Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

An investigation on the role of institutions for income and growth models

Abstracts

This work evaluates the role of institutions on per capita income levels (cross-section) and growth models (panel data). The cross-section results suggest that there is some evidence regarding the role of institutions since all the estimated coefficients are positive and statistically significant but there is evidence of weak instruments. The results from the panel growth models suggest that there is scarce evidence for the role of institutions in fostering long-run growth. In one word, there is no indication of an empirical consensus to claim that institutions have a primary role, meaning that institutions cause growth and difference in income levels.

Per Capita Income and Growth Models; Institutions; Cross-Section and Panel Data Analysis


O presente trabalho examina o papel das instituições em modelos de renda per capita (corte transversal) e de crescimento (painel). Os resultados das estimações de corte transversal sugerem que há alguma evidência quanto ao papel das instituições dado que os coeficientes estimados são positivos e estatisticamente significativos, mas existem evidências de que os instrumentos utilizados são fracos. Os resultados para os modelos de crescimento sugerem que há poucas evidências quanto arelevância das instituições para estimular o crescimento. Sumarizando, não há indicação de um consenso empírico capaz de sustentar o argumento do papel primordial das instituições, ou seja, de que instituições causem crescimento ou diferenças nos níveis de renda.

Modelos de Crescimento e Renda Per Capita; Instituições; Análise de Corte Transversal e Painel


ARTIGOS

An investigation on the role of institutions for income and growth models

Flávio Vilela VieiraI; Aderbal Oliveira DamascenoII

IUniversidade Federal de Uberlândia. Email: flaviovieira@ufu.br

IIUniversidade Federal de Uberlândia. Email: damasceno@ie.ufu.br

ABSTRACT

This work evaluates the role of institutions on per capita income levels (cross-section) and growth models (panel data). The cross-section results suggest that there is some evidence regarding the role of institutions since all the estimated coefficients are positive and statistically significant but there is evidence of weak instruments. The results from the panel growth models suggest that there is scarce evidence for the role of institutions in fostering long-run growth. In one word, there is no indication of an empirical consensus to claim that institutions have a primary role, meaning that institutions cause growth and difference in income levels.

Keywords: Per Capita Income and Growth Models; Institutions; Cross-Section and Panel Data Analysis.

JEL classification: C33, O47, O43

RESUMO

O presente trabalho examina o papel das instituições em modelos de renda per capita (corte transversal) e de crescimento (painel). Os resultados das estimações de corte transversal sugerem que há alguma evidência quanto ao papel das instituições dado que os coeficientes estimados são positivos e estatisticamente significativos, mas existem evidências de que os instrumentos utilizados são fracos. Os resultados para os modelos de crescimento sugerem que há poucas evidências quanto arelevância das instituições para estimular o crescimento. Sumarizando, não há indicação de um consenso empírico capaz de sustentar o argumento do papel primordial das instituições, ou seja, de que instituições causem crescimento ou diferenças nos níveis de renda.

Keywords: Modelos de Crescimento e Renda Per Capita; Instituições; Análise de Corte Transversal e Painel.

1 Introduction

A wide variety of empirical studies on growth and per capita income levels using institutions as an explanatory variable have been developed during the last decade and there is some empirical evidence that the quality of institutions do matter but there is no consensus on what is called the institution rule hypothesis. In other words, once we incorporate institutions in our model, it is not clear if other factors such as geography, trade integration and policy variables will play only an indirect role on growth and differences in income levels.

This work evaluates the role of institutions on per capita income levels models and growth models for a set of almost one hundred countries, using cross-section and dynamic panel data analysis to answer two questions: Do Institutions have a primary role on explaining huge cross-country differences on per capita income levels? Does long-run growth performance relies mainly on institutional quality? The variable used as proxy for institutional quality is the Law and Order index for both models.

The results of the per capita income level models and the results of the growth models suggest that there is no indication of an empirical consensus to claim that institutions have a primary role, meaning that institutions cause difference in income levels and growth. One of the main novelties of the paper is to bring together both cross-section (income levels models using 2SLS estimation method) and panel data (growth models using System and Difference GMM estimation methods) analysis but most importantly to provide a deeper investigation regarding the use of instruments and see if they are valid and not weak and if there is no problem with instrument proliferation.

The paper provides two main contributions to the literature. First, the empirical analysis can be considered an advance on methodological grounds by developing a rigorous investigation on whether or not the instruments are valid, relevant and if there is instrument proliferation, which are crucial for parameter estimation and inference since institutions are endogenous to growth and development. The second contribution is related to the fact that once we consider the issue of excessive, valid and relevant instruments, the hypothesis that institutions cause differences in per capita income and in long-run growth is not corroborated by the empirical results, which questions a relative consensus on the literature.

The paper is organized in three sections other than this introduction and final remarks. Section two is devoted to summarize the empirical and theoretical literature on economic growth and differences in per capita income levels among countries with the inclusion of institutions and other control variables. Section three develops a cross-section analysis based on per capita income models and summarizes the results for the 2SLS estimation method. Section four develops a dynamic panel data analysis based on growth models and reports the results for System and Difference GMM estimation methods.

2 Institutions, Differences in Per Capita Income and Economic Growth: Theory and Evidence

Economic growth and differences in countries per capita income levels have been the focus of several research studies in the field of macroeconomics and also a topic of interest for policymakers, as well as in other areas of research, such as reduction of poverty and economic development. The literature of economic growth and differences on per capita income levels made significant progress on theoretical and empirical grounds during the last two decades. Most of this advance is due to new econometric techniques and longer database, incorporating lessons from the endogenous growth and human capital models and empirically the novelty has been on how to deal with the endogeneity problem and the use of valid instruments. The use of econometric techniques based on GMM estimation for dynamic panel data analysis for growth models and cross-section analysis with two stage least squares (2SLS) to test for differences in per capita income levels is part of this advance and both of them will be implemented in this paper1 1 A historical look on the growth literature reveals that during the 1950s and 1960s growth theory was linked primarily to the neoclassical model developed by Ramsey (1928), Solow (1956), Swan (1956), Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965). These models were based on the so-called convergence property and the idea is that economies with low per capita GDP will face higher growth rates given the assumption of diminishing capital returns. Since the 1980s, the concept of capital in the neoclassical model has been expanded to incorporate not only physical capital but also human capital, as seen through the models developed by Lucas (1988) and Rebelo (1991), among others. Romer (1994) highlights the dilemma encountered by the theoretical and empirical growth literatures and the contribution of endogenous growth theory to understand the long-term growth, arguing that the main contribution of this approach is to provide a theory of technological progress, one of the central elements absent from the neoclassical growth model. The inclusion of a theory of technological change in the neoclassical framework is difficult, since the conventional assumptions of competitiveness cannot be maintained. .

The empirical evidence from the growth and the cross country income levels difference literatures suggest a positive association with the quality of institutions meaning that better institutions foster long run economic growth and countries with better institutions are the ones with higher per capita income levels. Figure 2 illustrate such evidence for our complete set of 91 countries where the proxy for institution (Law & Order) shows a positive and statistically significant coefficient when plotted against the log of per capita GDP and the GDP growth rate. Regardless of such primary evidence it is necessary to investigate econometrically such relationship in both models using the adequate techniques such as GMM System and Difference for growth models and 2SLS for models of per capita income levels. It is fair to say that the positive coefficients reported in both graphs does not imply a specific causality from institutions to GDP growth and per capita GDP levels since we might face reverse causality in the sense that countries with higher income levels and growth rates can create a better institutional environment, which is likely to happen in most cases.

