforms while at the same time unable to play the card of the local leader responsible for delivering fragments of government programmes to specific neighbourhoods.

The Binary – Logit – Model

The models for local funds render no significant results at all, showing that the chances that a councillor will never reallocate any local funds does not significantly change as a consequence of (1) serving/having served on the CFBFO ; (2) being a fresher ; (3) concentrating most of the votes in a particular region other than South Zone, Centro& North Zone . 17 17 In fact, the coefficient of Ilha do Governador does have a significant impact. However, the idea here is to verify whether or not the South Zone, Centro & North Zone does distinguish itself from the other regions regarding the budget amending process. Therefore, a comprehensive test of the hypothesis demands an interpretation of the five coefficients all together. Proceeding in such way, looking at the whole set of regional coefficients, all but one with no significant effect, we may infer that there is no significant difference among the distinct regions of the city. The figures for non-territorial funds tell a different story. Because there are no differences among the levels of significance as well as among the coefficients, except, if any, for the third decimal place, I display only the outcome of Model I.

Apart from my argument regarding freshness , my hypotheses are corroborated. Starting with the regional hypotheses, except for Suburbs , the sign and the significance level of the coefficients are all the expected ones. In sum councillors from South Zone, Centro & Tijuca are more likely to fund broad public policies than their fellow legislators from the other four regions of the city. 18 18 Alternatively, I ran a separate binary component model testing the effect of party ideology , which turned out to be insignificant, as expected.

Table 5 also confirms the importance of the CFBFO membership: sitting or having sat on the CFBFO increases by 55% the chance of submitting at least one budget amendment reallocating non-territorial funds .Thus, be it because of collusion, influence or better understanding of the budgetary process, legislators with experience in the CFBFO are far more likely to use the amending power of prioritising the targeting of government programmes.

Table 5
Regions – The Chance of a Councillor to Reallocate At Least Some Amount of Non-territorial Funds

Final remarks

I believe the previous pages have provided a less caricatural and more accurate and diverse account of legislators’ behaviour under OLPR systems.The electoral connection does have a rather powerful effect, as the theory predicts. This is not however a one-dimensional influence, as on their own particular manner comparativists and researchers specialised in Brazil see it. On the contrary, the different patterns of territorial distribution of votes create different sets of incentives, which lead to different behaviours.

Additionally, apart from teasing out the effect of the electoral connection, I believe this paper contributes to the long-lasting debate on the electoral reform in Brazil.

A much frequently mentioned weakness of the OLPR system is its alleged lack of accountability ( Silva et al. , 2015SILVA, P.; DAVIDIAN, A.; FREITAS, A. e CAZZOLATO, J. D. (2015), “Reforma política no Brasil: indagações sobre o impacto no sistema partidário e na representação. OpiniãoPública , 21(1): 1-32. Available at http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?pid=S0104-62762015000100001&script=sci_arttext&tlng=pt, consulted in 9 August 2017.
http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?pid=S010...
). 19 19 Alternatively, Miguel (2010) provides a positive view of the accountability in OLPR systems. Nevertheless, the day-to-day activities of legislators in the legislature itself, outside it and in social media platforms show that the ties between representatives and constituents are far from being as ephemeral as reformers claim ( Kuschnir, 2000aKUSCHNIR, K., (2000a). Eleições e representação no Rio de Janeiro. RelumeDumará/ Núcleo de Antropologia da Política da UFRJ. ; 2000bKUSCHNIR, K. (2000b). O cotidiano da política . Rio de Janeiro, Jorge Zahar. ; Marques et al. , 2014MARQUES, F. P. J. A.; DE AQUINO, J. A. e MIOLA, E. (2014),“Deputados brasileiros no Twitter: um estudo quantitativo dos padrões de adoção e uso da ferramenta”. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política , 14: 201-225. Available at https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Francisco_Paulo_Marques/publication/275291048_Deputados_brasileiros_no_Twitter_um_estudo_quantitativo_dos_padroes_de_adocao_e_uso_da_ferramenta/links/564b0fac08ae127ff987f76c/Deputados-brasileiros-no-Twitter-um-estudo-quantitativo-dos-padroes-de-adocao-e-uso-da-ferramenta.pdf, consulted in 11 August 2017.
https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Fra...
; Viera, 2017VIEIRA, F. A. (2017), Parlamentares e internet: uma análise comparada do perfil de uso das tecnologias digitais por deputados federais e senadores do Brasil, Chile e Uruguai . Master dissertation,Curitiba, Universidade Federal do Paraná (UFPR). Available at http://acervodigital.ufpr.br/bitstream/handle/1884/47314/R%20-%20D%20-%20FABRICIA%20ALMEIDA%20VIEIRA.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y, consulted in 15 August 2017.
http://acervodigital.ufpr.br/bitstream/h...
). Moreover, as seen in the Table 6 , the overwhelming majority of the councillors in Rio de Janeiro roughly repeats the same territorial distribution of vote election after election. In other words, the informal constituencies do express a solid long-term relationship involving representatives and constituents or, at least, subsets of constituents. 20 20 The table includes information on main office holders only.The city of Rio de Janeiro is divided into 97 electoral zones. The coefficients result from the correlation between each electoral zone in two consecutive elections in terms of their contribution to the individual councillor’s total vote. Thus, for instance, councillor A’s territorial distribution of vote in the 1996 election is correlated with councillor A’s territorial distribution of vote in the 2000 election, electoral zone by electoral zone.

Table 6
Correlation Between the Territorial Distributions of Vote in Two Consecutive Elections

As seen in the Total column, on average half of the councillors attain a nearly perfect correlation, reaching coefficients between 0.9 and 1. Slightly above one third displays figures ranging from 0.6 to 0.9, still fairly high values. Thus, close to 90% garner their votes systematically in about the same territory. 21 21 Appendices 2 and 3 shows two examples of how the patterns of vote distribution in different elections almost perfectly correlate.