Initially, it is necessary to address the role of institution and its definition. North (1990) definition of institutions is associated to the idea that institutions are the rules of the game in a society and it imposes constraints that shape human interaction. Acemoglu & Robinson (2004) highlights the relevance of institutions for improving economic growth and development, arguing that:

Economic institutions are important because they influence the structure of economic incentives in society, and without property rights, individuals will not have the incentive to invest in physical or human capital or adopt more efficient technologies. Economic institutions are also important because they help to allocate resources to their most efficient uses, they determine who gets profits, revenues and residual rights of control.

Figure 1


On the empirical evolution of the growth literature and the contribution of geography, integration and institutions, Rodrik et al. (2004) argues that:

Growth theory has traditionally focused on physical and human capital accumulation, and, in its endogenous growth variant, on technological change. But accumulation and technological change are at best proximate causes of economic growth. (...)

But why did some societies manage to accumulate and innovate more rapidly than others? The three-fold classification offered above - geography, integration, and institutions - allow us to organize our thoughts on the "deeper" determinants of economic growth. These three are the factors that determine which societies will innovate and accumulate, and therefore develop, and which will not.

The following review of the literature will be divided into two sets. The first one deal with the empirical studies where the per capita GDP growth rate is the dependent variable, while the second one has the per capita GDP level as the dependent variable since it is concerned with differences in such levels across countries and not with their growth rates.

The evolution of the empirical growth literature using panel data goes back to the work developed by Barro et al. (1995) using data for more than one hundred countries from 1960 to 1990. The empirical results suggest that, for a given level of real per capita income, the growth rate is positively affected by the level of education and life expectancy, low fertility, lower government consumption, by maintaining the rule of law, lower inflation rate, improvement in the terms of trade, and negatively by the initial level of real per capita GDP. The inflation rate not only has a negative impact on real GDP growth in the long run, but also on the investment rate, but this result is statistically significant when the economies with a history of high inflation are included in the sample2 2 See Bruno & Easterly (1998) for additional evidence on inflation and growth. .

Acemoglu & Robinson (2004) develops the empirical and theoretical case where differences in economic institutions are the fundamental cause of differences in economic development since there are different ways of organizing societies in order to encourage innovation, to save for the future, to find better ways to improve knowledge and education, and to provide public goods.

Acemoglu et al. (2001) is a referential paper on addressing the endogeneity problem of using proxies for institutions when examining and evaluating difference in economic performance among countries. The paper uses differences in mortality rates as an instrument to estimate the effect of institutions on economic growth using 2SLS estimation, and the results are robust to different specifications, indicating the occurrence of significant effects of institutions on per capita income for a set of 64 countries. The main idea of the model is to estimate the coefficients associated to variables (indexes) of protection to the risk of expropriation as a proxy for institutions. The argument is that countries with better institutions, with more secure property rights, and policies with less distortion, tend to invest more in physical and human capital and usually have a more efficient use of such production factors in order to achieve a higher level of income. The authors make clear that when using the mortality rate as an instrument for institutions, this is valid only if other variables that are correlated with the mortality rate are not related to the per capita income. The idea is that the instrument for institutions (mortality rate) should be an important factor to capture the variation observed in the institutions, without having an effect on the growth rate.

Rodrik (1999) investigates the difference in growth rates for the periods 1960-75 and 1975-89 and the motivation of the study is to understand some issues and questions there are not a consensus in the growth literature such as: what are the crucial factors responsible for instability in the economic performance of developing countries; why countries that have a good economic performance in the 1960s and 1970s have had problems in the following decades; why some countries were strongly but shortly affected by external volatility in the second half of 1970 while others took a lot of time to recover from such external shocks; what are the main reasons underlying the process of expansion of the adverse effects of external shocks on the growth rate of many economies.

The hypothesis investigated by Rodrik (1999) is that domestic social conflicts are crucial to understand and answer the above questions as these conflicts have a negative impact on productivity, besides being related to cases involving the postponement of policies associated to fiscal and relative prices (real exchange rate and wages) adjustments. Another key aspect is the effect that such conflicts have on the uncertainty (investment decision) of the economy and the diversion of activities out of the production sector. The empirical analysis uses indicators of inequality, ethnic fragmentation, quality of government institutions, rule of law, democratic rights and social protection network to test RodriK's hypothesis. The results indicate that countries that had the greatest reduction in the rate of GDP growth in 1975 were those where society is more fragmented and has fragile institutions. The degree of severity of external shocks can be considered secondary in explaining the differences in growth rates between countries, and once controlling for social conflicts and institutional quality, other factors (trade policies, government consumption, ratio of debt / exports) have little explanatory power over such differences in growth rates, or are secondary factors when compared with the social conflict that ultimately is linked to the adoption of inadequate macroeconomic policies.

The second branch of the literature deals with empirical tests on the role of institutions and other factors in explaining why countries have such a huge difference in per capita income levels. Hall & Jones (1999) is one of the pioneers in examining the issue of why output per capita is so different across countries using a large set of countries. The main goal is to explain changes in long-run economic performance focusing directly in the investigation of cross-section analysis for income levels. One of the main empirical findings is that differences in capital accumulation, productivity and ultimately in per capita income is due to differences in institutions and government policies. The authors call this as social infrastructure and considered it as endogenous, which requires finding variables that are good instruments (location and language) in order to overcome problems such as coefficient bias in the presence of endogenous variables3 3 Studies such as Weil et al. (1992) was crucial in setting an empirical agenda to investigate differences in per capita income levels across countries based on differences in human and physical capital and productivity. . The authors emphasize that productivity is crucial to understand such differences in income levels. The goal is to answer two main questions: Why there is a significant difference in investments in physical and human capital? Why there is an important productivity difference across countries?

In order to answer these questions, Hall & Jones (1999) argue that long run economic performance of a country is primarily determined by social infrastructure, meaning that differences in capital accumulation, productivity and ultimately in per capita output are related to different levels of social infrastructure. Examining 127 countries the authors found a close and positive relation between per capita output and social infrastructure. After controlling for endogeneity of social infrastructure (institutions and government policies) they still find evidence that most of differences in long-run economic performance is due to differences in social infrastructure across countries. The estimated coefficient for output per capita and productivity is 0.60 and the correlation between the differences for the two series in log is 0.89. Most of the differences in output per capita are due to productivity by a factor of 8.3 against human capital with 2.2 and capital intensity with 1.8 when comparing the five highest and lowest countries in terms of output per capita, which are different by more than 30 times for this set of countries.

The estimation of the social infrastructure index (SI) by Hall & Jones (1999) uses a combination of two indexes to construct the proxy for SI. One is the index of government antidiversion policies (GADP) based on data from the Political Risk Service (130 countries and 24 categories) and the authors select five categories: law and order; bureaucracy quality; corruption; risk of expropriation and government repudiation of contracts, each of them as average for the period of 1986-95. The second index tries to capture the degree of openness to trade and it draws from the data developed by Sachs & Warner (1995) and it varies from 0 to 1 according to criteria such as: level of nontariff barriers; average tariff rates; black market premium; country classified as non-socialist; and absence of government as a monopolist for major exports. The final proxy for SI is given by the sum of GADP and the openness index and the instruments used captures geography characteristics (distance from the equator), the Western European influence (primary spoken language) and the (log) predicted trade share of the economy constructed by Frankel & Romer (1999). The estimated model for output per capita shows that the estimated coefficient for social infrastructure is positive (for the main specification

SI = 5.14 with four instruments) and statistically significant for all specifications. The authors conclude after some robustness tests that taking into account elements such as geography (distance from the equator) and Western influence (language), differences in social infrastructure determines (cause) large differences in per capita income across countries.

Other works such as the one developed by Easterly & Levine (2003) is focused on understanding differences in per capita income across countries. They develop an analysis first reviewing the empirical literature / theories of how geography, institutions, and policy influence economic development and so the disparity in income levels. The geography / endowment hypothesis argues that environment has a direct impact on the quality of land, labor, and production technologies, while the institution view is based on the idea that the environment's main impact on economic development operates through institutions. The policy view tries to minimize the relevance of tropics, germs, and crops as a fundamental determinant of differences in economic development and income level by arguing that economic policies and institutions are a result of current knowledge and political forces. Within this perspective, to change income levels it is necessary to understand each country policies and institutions. Ultimately, the authors seek to empirically address which of these three views / theories are more adequate to explain differences in income levels across countries4 4 The geography/endowment hypothesis is associated to different studies such as Sachs & Warner (1995), Sachs & Warner (1997), Bloom & Sachs (1998) and O'Neill (2001), arguing for the presence of direct effects of tropics, germs, and crops on development. The institutions hypothesis relates the effect of tropics, germs, and crops through institutions and can be associated to works such as Hall & Jones (1999) who uses institutional quality as one component of social infrastructure which is crucial to explain differences in productivity, allowing for the use of instruments such as distance from the equator and European language. Acemoglu et al. (2001) is another example of the institution view with a germs theory of institution by using settler's mortality as an instrument for institutions. The policy view argues in favor of sound macroeconomic policies, openness to international trade, and the absence of capital account controls considered as important measures to foster economic growth and to increase per capita income. Tropics, germs, and crops may influence production technologies and institutions but to improve economic development it is necessary to change policies targeting low inflation, increase in trade and financial integration to the world. One example of this view is Frankel & Romer (1999) to whom geography matters for economic development through government policy (trade openness). .

Easterly & Levine (2003) uses settler mortality as an indicator of endowments to test the geography and the institutions hypotheses and other control variables such as: latitude, dummies for crops / minerals, landlocked, a measure for openness (Frankel & Romer 1999), real exchange rate overvaluation and inflation to address the policy view, and six indexes for quality of institutions draw from Kaufmann et al. (2008) to capture the relevance of institutions in a per capita income model. The authors also use other control variables such as ethno linguistic diversity, religion and French legal origin.

The initial step was to estimate a model for a sample of 72 countries by OLS with heteroskedasticity consistent standard errors for the log of the per capita GDP on the endowment variables and the results indicate that endowments explain cross-country variation in per capita income. The next step was to run an OLS model and check if endowments help to explain cross-country differences in institutional development and the results indicate that variables like settler mortality and natural resources (germs and crops) are the dominant forces to understand institutional development. Up to this point the Easterly & Levine (2003) have found evidence that endowments have an impact on economic and institutional development. Following this result, the authors estimate a 2SLS model for the log of per capita GDP using four instruments (settler mortality, latitude, landlocked and crops/minerals) in the first stage estimation, and institutions index, French legal origin, religion, ethno linguistic diversity and oil as exogenous variables in the second stage estimation. The estimated coefficients for the institution indexes are all positive and statistically significant and the overidentification tests were not rejected indicating that the set of instruments are valid. The final estimated model treats macroeconomic policy variables (inflation, openness and real exchange rate overvaluation) as endogenous using 2SLS and the evidence suggests that such policies do not explain differences in per capita income after taking into account the impact of institutions on income levels. The estimated coefficients for the institution index are all positive and statistically significant.

The empirical evidence found by Easterly & Levine (2003) suggests that endowments (tropics, germs, and crops) have an impact on per capita income through institutions but not a direct effect, which is a support for the institution view but not for the geography one. The same is true for what they call policies variables which has no impact on development when controlling for institutions, in other words, institutions rule differences in per capita income levels across countries. Such empirical results are hand to hand with the work of Acemoglu et al. (2001).

Acemoglu & Robinson (2004) review what is called the geography hypothesis as an alternative to explain difference in economic performance among countries and the main idea is to focus on the role of physical and geographical environment. This approach emphasizes differences in geography, climate and ecology as fundamental in understanding how preferences and the opportunity set of individual economic agents in different societies. The geography hypothesis can be divided into three versions. The first one highlights how climate may be an important factor of work effort, incentives, or productivity. The second one argues that geography may determine the technology available to a society, especially in agriculture, while the last one is based on the idea that infectious disease is costly and more likely to happen in the tropics than in the temperate zones, which can mitigate economic performance over time (Sachs 2000).

One can say that there is a clear disagreement among the role played by geography in explaining differences in per capita income levels. Sachs (2003) is an example of studies that do not agree with others such as Acemoglu et al. (2001), Easterly & Levine (2003) and Rodrik et al. (2004) on the proposition that the role of geography in explaining cross-country differences in per income is secondary and operates mainly through institutions. According to the author per capita income, economic growth, and other economic and demographic dimensions are strongly correlated with variables associated to geography and ecology, including climate zone, disease ecology, and distance from the coast. The variable used to corroborate his argument is malaria transmission, which is strongly affected by ecological conditions and has a direct impact on per capita income once controlling for institutions quality.

Rodrik et al. (2004) empirically investigates the contribution of institutions, geography and trade in explaining differences in per capita income across countries and the evidence suggests the predominance of institutions over geography and trade using different instruments. The authors argue that integration to the world economy and the quality of institutions should be treated as endogenous since they affect each other and are affected by geographical variables and by income levels. Dealing with this means to take into account endogeneity and reverse causality issues in estimating a cross country income model.

The main empirical evidence found by Rodrik et al. (2004) is that once institutions are part of the regression (2SLS), integration has no direct effect on per capita income, while geography measures have at best only weak direct effects even though they are important to understand the quality of institutions. Trade does not reveal to be statistically significant once institutions are controlled for and it seems to have an unexpected negative sign. The estimated coefficients for the measure of property rights and the rule of law are positive and statistically significant. The authors also found similar evidence to Easterly & Levine (2003) that geography has a significant impact on the quality of institutions and this is the channel through which it affects income levels. In the preferred model specification (settler mortality as instrument for institutions quality) developed by Rodrik et al. (2004) it was possible to account for half of the variance in cross country incomes and trade and distance from the equator are not statistically significant. Comparing the estimated coefficients (table 2 and OLS) for institutions (rule of law), geography (distance from the equator) and integration (log of trade to GDP) after they have been standardized in order to be comparable, the results for the log of GDP per capita reveals that the coefficient for institutions is positive and statistically significant and greater than the coefficient for geography (positive and significant), which is greater than the estimated coefficient for integration (positive but not significant). The 2SLS estimation reported on table 3 reveals on the preferred specification (column 6) that the coefficient for institutions is positive (1.98) and statistically significant, while the coefficients for geography (-0.72) and integration (-0.31) are not significant and the latter has an unexpected sign.