Still, critics argue that legislators would easily and often abandon their constituencies for different ones from one election to the other because of the remarkable flexibility of the electoral rules. Thus, citizens, although unhappy with their representation, would have no power to inflict any penalty on runaways, who, having a large territory from which to seek votes, would just smoothly land elsewhere and manage to keep their seats thanks to deals struck with local leaders. ( Ames, 2005AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. ; Almeida, 2006ALMEIDA, A. (2006), “Amnésia eleitoral: em quem você votou para deputado em 2002? E em 1998?”, in A Almeida, G. A. D. Soares e L. R. Rennó (orgs.), Reformapolítica: lições da históriarecente , pp. 34-46. ).

Such modus operandi is indeed frequently used to portray the behaviour of legislators in Brazil. Yet, it is an expedient available to a tiny minority: the political machines´ higher-ups and politicians with particularly close ties with big business. A strategic access to state and party resources and/or campaign donors allows them to seal alliances with key players in local politics, who in return deliver blocks of votes. 22 22 This is the case of former president of the Chamber of Deputies, Eduardo Cunha, who, during his 2014 campaign,seldom shook any hands out on the streets but much frequently made brief appearances in popular gathering carefully staged in evangelical churches and eminent civic organisations across many small towns ( Serodio, 2014) .

The single non-transferable vote (SNTV) or distritão , as nicknamed in Brazil, perfectly serves this very same modus operandi and has received enthusiastic support from Mr.Temer and PMDB most prominent bosses ( Temer, 2015TEMER, M. (2015), “O Distritão”. Estado de S. Paulo [ on-line ].Available at http://opiniao.estadao.com.br/noticias/geral,o-distritao-imp-,1634397, consulted in 14 August 2017.
http://opiniao.estadao.com.br/noticias/g...
). The SNTV at once surpasses the OLPR system in terms of deleterious effects on party organisation and the amount of money needed to runwide-ranging campaigns, centred exclusively on individual candidates ( Nicolau, 2017aNICOLAU, J. (2017a), “Distritão, o retrono”.Available at http://www.academia.edu/33938344/Distrit%C3%A3o_o_retorno_2017, consulted in10 August 2017.
http://www.academia.edu/33938344/Distrit...
). 23 23 The distritão was voted down in the Chamber of Deputies in 2015 and 2017. Despite parliament´s decision to keep the system essentially unmodified, justices from the Supreme Court as well as the chiefs of the executive and of the legislative still insist in the need of radically changing the rules ( Galli, 2017 ; Noblat, 2017).

On a much different direction, some reformers see rank-ordered party lists as a means of strengthening parties’ programmatic identities while diminishing the incentives for individual legislators to cultivate the personal vote and, therefore, the alleged endemic distributive logic of the legislature (Shugart and Carey, 1992; Ames, 2005AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. ; Ministério da Justiça, 2009MINISTÉRIO DA JUSTIÇA. (2009), Mensagem 58/2009 [ on-line ]. Available at http://www.camara.gov.br/proposicoesWeb/prop_mostrarintegra?codteor=632496&filename=MSC+58/2009+%3D%3E+PL+4636/2009, consulted in 12 August 2017.
http://www.camara.gov.br/proposicoesWeb/...
;Comissão Especial de ReformaPolítica, 2012).

However, there is no reason to see rank-ordered lists as intrinsically free from the rationale of pork politics, as clear evidence from Costa Rica shows.When deciding on their closed lists in national legislative elections, Costa Rican parties choose to pick names with regional appeal, rather than policy-oriented members. Once elected,these candidates turn into legislators prodigious in the supply of local benefits to their constituencies (Taylor, 1992). Neither does the adoption of ranked-ordered list per se guarantee another much desirable goal: less costly majority-building processes, which might be achieved under the OLPR system by the introduction of an electoral threshold and/or a ban on electoral coalitions in legislatives races. 24 24 In fact, the Constitutional Amendment no 97, promulgated on the 4th of October 2017, establishes an electoral threshold for parties to access public funding and free radio and television time for their election campaigns, beginning at 1.5% in 2018 and reaching 3% from 2030 on. This same amendment bans electoral coalitions in legislative races, starting in the 2020 local election ( Brasil, 2017) .

These last lines are in no way a sweeping praise of the OLPR system. Even experts on Brazil who openly advocate for its maintenance stress the need for some adjustments ( Nicolau, 2017bNICOLAU, J. (2017b). Representantes de quem? Os (des) caminhos do seu voto da urna à Câmara dos Deputados . Rio de Janeiro, Zahar. ). As any other set of rules, it has its pros and cons, depending on different points of view, and must be assessed in the light of its context. Yet, along the lines of Nicolau (2007)NICOLAU, J. (2007), “O sistema eleitoral de lista aberta no Brasil”, in Jairo Nicolau andTmothy Power (eds.), Instituições representativas no Brasil: balanço e reforma . Belo Horizonte, Editora da UFMG, pp. 97-122. , who warns us about how we are still groping in terms of the workings of the electoral connection amid pervading intraparty competition, I believe we should avoid being lured into slapdash changes, which, implemented as promises of a certain foreseeable reality, might in truth end up delivering unwished consequences.