The main criticism stated by Sachs (2003) with respect to the institutions rule argument is that there are specification problems in the model and how they test the primacy of institutions. The first specification problem is associated to the use of a static rather than a dynamic model for per capita income and the author argues that it is more likely that the quality of institutions in a given time period will affect the growth rate and not the income level but the three mentioned studies are concerned in explaining differences in per capita income and not in growth rates across countries. Other than this, Sachs (2003) argues that differences in income levels should not be explained by only a few variables excluding geography and the choice made by studies such as Rodrik et al. (2004) in using distance from the equator is not adequate. Sachs (2003) uses three instruments to estimate a 2SLS model of the log of GNP per capita adjusted to PPP: KGPTEMP is a measure of the share of a country population in temperate ecozones; LOGMORT is an estimate of mortality rates of British soldiers and other populations in the early 19th century; and ME is a measure of malaria risk. For all the regressions quality of institutions and malaria risk are statistically significant.

Regarding the use of indexes of institutional quality based on surveys of foreign and domestic investors (Rule of Law, Corruption, Investment Profile and Bureaucracy) Rodrik et al. (2004) states that such indexes are able to capture investor's perceptions but not exactly which are the rules governing these institutions, which is a limitation and future research on growth disparities will have to deal with this. It is also necessary to distinguish between stimulating and sustaining economic growth and better and more reliable institutions are more important for the latter than to the former meaning that developing countries can boost initial growth with some minor changes in their institutional environment.

3 Institutions and GDP per capita Level: Empirical Evidence

This section summarizes methodological aspects of using the two stages least square (2SLS) estimation method for models of cross country income differences and reports the estimation results on tables 1 and 2.

3.1 Empirical Methodology

This section of the paper has two goals. First, specify the 2SLS estimation procedures since it is widely used in the cross section models of differences in per capita income across countries. Second, compare the estimated coefficients for different sets of countries using institutions, geography, integration and instrumental variables.

The cross section empirical studies on per capita income differences across countries are almost always based on the use of 2SLS estimation since this is the core instrument when dealing with endogeneity problems as it happens with the inclusion of institutions in this kind of model.

Considering the following model for a dependent variable (y) on a single regressor (x):

Assuming that the regressor (x) is endogenous, the OLS estimation is not valid since it violates the assumption required for consistency that the error term (u) is not correlated to the regressors (Cov(x,u) = 0) and the instrumental variable (IV) approach deals with this by selecting new variables (z) that are highly correlated to the regressors (Cov(z,x) ≠ 0) but not with the error term (Cov(z,u) = 0).

The 2SLS estimation is based on a two stage procedure where the first implements an OLS estimation of the endogenous variable (proxy for institutions) as the dependent variable as a function of exogenous variables and the new set of instruments (z) and this is called the reduced form equation. The second stage is the OLS regression of the dependent variable of the original model (log of per capita GDP) on the exogenous variables and the replacement of endogenous regressors by predictions from the first stage. One advantage of the 2SLS estimation is that in the presence of independent and homocedastic errors it is the most efficient estimator but since this is not an easy assumption, we use the correction for heteroskedasticity in our estimates (tables 1 and 1).5 5 Another possibility is to use the optimal GMM estimator (OGMM) with the heteroskedasticity correction, which is based on a weighting matrix that it different from the one used by 2SLS estimation. One of the problems associated to 2SLS estimation is how to avoid the use of weak instruments since they will result in less precise coefficients due to high standard errors (lower t-statistics) and the occurrence of finite sample bias (the IV estimator is not centered on the true populational coefficient). See Cameron & Trivedi (2008) chapter 6 for further details on 2SLM and OGMM. The paper uses overidentification tests with the estat overid command for Stata 10.0 and the estat firststage command to evaluate the presence of weak instruments (F-stat of first stage). Table A.4 of the appendix reports additional estimation such as the OGMM for the cross-section models in order to have a broader range of coefficient estimates and to compare them with the 2SLS.

3.2 Empirical Results

First of all, it should be emphasized that the set of instruments used in the 2SLS estimation when dealing with endogeneity of institutions (Law) is SettlerMort, Legoruk, EnglishLang, and EuropeLang, where for integration (Trade) we use the index developed by Frankel & Romer (1999) to capture perceived integration.6 6 Law is a variable based on two components, the first one (Law) is an assessment of the strength and impartiality of the legal system while the second (Order) is an assessment of popular observance of the law. In order to obtain the instrument for Law we follow three basic approaches. The first one uses variables that capture the influence of Western Europe across countries and it is based on the argument that a higher influence is associated to a more developed institutional environment. According to this approach, the variables used as instruments are the fraction of the population of each country speaking English, denominated as EnglishLang, and the fraction of the population speaking one the major languages of Western Europe (English, French, German, Portuguese, or Spanish), denominated as EuropeLang (Hall & Jones 1999). The second approach uses variables that distinguish countries regarding the origin of the legal system and are based on the argument that the British legal system (English Common Law) is associated to a higher degree of institutional development. In order to do this, the variable LegorUK is a dummy assuming the value 1 for countries where the origin of the legal system is British and zero otherwise ((La Porta et al. 1999),(La Porta et al. 2008)). The third one uses variables that captures the conditions faced by the settlers in the ex-colonies and is based on the argument that where they faced the most adverse conditions for settlement, the worst institutions were introduced and they persisted over time. In order to do this the variable used as instrument is the mortality rate faced by the settlers in the ex-colonies, denominated as SettlerMort (Acemoglu et al. 2001). For a complete list of variables and a more detailed definition see appendix table A.1.

The estimation of the cross-section models of per capita GDP levels for the complete sample (91 countries) using 2SLS is reported on table 1. The 2SLS estimated models (columns 5, 6, 7 and 8) show that the coefficients for institutions (Law) are positive and statistically significant in all four models. It is necessary to interpret this result with some caution since models (5) and (6) that are over-identified have overidentification tests that reject the null at 5%, and so the instruments are not valid. Comparing the 2SLS and the OLS coefficients for Law one can see that the 2SLS estimation provides higher estimates. Geography (Latitude) has a negative (unexpected) coefficient for models (6) and (7) but in both cases it is not statistically significant while in model (8) it has a positive and significant coefficient. Trade (integration) is not statistically significant in the two 2SLS estimation (7 and 8) regardless if it is considered as exogenous (7) or treated as endogenous (8) and instrumented by FrankelRomer index of perceived trade openness.

The next step is to estimate the same models from table 1 but now for a restricted sample which includes countries in our sample with data for Settler Mortality, which is the instrumental variable used by Acemoglu et al. (2001). The only difference is that on table 2, settler mortality was used as an instrument while in table 1 it was not.