Figure 1
Councillor Luis Carlos Aguiar – Vote Distribution, 2000 Election

Figure 2
Councillor Carlos Bolsonaro – Vote Distribution, 2000 Election

Figure 3
Councillors Aspásia Camargo and Andrea Gouvêa Vieira – Vote Distribution and Territorial Overlap

Figure 4
Councillors Leila do Flamengo and Luis Carlos Aguiar – Living Standards of Top Neighbourhoods

Figure 7
The Three-way Interaction of Dominance, Vote Distribution and Living Standards

Table 4
Zero-inflated Negative Binomial Models – Binary Component – Non-territorial Funds

REFERENCES

  • AIKEN, L. S. & West, S. G. (1996), Multiple regression: Testing and interpreting interactions . Newbury Park, Sage.
  • ALMEIDA, A. (2006), “Amnésia eleitoral: em quem você votou para deputado em 2002? E em 1998?”, in A Almeida, G. A. D. Soares e L. R. Rennó (orgs.), Reformapolítica: lições da históriarecente , pp. 34-46.
  • AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
  • AMORIM NETO, O. e SANTOS, F. (2002), “A produção legislativa do congresso: entre a paróquia e a nação”, in Luiz Werneck Vianna (org.), A democracia e os três poderes no Brasil. Belo Horizonte/Rio de Janeiro, Iuperj/Faperj/Editora da UFMG.
  • AMORIM NETO, O. e SANTOS, F. (2003),“O segredo ineficiente revisto: o que propõem e o que aprovam os deputados brasileiros”. Dados , 46 (4). Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a02v46n4.pdf, consulted in 11 January 2010.
    » http://www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a02v46n4.pdf
  • AVELINO, G. & BIDERMAN, C. (2009),“Obras e votação municipal de candidatos a deputado federal no estado de São Paulo: alguns resultados preliminares”, in Magna Inácio and Lucio Rennó (orgs.), Legislativo brasileiro em perspectiva comparada , Belo Horinzonte, Editora da UFMG, pp. 294-334.
  • BECK, N. & KATZ, N. J. (1995), “What to do (and not to do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data”. The American Political Science Review , 89 (3): 634-647.
  • BRASIL. (2015), Emenda Constitucional 86 de 17 de março de 2015. Available from http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/Constituicao/Emendas/Emc/emc86.htm, consulted in 12 August 2017.
    » http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/Constituicao/Emendas/Emc/emc86.htm
  • BRASIL. (2017),Emenda Constitucional 97 de 4 de outubro de 2017.Available at http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/constituicao/emendas/emc/emc97.htm, consulted in12 August 2017.
    » http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/constituicao/emendas/emc/emc97.htm
  • CAREY, J. M. & SHUGART, M. S., (1995), Incentives to cultivate a personal vote: a rank ordering of electoral formulas”. Electoral Studies , 14 (4): 417-439. Available at http://cedar.olemiss.edu/courses/pol628/careyshugart95.pdf, consulted in 11 January 2010.
    » http://cedar.olemiss.edu/courses/pol628/careyshugart95.pdf
  • CARVALHO, N. R. (2003), E no início eram as bases: geografia política do voto e comportamento legislativo no Brasil . Rio de Janeiro, Revan.
  • DIAS, J. L. M. (1991), O jogo e os jogadores: legislação eleitoral e padrões de competição política . Master dissertation, Rio de Janeiro, Iuperj.
  • DINIZ, E. (1982), Voto e máquina política . Rio de Janeiro, Paz e Terra.
  • FLEISCHER, D. V. (1976), “Concentração e dispersão eleitoral: um estudo da distribuição geográfica do voto em Minas Gerais, 1966-1974. Revista Brasileira de Estudos Políticos , 43.
  • GALLANGHER, M. (2005), “Conclusion”, in Michael Gallagher and Paul Mitchell, (eds.), The politics of electoral systems . Oxford, Oxford Scholars Online. Available at https://shib-idp.ucl.ac.uk/idp/profile/Shibboleth/SSO?shire=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fShibboleth.sso%2fSAML%2fPOST&target=ezp.2aHR0cDovL3BhLm94Zm9yZGpvdXJuYWxzLm9yZy8-&time=1286156244&providerId=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fshibboleth, consulted in 14 April 2009.
    » https://shib-idp.ucl.ac.uk/idp/profile/Shibboleth/SSO?shire=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fShibboleth.sso%2fSAML%2fPOST&target=ezp.2aHR0cDovL3BhLm94Zm9yZGpvdXJuYWxzLm9yZy8-&time=1286156244&providerId=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fshibboleth
  • GALLI, M. (2017), “José Serra e Eunício Oliveira defendem parlamentarismo e voto distrital misto”. Conjur , 26th October [online]. Available at https://www.conjur.com.br/2017-out-26/senadores-defendem-parlamentarismo-voto-distrital-misto, consulted in 11November 2017.
    » https://www.conjur.com.br/2017-out-26/senadores-defendem-parlamentarismo-voto-distrital-misto
  • GARCEZ, L. S.; MARTINS, M. & VIEIRA, P. S. (2009), “Conexão política em espaços urbanos: estudos etnográficos sobre atuações de parlamentares na cidade do Rio de Janeiro”. Ponto Urbe , 5. Available at http://www.pontourbe.net/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=17:conexao-politica-em-espacos-urbanos-estudos-etnograficos-sobre-atuacoes-de-parlamentares-na-cidade-do-rio-de-janeiro&catid=7:graduacao-em-campo&Itemid=12, consulted in 12 September 2010.
    » http://www.pontourbe.net/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=17:conexao-politica-em-espacos-urbanos-estudos-etnograficos-sobre-atuacoes-de-parlamentares-na-cidade-do-rio-de-janeiro&catid=7:graduacao-em-campo&Itemid=12
  • GARCÍA-SÁNCHEZ, M. – (2003), ¿ Ciudadaníaavergonzada? Democracia local y construcción de ciudadanía. El caso de las juntas administradoras locales de Bogotá . Universidad Nacional de Colombia, Instituto de Estudios Políticos y Relaciones Internacionales. Available at http://biblioteca.clacso.edu.ar/subida/clacso/becas/20101117124348/garcia.pdf.ori:, consulted in 17 January 2011.
    » http://biblioteca.clacso.edu.ar/subida/clacso/becas/20101117124348/garcia.pdf.ori:
  • GREENE, W. (2010), “Testing hypotheses about interaction terms in nonlinear models”. Working paper. Available at http://w4.stern.nyu.edu/economics/docs/workingpapers/2009/Interaction-Terms-in-Nonlinear-Models.pdf, consulted in 24 August 2012.
    » http://w4.stern.nyu.edu/economics/docs/workingpapers/2009/Interaction-Terms-in-Nonlinear-Models.pdf
  • GREENE, W. (2012). Limdep Version 10. Econometric Modeling Guide. Plainview, NY. Econometric Software, Inc.
  • HILBE, J. M. (2011), Negative binomial regression . Cambridge,Cambridge University Press.
  • JACCARD, J. & TUTTISI, R. (2003), Interaction effects in multiple regression. Thousand Oaks, CA. Sage.