The 2SLS estimated models from table 2 (columns 5, 6, 7 and 8) show that the coefficients for institutions (Law) are positive and statistically significant in all four models. In the same way when we present the results from table 1, it is necessary to interpret this result with some caution since models(5),(6) and(7) that are over-identified have overidentification tests that reject the null at 5% and so the set of instruments are not valid. Geography (Latitude) is not statistically significant in any of the three models using 2SLS and it has an unexpected negative sign in models 6 and 7. Trade (integration) is not statistically significant in the two 2SLS estimation (7 and 8) regardless if it is considered as exogenous(7) or treated as endogenous(8) and instrumented by the index constructed by Frankel & Romer (1999).7 7 Examining the results from table 4A of the appendix for a comparison of different estimation methods we can see that there is a significant variation on the estimated coefficients when using the Jacknife IV (JIVE) and the LIML estimators that are asymptotically equivalent to 2SLS but may have better finite sample properties than 2SLS. The estimated coefficients for 2SLS and OGMM are much more similar for both complete and restricted samples.

After the cross-section estimation reported on tables 1 and 2 the paper develops an empirical investigation on the issue of weak instruments based on a set of tests reported in table 3.8 8 See table 3A of the appendix for the correlation analysis of Law and the instruments for the complete and restricted sample. The correlation coefficients are high and vary from 0.2 to 0.51. Stock & Yogo (2005) developed two tests for weak instruments and following Cameron & Trivedi (2008) we implement these tests for the cross-section analysis. Basically the tests have a null hypothesis that the instruments are weak against the alternative that they are strong and the idea is to look at the Robust F statistics for joint significance of instruments in the first-stage regression and the minimum eigenvalue statstics and compare these with the critical values from from Stock & Yogo (2005) tables. A rule of thumb for the F statistics is that if it is greater than 10 we can say that it is possible to reject the null of weak instruments.

Examining table 3 we can see that the Robust F statistics do not reject the null for models (5), (6) and (7) for the complete and restricted sample when Law is the instrumented variable so there is evidence of weak instruments, except for model (8) in both samples when Trade is included as endogenous variable in the model. Once we look at the minimum eigenvalue statistics there is evidence of weak instruments for all models except when Trade is treated as endogenous, model (8) in both samples.

Summarizing the results for the cross-country differences in per capita income levels it is fair to say that there are some mixed evidences regarding the role of institutions (Law) since all the estimated coefficients are positive and statistically significant but there is evidence that theinstruments are not valid and even if they are we do have weak instruments for the most estimated models.Integration (Trade) and Geography (Latitude) do not seem to play a direct and significant role on explaining differences in per capita income levels across countries when modeling institutional variables (Law) as endogenous or even when integration (Trade) is considered endogenous.

4 Institutions and GDP per capita Growth: Empirical Evidence

This section of the paper presents some methodological issues on panel data estimation for long run growth models and the use of the generalized method of moments (GMM) reporting on table 4 and 5 the estimated coefficients for the complete sample and for developing countries.

4.1 Empirical Methodology

This section of the study aims to specify the methodology of panel data analysis using GMM estimation to be used in the econometric analysis, specifying the growth models to be estimated, the number of countries in the sample and the explanatory variables.

The study uses a dynamic panel data model specification and the motivation for the use of this methodology is the possibility to take into account the following: (i) the time series dimension of the data, (ii) non observable country specific effects; (iii) inclusion of lagged dependent variable among the explanatory variables, and (iv) the possibility that all explanatory variables are endogenous.

The standard approach on panel data starts with the assumption that the growth rate path is consistent with the following procedure:

where y is the natural log of per capita real GDP, X represents the set of explanatory variables, η is a non-observable and country specific term, εis a random term and the subscripts i and t refers to country and time, respectively9 9 The model specification includes a term that varies over time and is constant across countries, and such term is not reported in the following equations just to simplify the presentation. This time-specific term is part of all regressions estimated by including the time Dummies variables for each period (five year average) of the sample. .

It should be noted that the time specific effect allows to control the international conditions that change over time and ultimately affect the growth performance of countries in the sample, while the non observable country specific effect (η) incorporates factors that influence the growth of per capita GDP and are potentially correlated with the explanatory variables.What characterizes the dynamic relationship is the presence of lagged dependent variable as one of the explanatory variables, which is evident once we rewrite equation (2) as:

The elimination of the country specific and the non observable term (η) is obtained once we apply first difference to equation (3):

The use of instruments is required to deal with the possible endogeneity of the explanatory variables and the correlation between the new term of error, εi,t - εi,t-1, and the lagged dependent variable, yi, t-1 - yi, t-2. Under the assumptions that the error term (ε) is not serially correlated and the explanatory variables (X) are weakly exogenous, lagged values of the explanatory variables can be used as instruments, as specified under the following moment conditions:

The GMM estimator based on the moment conditions (5) and (6) is called Difference GMM and we call this GMM-DIFF throughout the paper. There are statistical problems associated with the use of GMM-DIFF: statistically, when the regressors in equation (4) are persistent, lagged levels of X and y are weak instruments. The use of weak instruments asymptotically implies that the variance of the coefficient increases and in small samples the coefficients can be bias. To reduce the potential bias and inaccuracy associated with the use of DIFF-GMM estimator, Arellano & Bover (1995) and Blundell & Bond (1998) develop a system of regressions in differences and levels. The instruments for the regression in differences are the lagged levels of the explanatory variables, moment conditions (5) and (6). The instruments for the regression in levels are the lagged differences of explanatory variables. These are appropriate instruments under an additional assumption, that is, although there may be correlation between the levels of explanatory variables and the country specific effect (η) in equation (3), there is no correlation between those variables in differences and the country specific effect (η). This can be represented as:

and

The moment conditions for the regression in levels, which is the second part of the system, are:

The GMM estimator based on the moment conditions (5), (6), (8) and (9) is called System GMM or GMM-SYST throughout the paper. The consistency of the GMM estimator depends on the validity of the moment conditions. To such extent it will be considered two specification tests based on Arellano & Bond (1991), and Arellano & Bover (1995) and Blundell & Bond (1998):(i) Hansen test is a test of overidentifying restrictions and the joint null hypothesis is that the instruments are valid, i.e., uncorrelated with the error term, and that the excluded instruments are correctly excluded from the estimated equation; (ii) and the Arellano-Bond test which tests the hypothesis of no second order serial correlation in the error term.

Recently, studies such as Roodman (2009a) and Roodman (2009b), develop a detailed analysis on instrument proliferation when using Difference GMM and System GMM. The author discusses the symptoms of instrument proliferation showing that as the time dimension increases, the number of instruments can be too large compared to the sample size and the outcome is that some asymptotic results and specification tests are not valid. Too many instruments can over fit endogenous variables and fail to expunge their endogenous components, resulting in biased coefficients. Another argument is that the Hansen and Difference-in-Hansen tests can be weak when using the Difference GMM and System GMM in the presence of overidentification.