  • JEWELL, M. E. & LOEWENBERG, G. (1979), “Editors’ introduction: toward a new model of legislative representation”. Legislative Studies Quarterly , 4 (4): 485-499. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/439402, consulted in 1 June 2010.
    » http://www.jstor.org/stable/439402
  • KINZO, M. D. G. (1993), Radiografia do quadro partidário brasileiro . São Paulo, Fundação Konrad Adenauer-Stiftung.
  • KINZO, M. D. G.; Martins Jr., J. P. & Borin, I. (2003),“Padrões de competição eleitoral na disputa para a Câmara paulistana: 1992-2000”. Novos Estudos Cebrap , 65: 45-56.
  • KUSCHNIR, K., (2000a). Eleições e representação no Rio de Janeiro. RelumeDumará/ Núcleo de Antropologia da Política da UFRJ.
  • KUSCHNIR, K. (2000b). O cotidiano da política . Rio de Janeiro, Jorge Zahar.
  • LAMBERT, D. (1992). “Zero-Inflated poisson regression, with an application to defects in manufacturing”. Technometrics , 34 (1): 1-14. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1269547, consulted in 19 May 2012.
    » http://www.jstor.org/stable/1269547
  • LANCASTER, T. D. (1986), “Electoral structures and pork barrel politics”. International Political Science Review/Revue Internationalede Science Politique , 7 (1): 67-81. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1600916,consulted in 5 July 2010.
    » http://www.jstor.org/stable/1600916
  • LEMOS, L. B. S. (2001), “O congresso brasileiro e a distribuição de benefícios sociais no período 1988-1994: uma análise distributivista”. Dados , 44 (3): 561-605.
  • LOEWENBERG, G. & KIM, C. L. (1978), “Comparing the representativeness of parliaments”. Legislative Studies Quarterly , 3 (1): 27-49. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/439678, consulted in 5 July 2010.
    » http://www.jstor.org/stable/439678
  • LONG, J. S. (1997), Regression models for categorical and limited dependent variables. Thousand Oaks, CA. Sage.
  • LOPEZ, F. G. (2004). “A política cotidiana dos vereadores e as relações entre Executivo e Legislativo em âmbito municipal: o caso do município de Araruama”. Revista de Sociologia e Política ,22: 153-177. Available at http://www.scielo.br/scieloOrg/php/clinicaltrials.php?pid=S0104-44782004000100012&lang=en, consulted in 11 January 2010.
    » http://www.scielo.br/scieloOrg/php/clinicaltrials.php?pid=S0104-44782004000100012&lang=en
  • MAINWARING, S. (1991), “Politicians, parties, and electoral systems: Brazil in comparative perspective”. Comparative Politics , 24 (1): 21-43. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/422200, consulted in 8 September 2010.
    » http://www.jstor.org/stable/422200
  • MARQUES, F. M. C. (2009), Grupo César Maia: líderes, partidos e política no Rio de Janeiro . Rio de Janeiro, Publit.
  • MARQUES, F. P. J. A.; DE AQUINO, J. A. e MIOLA, E. (2014),“Deputados brasileiros no Twitter: um estudo quantitativo dos padrões de adoção e uso da ferramenta”. Revista Brasileira de Ciência Política , 14: 201-225. Available at https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Francisco_Paulo_Marques/publication/275291048_Deputados_brasileiros_no_Twitter_um_estudo_quantitativo_dos_padroes_de_adocao_e_uso_da_ferramenta/links/564b0fac08ae127ff987f76c/Deputados-brasileiros-no-Twitter-um-estudo-quantitativo-dos-padroes-de-adocao-e-uso-da-ferramenta.pdf, consulted in 11 August 2017.
    » https://www.researchgate.net/profile/Francisco_Paulo_Marques/publication/275291048_Deputados_brasileiros_no_Twitter_um_estudo_quantitativo_dos_padroes_de_adocao_e_uso_da_ferramenta/links/564b0fac08ae127ff987f76c/Deputados-brasileiros-no-Twitter-um-estudo-quantitativo-dos-padroes-de-adocao-e-uso-da-ferramenta.pdf
  • MAYHEW, D. (1974), Congress: the electoral connection. Fredericksburg. BookCrafters.
  • MIGUEL, L. F. (2010),“Accountability em listas abertas”. Revista de Sociologia e Política , 18 (37): 183-200 [ on-line ].Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rsocp/v18n37/12.pdf, consulted in 18 March 2013.
    » http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rsocp/v18n37/12.pdf
  • MITCHELL, M. (2012), Interpreting and visualizing regression models using stata . Stata Press, E-Book.
  • MINISTÉRIO DA JUSTIÇA. (2009), Mensagem 58/2009 [ on-line ]. Available at http://www.camara.gov.br/proposicoesWeb/prop_mostrarintegra?codteor=632496&filename=MSC+58/2009+%3D%3E+PL+4636/2009, consulted in 12 August 2017.
    » http://www.camara.gov.br/proposicoesWeb/prop_mostrarintegra?codteor=632496&filename=MSC+58/2009+%3D%3E+PL+4636/2009
  • NICOLAU, J. (2001), “A conexão eleitoral de uma família política carioca”. Revista Brasielira de Ciências Sociais , 16 (46): 180-182. Available at http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?script=sci_pdf&pi-d=S0102-69092001000200013&lng=en&nrm=iso&tlng=pt, consulted in 21 September 2010.
    » http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?script=sci_pdf&pi-d=S0102-69092001000200013&lng=en&nrm=iso&tlng=pt
  • NICOLAU, J. (2007), “O sistema eleitoral de lista aberta no Brasil”, in Jairo Nicolau andTmothy Power (eds.), Instituições representativas no Brasil: balanço e reforma . Belo Horizonte, Editora da UFMG, pp. 97-122.
  • NICOLAU, J. (2017a), “Distritão, o retrono”.Available at http://www.academia.edu/33938344/Distrit%C3%A3o_o_retorno_2017, consulted in10 August 2017.
    » http://www.academia.edu/33938344/Distrit%C3%A3o_o_retorno_2017
  • NICOLAU, J. (2017b). Representantes de quem? Os (des) caminhos do seu voto da urna à Câmara dos Deputados . Rio de Janeiro, Zahar.
  • NOBLAT, Ricardo.(2015), “Contagem regressiva para Temer”. Blog do Noblat [ on-line ].Available at http://noblat.oglobo.globo.com/meus-textos/noticia/2017/10/contagem-regressiva-para-temer-10-10-2017.html, consulted in 2 November 2017.
    » http://noblat.oglobo.globo.com/meus-textos/noticia/2017/10/contagem-regressiva-para-temer-10-10-2017.html
  • NORRIS, P. (2004), Electoral engineering: voting rules and political behavior . Massachusetts,Harvard University/Cambridge University Press.
  • PEREIRA, C. e MUELLER, B. (2003), “Partidos fracos na arena eleitoral e partidos fortes na arena legislativa: a conexão eleitoral no Brasil”. Dados , 43 (4). Available at www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
    » www.scielo.br/pdf/dados/v46n4/a04v46n4.pdf
  • PEREIRA, C. & MUELLER, B. (2004), “The cost of governing: strategic behavior of the president and legislators in Brazil’s budgetary process”. Comparative Political Studies , 37 (781). Available at http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/37/7/781, consulted in 2 June 2009.
    » http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/37/7/781
  • PEREIRA, C. e RENNÓ, L. (2007),“O que é que o reeleito tem? O retorno: o esboço de uma teoria da reeleição no Brasil”. Revista de Economia Política , 27 (4): 664-683. Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rep/v27n4/a10v27n4.pdf, consulted in 2 June 2009.
    » http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rep/v27n4/a10v27n4.pdf
  • PITROVÁ, M. (2008), “Municipalities in the Federal Republic of Germany”. The Journal of the Central European Political Science Association , 1 (4): 60-75. Available at http://www.politicsince.eu/documents/file/2008_06.pdf, consulted in 19 December 2012.
    » http://www.politicsince.eu/documents/file/2008_06.pdf
  • REZENDE, S. (2009), “Sidney Rezende entevista o vereador Carlos Eduardo (PSB)”. YouTube [ on-line ]. Available at http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=97auw86xLw0, consulted in 21 December 2012.
    » http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=97auw86xLw0
  • REZENDE, S. (2012), “SRZD entrevista a vereadora que ‘fecha’ com o subúrbio carioca”. SRZD Blog [ on-line ].Available at http://www.sidneyrezende.com/noticia/189079+srzd+entrevista+a+vereadora+que+fecha+com+o+suburbio+carioca, consulted in 12 December 2012.
    » http://www.sidneyrezende.com/noticia/189079+srzd+entrevista+a+vereadora+que+fecha+com+o+suburbio+carioca
  • RODRIGUES, L. M. (1995), “Eleições, fragmentação partidária e governabilidade”. NovosEstudosCebrap , 41: 78-90.
  • SAMUELS, D. J. (2002), “Pork barreling is not credit claiming or advertising: campaign finance and the sources of the personal vote in Brazil”. The Journal of Politics , 64 (3): 845-863. Available at http://www.jstor.org/stable/1520116, consulted in 14 April 2009.
    » http://www.jstor.org/stable/1520116
  • SANTOS, M. M. (2005), Tribunos do povo, servos de Deus: um estudo antropológico sobre políticos e religião na cidade de Porto Alegre . Master dissertation. Porto Alegre, AntropolgyDepartment, Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul (UFRGS).
  • SERODIO, G. (2014), “O diabo tomou conta da política”. Valor Econômico [ on-line ]. Available at http://www.valor.com.br/eleicoes2014/3714044/o-diabo-tomou-conta-da-politica-diz-cunha, colsulted in 14 August 2017.
    » http://www.valor.com.br/eleicoes2014/3714044/o-diabo-tomou-conta-da-politica-diz-cunha
  • SHUGART, M. S. (2005), “Comparative electoral systems research: the maturation of a field and new challenges ahead”, in Michael Gallagher and Paul Mitchell (eds.), The Politics of Electoral Systems . Published to Oxford Scholars On-line. Available at https://shib-idp.ucl.ac.uk/idp/profile/Shibboleth/SSO?shire=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fShibboleth.sso%2fSAML%2fPOST&target=ezp.2aHR0cDov-L3BhLm94Zm9yZGpvdXJuYWxzLm9yZy8-&time=1286156244&providerId=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fshibboleth, consulted in 14 April 2009.
    » https://shib-idp.ucl.ac.uk/idp/profile/Shibboleth/SSO?shire=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fShibboleth.sso%2fSAML%2fPOST&target=ezp.2aHR0cDov-L3BhLm94Zm9yZGpvdXJuYWxzLm9yZy8-&time=1286156244&providerId=https%3a%2f%2flibproxy.ucl.ac.uk%2fshibboleth
  • SILVA, P.; DAVIDIAN, A.; FREITAS, A. e CAZZOLATO, J. D. (2015), “Reforma política no Brasil: indagações sobre o impacto no sistema partidário e na representação. OpiniãoPública , 21(1): 1-32. Available at http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?pid=S0104-62762015000100001&script=sci_arttext&tlng=pt, consulted in 9 August 2017.
    » http://www.scielo.br/scielo.php?pid=S0104-62762015000100001&script=sci_arttext&tlng=pt
  • SIQUEIRA, R. A. S. (2009), “Mediações políticas: estudo do cotidiano de um vereador carioca”. Sociedade e Cultura , 12: 45-54. Available atredalyc.uaemex.mx/pdf/703/70312338006.pdf, consulted in 12 September 2010.
    » atredalyc.uaemex.mx/pdf/703/70312338006.pdf
  • SOUZA, R. B. (2004), Clientelismo e Voto em Campos dos Goytacazes . Master dissertation, Campos dos Goytacazes, Centro de Ciência do Homem, Universidade Estadual do Norte Fluminense (UENF).Available at http://www.royaltiesdopetroleo.ucam-campos.br/index.php?cod=4, consulted in 2 March 2010.
    » http://www.royaltiesdopetroleo.ucam-campos.br/index.php?cod=4
  • TEMER, M. (2015), “O Distritão”. Estado de S. Paulo [ on-line ].Available at http://opiniao.estadao.com.br/noticias/geral,o-distritao-imp-,1634397, consulted in 14 August 2017.
    » http://opiniao.estadao.com.br/noticias/geral,o-distritao-imp-,1634397
  • VIEIRA, F. A. (2017), Parlamentares e internet: uma análise comparada do perfil de uso das tecnologias digitais por deputados federais e senadores do Brasil, Chile e Uruguai . Master dissertation,Curitiba, Universidade Federal do Paraná (UFPR). Available at http://acervodigital.ufpr.br/bitstream/handle/1884/47314/R%20-%20D%20-%20FABRICIA%20ALMEIDA%20VIEIRA.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y, consulted in 15 August 2017.
    » http://acervodigital.ufpr.br/bitstream/handle/1884/47314/R%20-%20D%20-%20FABRICIA%20ALMEIDA%20VIEIRA.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y
  • 1
    The Brazilian OLPR system adds together all the strongest incentives for legislators to cultivate a personal vote. Unlimited reelection is allowed, parties may launch a rather large numbers of candidates, candidate selection process takes place far from the central leadership and campaigns – including fund raising strategies – are run as individual enterprises. More important, regarding the ballot structure, the personal vote alone determines the place of each candidate on the party list.
  • 2
    In contrast, Brazilian anthropologists have advanced significantly in understanding the relations between legislators and their constituents ( Kuschnir, 2000aKUSCHNIR, K., (2000a). Eleições e representação no Rio de Janeiro. RelumeDumará/ Núcleo de Antropologia da Política da UFRJ. ; 2000bKUSCHNIR, K. (2000b). O cotidiano da política . Rio de Janeiro, Jorge Zahar. ; 2001; Lopez, 2004LOPEZ, F. G. (2004). “A política cotidiana dos vereadores e as relações entre Executivo e Legislativo em âmbito municipal: o caso do município de Araruama”. Revista de Sociologia e Política ,22: 153-177. Available at http://www.scielo.br/scieloOrg/php/clinicaltrials.php?pid=S0104-44782004000100012&lang=en, consulted in 11 January 2010.
    http://www.scielo.br/scieloOrg/php/clini...