In order to deal with too many instruments, Roodman (2009a) suggest the use of the collapse suboption for the xtabond2 command in Stata. The author develops an analysis on the existence of two techniques to limit the number of instruments generated in difference and system GMM. The first one is based on the idea of using only certain lags instead of all available lags for instruments and in this case the number of instruments per period is limited in such a way that it is linear in T. The use of the Collapse suboption is part of the second approach to reduce the number of instruments and it is the one recommended by the author. The main idea is to combine instruments through addition into smaller sets, without dropping any lags as the first technique does. The Collapse suboption implies the creation of one instrument for each variable and lag distance, rather than one for each time period, variable, and lag distance, where the final outcome is to divide the GMM-style moment conditions into groups and sums the conditions in each group to form a smaller set of conditions. At the end, we have a set of collapsed instruments where one is made for each lag distance, with zero substituted for any missing values and making the number of instruments linear in T.10 10 A more detailed presentation including matrix notation can be found in Roodman (2009a), p.148-149. See also Baltagi (2008) for further empirical examples using the collapse command.

The panel data model is estimated for the complete sample (91 countries) and for developing countries over the period 1980-2004. The data used are transformed and are based on averages for non-overlapping periods of five years (1980-1984, 1985-1989, 1990-1994, 1995-1999, 2000-2004), so that there are five data entries for each country for each variable in the sample. The reason for using five year average data is to minimize the business cyclical effects and the error term to be less likely to face autocorrelation problems (see ). There is no data for all countries, time and variables, so the estimated panel is an unbalanced one. The variables used in the econometric estimation are reported on table A.1 of the appendix, where the variables were in the logarithmic form except for the time dummies and the indexes of institution quality.

4.2 Empirical Results

The analysis of table 4 reveals that the coefficient for institution (Law) is positive in for all models and statistically significant only when using the GMM-SYST for the complete sample in a more parsimonious specification (without Credit, Pop and TermsTrade) and this result stands in three out of four (5, 6 and 8) estimation models for developing countries11 11 The results for the AR(2), Hansen and Hansen Diff tests indicate that we are able to reject the null hypothesis meaning that there is no second order autocorrelation and the instruments are valid, with only one exception for the Hansen Diff test in model specification (1) using System-GMM. . The results also suggest that Gov (government consumption) has a negative and statistically significant coefficient in all estimated models, suggesting a robust role played by such policy variable, meaning that countries with more fiscal discipline benefit over time in terms of fostering economic growth12 12 Sala-I-Martin & X. (1990) develops a theoretical and empirical investigation on the contribution of government spending to growth considering not only government consumption, as we have done in our paper, but also government investment (infrastructure) suggesting a possibility that government investment can foster economic growth. .

Some minor evidence of significance was found for Educ only for model(2) using GMM-SYST, for Credit in models (4) and (8) using GMM-DIFF but only at 10% and for Pop in model (2) using the GMM-SYST. The estimated coefficients for the integration to the world economy (Trade), macroeconomic stability (Inf) and Terms of Trade were not statistically significant in any model specification13 13 Conditional convergence (negative coefficient for Yinitial) is observed for all estimated models except for model (5) and most coefficients are statistically significant except for models (1) and (5). .

After all one can say that the empirical result for the long-run per capita GDP growth models suggest that there are mixed evidence for the role of institutions (Law) in fostering economic growth and the GMM-SYST is the one that is more likely to capture such role and the quality of institutions seems to be more relevant for developing countries. Another lesson to be draw from the estimated growth models is that fiscal discipline (policy variable), measured by government consumption / GDP, plays a crucial role in stimulating long-run growth.

Recent work such as Roodman (2009a) and Roodman (2009b) and Bazzi & Clements (2009) emphasize the need for a deeper investigation on weak instruments for cross-section and instrument proliferation for panel data analysis. Since for one model (1) the overidentification tests from table 4 suggest the existence of poor instruments and given the use of a significant number of instruments, especially for the System GMM, we have estimated the same model using a reduced number of instruments (collapse command in Stata) and the results are reported on table 5.

Comparing the results with fewer instruments (table 5) with the ones from table 4 one can see that for the complete sample (columns 1, 2 3 and 4) institutions (Law) has a positive and significant coefficient in model (4) and only at 10%, which is different from previous estimation when System-GMM was more likely to capture such role for institutions in the complete sample and developing countries were more likely to face significant estimated coefficients. Government spending and population growth have significant coefficients for the System GMM estimation using the complete sample, while for the Difference GMM model (4), years of schooling (Educ) and credit are significant but with unexpected signs. For developing countries (columns 5 to 8) government spending is the only variable with significant coefficient for all models and population growth for System GMM. There is no significant coefficient for institutions (Law) regardless of the estimation method or model specification which is a contrasting result with the one from previous estimation where in three out of four models for developing countries Law has a positive and significant coefficient. Such results can be seen as additional empirical evidence that there is no empirical support for the argument that institutions rule, especially if the research deals more carefully with instruments proliferation.

At the end, the results from the growth model estimation with and without limiting the number of instruments do not allow us to argue in favor of institutions causing growth or having a primary role when compared to other control variables.

5 Concluding Remarks

This paper aims to answer two theoretical and empirical questions. First, institutions have a primary role on explaining huge cross-country differences on per capita income levels when compared to other control variables such as integration and geography? Second, does long-run growth performance relies mainly on quality of institutions?

Considering the results for the cross-country differences in per capita income levels there are some mixed evidence regarding the role of institutions (Law) since all the estimated coefficients are positive and statistically significant but the set of instruments is not valid. Integration (Trade) and Geography (Latitude) do not seem to play a direct and significant role on explaining differences in per capita income levels across countries. The results from the per capita GDP growth models suggest that there are mixed evidence for the role of institutions (Law) in fostering long-run economic growth and the GMM-STST is the one that is more likely to capture such role and developing countries are the ones where such role is more relevant. The estimated growth models when dealing with instrument proliferation have shown that it is even harder to corroborate the argument that institutions rule.

The paper provides two main contributions to the literature. First, the empirical analysis can be considered an advance on methodological grounds by developing a rigorous investigation on whether or not the instruments are valid, relevant and if there is instrument proliferation, which are crucial for parameter estimation and inference since institutions are endogenous to growth and development. The second contribution is related to the fact that once we consider the issue of excessive, relevant and valid instruments, the hypothesis that institutions cause differences in per capita income and in long-run growth is not corroborated by the empirical results, which questions a relative consensus on the literature.

Even though good institutions are associated to high levels of per capita GDP and higher long-run growth rates the empirical evidence presented here do not allow one to state that there is conclusive evidence that institutions have a primary role on the explanation of cross-country per capita income differences nor we can say that long-run per capita growth relies mainly on the quality of institutions (Law).

Regarding the role of institutions one can say that more frequently than not, they are somehow specific to each economy and society and the ones that perform well in one setting may not be adequate in a different environment depending on complementary institutions and norms. One example is the comparison of institutions for Russia and China as pointed out by (Rodrik et al. (2004), Rodrik (2008)) where the later does not have a western type of institution regarded as more adequate to foster economic growth and increase income levels but it has found specific ways to stimulate and attract an enormous amount of investments and the establishment of domestic contracts that ultimately seems to be quite effective in improving growth and income.