    ; Santos, 2005SANTOS, M. M. (2005), Tribunos do povo, servos de Deus: um estudo antropológico sobre políticos e religião na cidade de Porto Alegre . Master dissertation. Porto Alegre, AntropolgyDepartment, Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul (UFRGS). ; Siqueira, 2009SIQUEIRA, R. A. S. (2009), “Mediações políticas: estudo do cotidiano de um vereador carioca”. Sociedade e Cultura , 12: 45-54. Available atredalyc.uaemex.mx/pdf/703/70312338006.pdf, consulted in 12 September 2010.
    atredalyc.uaemex.mx/pdf/703/70312338006....
    ; Garcez et al. , 2009GARCEZ, L. S.; MARTINS, M. & VIEIRA, P. S. (2009), “Conexão política em espaços urbanos: estudos etnográficos sobre atuações de parlamentares na cidade do Rio de Janeiro”. Ponto Urbe , 5. Available at http://www.pontourbe.net/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=17:conexao-politica-em-espacos-urbanos-estudos-etnograficos-sobre-atuacoes-de-parlamentares-na-cidade-do-rio-de-janeiro&catid=7:graduacao-em-campo&Itemid=12, consulted in 12 September 2010.
    http://www.pontourbe.net/index.php?optio...
    ).
  • 3
    The Deadlock of Democracy in Brazil (2005) was first published in 2001. The book is a collection of papers produced from the late 1980s onwards.
  • 4
    Despite considering the living standards, Ames (2005)AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. emphasises the importance of vote distribution and dominance.
  • 5
    Ames (2005)AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. , as well as the other authors mentioned in this section, looks at the national Chamber of Deputies, whose members´ formal constituencies are the state whole territory.
  • 6
    Carvalho (2003)CARVALHO, N. R. (2003), E no início eram as bases: geografia política do voto e comportamento legislativo no Brasil . Rio de Janeiro, Revan. uses his own indicators of dominance, distinct from Ames’ (2005)AMES, B. (2005), The deadlock of democracy in Brazil . Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press. .
  • 7
    Since 1995 each member of the National Congress has an individual quota of funds to reallocate through budget amendments ( Pereira and Mueller, 2004PEREIRA, C. & MUELLER, B. (2004), “The cost of governing: strategic behavior of the president and legislators in Brazil’s budgetary process”. Comparative Political Studies , 37 (781). Available at http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstract/37/7/781, consulted in 2 June 2009.
    http://cps.sagepub.com/cgi/content/abstr...
    ).
  • 8
    In fact, there are 159 rather than 140 neighbourhoods in Rio de Janeiro. However, not all of them have polling stations in their territory, which means that people are registered in nearby neighbourhoods. I decided to deal with this issue by joining together the neighbourhoods without any polling stations and the more similar contiguous neighbourhoods in terms of their living standards, measured as their score on the Human Development Index (HDI). For instance, the neighbourhood of Gardênia Azul, which does not have any polling station, is contiguous to Jacarepaguá, Freguesia, Cidade de Deus and Anil. Its HDI score in 2000 was 0.77 while Jacarepaguá’s was also 0.77 and Freguesia’s, Cidade de Deus’ and Anil’s were respectively 0.90, 0.75 and 0.91. Since Gardênia Azul and Jacarepaguá have the same HDI score, they have been joint together in the dataset and treated as one neighbourhood. The neighbourhoods without any polling stations and the neighbourhoods with which they were combined – in parenthesis – are the following: Complexo do Alemão (Ramos), Complexo da Maré (Bonsucesso), Engenheiro Leal (Cavalcanti), Gamboa (Centro), Gardênia Azul (Jacarepaguá), Grumari (Recreio dos Bandeirantes), Itahangá (Barra da Tijuca), Jacarezinho (Jacaré), Joá (Barra da Tijuca), Manguinhos (Bonsucesso), Parque Anchieta (Ricardo de Albuquerque), Parque Colúmbia (Acari), Pitangueiras (Cacuia), Praça da Bandeira (Tijuca), Praia da Bandeira (Cocotá), Rocinha (São Conrado), Sampaio (Jacaré), Senador Vasconcelos (Santíssimo) and Vasco da Gama (São Cristóvão).
  • 9
    Appendix 1 Appendix 1 Independent Variables – Binary Model IV Name Code Expected Effect on DV on Local Funds Expected Effect on DV on Non-Territorial South Zone, Centro & North Zone 01 if councillor concentrates 50% or more of the votes in the region. Reference group: councillors who do not concentrate most of the votes in any region (no prevalent region). No significant effect Suburbs 0 to 01 in IV leads to greater chance of DV ≠ 0 0 to 01 in IV leads to smaller chance of DV ≠ 0 Ilha do Governador Barra & Jacarepaguá West Zone Fresher 0 if councillor has less than two years in office. Reference group: councillors with two or more years in office. 0 to 01 in IV leads to smaller chance of DV ≠ 0 Fresher with relatives 0 if councillor is relative of a former councillor or has less than two years in office. Reference group: councillor with two or more years in office. No significant effect CFOFF 0 if councillor does not sit or has not sat on the committee. Reference group: councillor who sits or has sat on the committee. 0 to 01 in IV leads to greater chance of DV ≠ 0 Author´s elaboration explains the coding, measuring and expected effects of the independent variables on the dependent variables in the binary model.
  • 10
    Regarding Party Ideology, Kinzo (1993)KINZO, M. D. G. (1993), Radiografia do quadro partidário brasileiro . São Paulo, Fundação Konrad Adenauer-Stiftung. and Rodrigues (1995)RODRIGUES, L. M. (1995), “Eleições, fragmentação partidária e governabilidade”. NovosEstudosCebrap , 41: 78-90. arrive at fairly similar categorisations: left – PT, PDT, PSB,PSol, PCdoB; centre-left – PMDB, PPS, PV; centre-right – PHS, PL/PR, PMN, PRB, PRTB, PSC, PSDB, PSDC, PTB, PTC, PTdoB, PTR; right – PPB, PFL/Democratas, Prona.
  • 11
    It is not possible to perform the Vuong test, which indicatesthe more appropriate model – the Zinb or the standard negative binomial – using robust standard errors. Therefore I separately ran the nine models with standard errors, including the Vuong test. The scores, all significant at the 0.01 level, are between 3.45 and 3.48 for the non-territorial funds regressions and 2.48 and 3.39 for the local funds regressions. Thus numbers clearly favour the Zinb model.
  • 12
    The percentage change in the expected amount of funds reallocated is found using the formula 100*[ (expß) -1] ( Long, 1997LONG, J. S. (1997), Regression models for categorical and limited dependent variables. Thousand Oaks, CA. Sage. , p. 228; Hilbe, 2011HILBE, J. M. (2011), Negative binomial regression . Cambridge,Cambridge University Press. ). The same formula is applied to interpret the logit models.
  • 13
    The analysis of interaction terms coefficients in nonlinear models deserves extra caution. As Greene (2010)GREENE, W. (2010), “Testing hypotheses about interaction terms in nonlinear models”. Working paper. Available at http://w4.stern.nyu.edu/economics/docs/workingpapers/2009/Interaction-Terms-in-Nonlinear-Models.pdf, consulted in 24 August 2012.
    http://w4.stern.nyu.edu/economics/docs/w...
    warns us, the interpretation of the magnitude of the effect on the dependent variable based on the value of the coefficient may frequently be unreasonable and misleading. Instead, graphically representing the partial effect of the interaction term is more informative, which is how I proceed.
  • 14
    The Constitutional Amendment no86, promulgated on the 17th of March, 2015, made the implementation of the budget amendments sponsored by individual legislators mandatory ( Brasil, 2015BRASIL. (2015), Emenda Constitucional 86 de 17 de março de 2015. Available from http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/Constituicao/Emendas/Emc/emc86.htm, consulted in 12 August 2017.
    http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/Con...
    ).
  • 15
    Sidney Rezende (2009)REZENDE, S. (2009), “Sidney Rezende entevista o vereador Carlos Eduardo (PSB)”. YouTube [ on-line ]. Available at http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=97auw86xLw0, consulted in 21 December 2012.
    http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=97auw86xL...
    has also interviewed councillor Dr. Carlos Eduardo, in 2009. Dr. Carlos Eduardo, a physician, whose votes are fairly well distributed across the entire city, is a member of the government coalition. However, in stark contrast with Fernandes, during the whole ten-minute interview, he mentions no other topic than the city public health care system and its deficiencies, showing no special interest in any specific geographic area. The interview is available at http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=97auw86xLw0 , accessed in 21/12/2012.
  • 16
    In the presence of interaction, the main effects, such as those of vote distribution and living standards in Model IX, are no longer meaningful; instead, the interpretation should focus on the interaction terms ( Mitchell, 2012MITCHELL, M. (2012), Interpreting and visualizing regression models using stata . Stata Press, E-Book. , chapter 6).
  • 17
    In fact, the coefficient of Ilha do Governador does have a significant impact. However, the idea here is to verify whether or not the South Zone, Centro & North Zone does distinguish itself from the other regions regarding the budget amending process. Therefore, a comprehensive test of the hypothesis demands an interpretation of the five coefficients all together. Proceeding in such way, looking at the whole set of regional coefficients, all but one with no significant effect, we may infer that there is no significant difference among the distinct regions of the city.
  • 18
    Alternatively, I ran a separate binary component model testing the effect of party ideology , which turned out to be insignificant, as expected.
  • 19
    Alternatively, Miguel (2010)MIGUEL, L. F. (2010),“Accountability em listas abertas”. Revista de Sociologia e Política , 18 (37): 183-200 [ on-line ].Available at http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rsocp/v18n37/12.pdf, consulted in 18 March 2013.
    http://www.scielo.br/pdf/rsocp/v18n37/12...
    provides a positive view of the accountability in OLPR systems.
  • 20
    The table includes information on main office holders only.The city of Rio de Janeiro is divided into 97 electoral zones. The coefficients result from the correlation between each electoral zone in two consecutive elections in terms of their contribution to the individual councillor’s total vote. Thus, for instance, councillor A’s territorial distribution of vote in the 1996 election is correlated with councillor A’s territorial distribution of vote in the 2000 election, electoral zone by electoral zone.
  • 21
    Appendices 2 Appendix 2 Territorial Distribution of Votes in Two Consecutive Elections and 3 Appendix 3 Territorial Distribution of Votes in Two Consecutive Elections shows two examples of how the patterns of vote distribution in different elections almost perfectly correlate.
  • 22
    This is the case of former president of the Chamber of Deputies, Eduardo Cunha, who, during his 2014 campaign,seldom shook any hands out on the streets but much frequently made brief appearances in popular gathering carefully staged in evangelical churches and eminent civic organisations across many small towns ( Serodio, 2014)SERODIO, G. (2014), “O diabo tomou conta da política”. Valor Econômico [ on-line ]. Available at http://www.valor.com.br/eleicoes2014/3714044/o-diabo-tomou-conta-da-politica-diz-cunha, colsulted in 14 August 2017.
    http://www.valor.com.br/eleicoes2014/371...
    .
  • 23
    The distritão was voted down in the Chamber of Deputies in 2015 and 2017. Despite parliament´s decision to keep the system essentially unmodified, justices from the Supreme Court as well as the chiefs of the executive and of the legislative still insist in the need of radically changing the rules ( Galli, 2017GALLI, M. (2017), “José Serra e Eunício Oliveira defendem parlamentarismo e voto distrital misto”. Conjur , 26th October [online]. Available at https://www.conjur.com.br/2017-out-26/senadores-defendem-parlamentarismo-voto-distrital-misto, consulted in 11November 2017.
    https://www.conjur.com.br/2017-out-26/se...
    ; Noblat, 2017).
  • 24
    In fact, the Constitutional Amendment no 97, promulgated on the 4th of October 2017, establishes an electoral threshold for parties to access public funding and free radio and television time for their election campaigns, beginning at 1.5% in 2018 and reaching 3% from 2030 on. This same amendment bans electoral coalitions in legislative races, starting in the 2020 local election ( Brasil, 2017)BRASIL. (2017),Emenda Constitucional 97 de 4 de outubro de 2017.Available at http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/constituicao/emendas/emc/emc97.htm, consulted in12 August 2017.
    http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/con...
    .