There is an extensive list of empirical studies on income levels and growth models trying to address the issue of endogeneity problems, reverse causality and their pitfalls, together with an attempt to separate the interpretation of what is really important in explaining differences in income levels and growth rates across countries and what roles the set of instruments play in this interpretation. Rodrik et al. (2004) argue that it is crucial to make a distinction between using an instrument and developing a theory of cause and effect, which according to the authors is not clear in studies such as Acemoglu et al. (2001) and Easterly & Levine (2003). Instruments should be viewed simply as having some desirable statistical properties and not as having a large part of the causal story.

There are some crucial aspects such as providing security of property rights, the enforcement of contracts, increase integration to the international market, macroeconomic stability and a process of building better voice and accountability, but the pace and paths to achieve such elements are different for each country, especially when comparing developing and developed countries. That is what Rodrik (2008) call as appropriate institutions since each country has distinct economic and social constraints when they implement institutions reforms.

Recent empirical studies on growth and income levels such as Bazzi & Clements (2009) have emphasized the need for caution and further investigation on the use of weak instruments (cross-section analysis) and instruments proliferation (panel data analysis) especially for System GMM estimation and the results comparing different data sets and using distinct econometric techniques have shown that there is clear evidence of weak instruments and excessive number of instruments in most previous empirical work on income levels and growth models. Our empirical results corroborate these recent empirical findings. Glaeser et al. (2004) is another example of studies examining the robustness of using three sets of data as proxies for institutional quality and they stress different sources of problems with these data and they consider such indicators to be conceptually unsuitable for the empirical investigation of the proposition that institutions cause growth. This line of argument sheds light to the need of improving data collection and their use in growth and cross-section per capita income models.

Our empirical results have not been able to corroborate the idea that institutional quality can be considered as cause of differences in per capita income among countries since our overidentification tests do not allow one to distinguish between such institutions been a result of economic prosperity or their cause. Future empirical research on cross country income levels and growth models should be focused on the choice of instruments and the construction of better indexes for institutions that are able to capture some specificities of each country in terms of different chains / environment through which institutions might work in terms of stimulating income levels and growth.

Bibliography

Recebido em 8 de maio de 2010.

Aceito em 16 de agosto de 2011.

Appendix A

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. & Robinson, J. A. (2001), 'The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation', The American Economic Review 91(5), 13691401.
  • Acemoglu, S. J. & Robinson, J. A. (2004), Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth, in P. A. Durlauf & S., eds, 'Handbook of Economic Growth', Vol. 1, North Holland.
  • Arellano, M. & Bond, S. (1991), 'Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte CarloEvidence and an Application to Employment Equations', Review of Economic Studies 58(2), 277297.
  • Arellano, M. & Bover, O. (1995), 'Another Look at the Instrumental-Variable Estimation of Error-Components Models', Journal of Econometrics 68(1), 2951.
  • Baltagi, B. H. (2008), Econometric Analysis of Panel Data, 4 edn, John Wiley AND Sons Ltd, Chichester.
  • Barro, R. J., Mankiw, N. G. & Sala-I-Martin, X. (1995), 'Capital mobility in neoclassical models of growth', The American Economic Review 85(1), 103115.
  • Bazzi, S. & Clements, M. (2009), 'Blunt Instruments: On Establishing the Causes of Economic Growth', Center for Global Development. Working Paper nş 171.
  • Bloom, D. & Sachs, J. (1998), 'Geography, demography, and economic growth in Africa', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1998(2), 207273.
  • Blundell, R. & Bond, S. (1998), 'Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models', Journal of Econometrics 87(1), 115143.
  • Bruno, M. & Easterly, W. (1998), 'Inflation crises and long-run growth', Journal of Monetary Economics 41, 326.
  • Cameron, A. C. & Trivedi, P. K. (2008), Microeconometrics Using Stata, 1 edn, Stata Press, Texas.
  • Cass, D. (1965), 'Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation', Review of Economic Studies 32(3), 233240.
  • Easterly, W. & Levine, R. (2003), 'Tropics, germs, and crops: how endowments influence economic development', Journal of Monetary Economics 50(1), 339.
  • Frankel, J. & Romer, D. (1999), 'Does trade cause growth?', American Economic Review 89(3), 379399.
  • Glaeser, E., R., L.-P. & Lopes-De-Silanes, F. (2004), 'Do Institutions Cause Growth?', Journal of Economic Growth 9(3), 271303.
  • Hall, R. E. & Jones, C. L. (1999), 'Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?', The Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1), 83116.
  • Islam, N. (1995), 'Growth Empirics: A Panel Data Approach', The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(4), 11271170.
  • Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. & Mastruzzi, M. (2008), 'Governance Matters VII: Governance Indicators for 1996-2007', World Bank. World Bank Policy Research.
  • Koopmans, T. C. (1965), 'On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth', Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics. Discussion Papers nş 163.
  • La Porta, R., de Silanes F., L. & Shleifer, A. (2008), 'The Economic Conseguences of Legal Origins', Journal of Economic Literature 46(2), 285332.
  • La Porta, R., de Silanes F., L., Shleifer, A. & Vishny, R. (1999), 'The Quality of Government', The Journal of Law, Economics AND Organization 15(1), 222279.
  • Lucas, R. (1988), 'On the machanics of economic development.', Journal of Monetary Economics 22, 342.
  • North, D. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, 1 edn, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
  • O'Neill, J. (2001), Building Better Global Economic Brics, Global Economic Paper 66, Goldman Sachs.
  • Ramsey, F. (1928), 'A Mathematical Theory of Saving', Economic Journal 38(152), 543559.
  • Rebelo, S. (1991), 'Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth', The Journal of Political Economy 99(3), 500521.
  • Rodrik, D. (1999), 'Where Did All the Growth Go? External Shocks, Social Conflict, and Growth Collapses', Journal of Economic Growth 4(4), 385412.
  • Rodrik, D. (2008), 'Second Best Institutions', Harvard University. Discussion Paper.
  • Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A. & Trebbi, F. (2004), 'Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions over Geography and Integration in Economic Development', Journal of Economic Growth 9(2), 131165.
  • Romer, P. M. (1994), 'The Origins of Endogenous Growth', Journal of Economic Perspectives 8, 322.
  • Roodman, D. (2009a), 'A Note on the Theme of Too Many Instruments', Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 71(1), 135158.
  • Roodman, D. (2009b), 'How to Do xtabond2: An Introduction to Difference and System GMM in Stata', Stata Journal 9(1), 86136.
  • Sachs, J. D. (2000), Notes on a New Sociology of Economic Development, in L. E. H. Huntington & S. P., eds, 'CultureMatters: How Values Shape Human Progress', Vol. 1, Basic Books.
  • Sachs, J. D. (2003), 'Institutions DonŽt Rule: Direct Effect of Geography on Per Capita Income', National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper nş 9490.
  • Sachs, J. & Warner, A. (1995), 'Economic reform and the process of global integration', Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1995(1), 1118.
  • Sachs, J. &Warner, A. (1997), 'Fundamental sources of long-run growth', The American Economic Review 87(2), 184188.
  • Sala-I-Martin, R. B. & X. (1990), Economic growth and convergence across the United States, Technical report, NBER.
  • Solow, R. (1956), 'A contribution to the theory of economics growth.', Quartely Journal of Economics 70, 6594.
  • Stock, J. H. & Yogo, M. (2005), Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression, in D. W. K. A. Stock & J. H., eds, 'Identification and Inference for Econometric Models: Essays in Honor of Thomas Rothenberg', Vol. 1, Cambridge University Press.
  • Strazicich, J. L. & M. (2001), 'Break point estimation and spurious rejections with endogenous unit root tests.', Oxford Bulletin of Economic and Statistics 63, 513615.
  • Swan, T. (1956), 'Economic growth and capital accumulation', Economic Record 32, 334361.
  • Weil, N. M., Romer, D. & D. (1992), 'A contribution to the empirics of economic growth', Quartely Journal of Economics 107, 207237.
  • Windmeijer, F. (2005), 'A Finite Sample Correction for the Variance of Linear Efficient Two-Step GMM Estimators', Journal of Econometrics 126, 2551.
  • 1
    A historical look on the growth literature reveals that during the 1950s and 1960s growth theory was linked primarily to the neoclassical model developed by Ramsey (1928), Solow (1956), Swan (1956), Cass (1965) and Koopmans (1965). These models were based on the so-called convergence property and the idea is that economies with low per capita GDP will face higher growth rates given the assumption of diminishing capital returns. Since the 1980s, the concept of capital in the neoclassical model has been expanded to incorporate not only physical capital but also human capital, as seen through the models developed by Lucas (1988) and Rebelo (1991), among others. Romer (1994) highlights the dilemma encountered by the theoretical and empirical growth literatures and the contribution of endogenous growth theory to understand the long-term growth, arguing that the main contribution of this approach is to provide a theory of technological progress, one of the central elements absent from the neoclassical growth model. The inclusion of a theory of technological change in the neoclassical framework is difficult, since the conventional assumptions of competitiveness cannot be maintained.
  • 2
    See Bruno & Easterly (1998) for additional evidence on inflation and growth.
  • 3
    Studies such as Weil et al. (1992) was crucial in setting an empirical agenda to investigate differences in per capita income levels across countries based on differences in human and physical capital and productivity.
  • 4
    The geography/endowment hypothesis is associated to different studies such as Sachs & Warner (1995), Sachs & Warner (1997), Bloom & Sachs (1998) and O'Neill (2001), arguing for the presence of direct effects of tropics, germs, and crops on development. The institutions hypothesis relates the effect of tropics, germs, and crops through institutions and can be associated to works such as Hall & Jones (1999) who uses institutional quality as one component of social infrastructure which is crucial to explain differences in productivity, allowing for the use of instruments such as distance from the equator and European language. Acemoglu et al. (2001) is another example of the institution view with a germs theory of institution by using settler's mortality as an instrument for institutions. The policy view argues in favor of sound macroeconomic policies, openness to international trade, and the absence of capital account controls considered as important measures to foster economic growth and to increase per capita income. Tropics, germs, and crops may influence production technologies and institutions but to improve economic development it is necessary to change policies targeting low inflation, increase in trade and financial integration to the world. One example of this view is Frankel & Romer (1999) to whom geography matters for economic development through government policy (trade openness).
  • 5
    Another possibility is to use the optimal GMM estimator (OGMM) with the heteroskedasticity correction, which is based on a weighting matrix that it different from the one used by 2SLS estimation. One of the problems associated to 2SLS estimation is how to avoid the use of weak instruments since they will result in less precise coefficients due to high standard errors (lower t-statistics) and the occurrence of finite sample bias (the IV estimator is not centered on the true populational coefficient). See Cameron & Trivedi (2008) chapter 6 for further details on 2SLM and OGMM. The paper uses overidentification tests with the estat overid command for Stata 10.0 and the estat firststage command to evaluate the presence of weak instruments (F-stat of first stage).
    Table A.4 of the appendix reports additional estimation such as the OGMM for the cross-section models in order to have a broader range of coefficient estimates and to compare them with the 2SLS.
  • 6
    Law is a variable based on two components, the first one (Law) is an assessment of the strength and impartiality of the legal system while the second (Order) is an assessment of popular observance of the law. In order to obtain the instrument for Law we follow three basic approaches. The first one uses variables that capture the influence of Western Europe across countries and it is based on the argument that a higher influence is associated to a more developed institutional environment. According to this approach, the variables used as instruments are the fraction of the population of each country speaking English, denominated as EnglishLang, and the fraction of the population speaking one the major languages of Western Europe (English, French, German, Portuguese, or Spanish), denominated as EuropeLang (Hall & Jones 1999). The second approach uses variables that distinguish countries regarding the origin of the legal system and are based on the argument that the British legal system (English Common Law) is associated to a higher degree of institutional development. In order to do this, the variable LegorUK is a dummy assuming the value 1 for countries where the origin of the legal system is British and zero otherwise ((La Porta et al. 1999),(La Porta et al. 2008)). The third one uses variables that captures the conditions faced by the settlers in the ex-colonies and is based on the argument that where they faced the most adverse conditions for settlement, the worst institutions were introduced and they persisted over time. In order to do this the variable used as instrument is the mortality rate faced by the settlers in the ex-colonies, denominated as SettlerMort (Acemoglu et al. 2001). For a complete list of variables and a more detailed definition see appendix
  • 7
    Examining the results from
    table 4A of the appendix for a comparison of different estimation methods we can see that there is a significant variation on the estimated coefficients when using the Jacknife IV (JIVE) and the LIML estimators that are asymptotically equivalent to 2SLS but may have better finite sample properties than 2SLS. The estimated coefficients for 2SLS and OGMM are much more similar for both complete and restricted samples.
  • 8
    See
    table 3A of the appendix for the correlation analysis of Law and the instruments for the complete and restricted sample. The correlation coefficients are high and vary from 0.2 to 0.51.
  • 9
    The model specification includes a term that varies over time and is constant across countries, and such term is not reported in the following equations just to simplify the presentation. This time-specific term is part of all regressions estimated by including the time Dummies variables for each period (five year average) of the sample.
  • 10
    A more detailed presentation including matrix notation can be found in Roodman (2009a), p.148-149. See also Baltagi (2008) for further empirical examples using the collapse command.
  • 11
    The results for the AR(2), Hansen and Hansen Diff tests indicate that we are able to reject the null hypothesis meaning that there is no second order autocorrelation and the instruments are valid, with only one exception for the Hansen Diff test in model specification (1) using System-GMM.
  • 12
    Sala-I-Martin & X. (1990) develops a theoretical and empirical investigation on the contribution of government spending to growth considering not only government consumption, as we have done in our paper, but also government investment (infrastructure) suggesting a possibility that government investment can foster economic growth.
  • 13
    Conditional convergence (negative coefficient for Yinitial) is observed for all estimated models except for model (5) and most coefficients are statistically significant except for models (1) and (5).
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      09 Nov 2011
    • Date of issue
      Sept 2011

    History

    • Accepted
      16 Aug 2011
    • Received
      08 May 2010
    Faculdade de Economia, Administração e Contabilidade de Ribeirão Preto da Universidade de São Paulo Avenida dos Bandeirantes, 3.900, CEP 14040-900 Ribeirão Preto SP Brasil, Tel.: +55 16 3315-3910 - Ribeirão Preto - SP - Brazil
    E-mail: revecap@usp.br