Appendix 1 Independent Variables – Binary Model
IV Name Code Expected Effect on DV on Local Funds Expected Effect on DV on Non-Territorial
South Zone, Centro & North Zone 01 if councillor concentrates 50% or more of the votes in the region. Reference group: councillors who do not concentrate most of the votes in any region (no prevalent region). No significant effect
Suburbs 0 to 01 in IV leads to greater chance of DV ≠ 0 0 to 01 in IV leads to smaller chance of DV ≠ 0
Ilha do Governador
Barra & Jacarepaguá
West Zone
Fresher 0 if councillor has less than two years in office. Reference group: councillors with two or more years in office. 0 to 01 in IV leads to smaller chance of DV ≠ 0
Fresher with relatives 0 if councillor is relative of a former councillor or has less than two years in office. Reference group: councillor with two or more years in office. No significant effect
CFOFF 0 if councillor does not sit or has not sat on the committee. Reference group: councillor who sits or has sat on the committee. 0 to 01 in IV leads to greater chance of DV ≠ 0
  • Author´s elaboration
  • Appendix 2 Territorial Distribution of Votes in Two Consecutive Elections

    Appendix 3 Territorial Distribution of Votes in Two Consecutive Elections

    Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      17 Sept 2018
    • Date of issue
      2018

    History

    • Received
      27 Oct 2016
    • Accepted
      11 Oct 2017
    Associação Nacional de Pós-Graduação e Pesquisa em Ciências Sociais - ANPOCS Av. Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 315 - sala 116, 05508-900 São Paulo SP Brazil, Tel.: +55 11 3091-4664, Fax: +55 11 3091-5043 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
    E-mail: anpocs@anpocs.org.br