Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Multiple large shareholders and absinvestment among Chinese listed firms

Abstract

Purpose

This study employees cash flow rights and the contestability of multiple large shareholders to explore the impact of multiple large shareholders on investment efficiency in Chinese setting.

Theoretical framework

We introduce Asymmetric Information Theory and Theory of Principal and Agent o support our study.

Design/methodology/approach

Empirical study (including PSM method, IV method, threshold method and so on) is used in this study. Moreover, this paper selects the non-financial listed companies of A share enlisted in both the Shanghai and the Shenzhen Stock Markets from the period of 2007 to 2016 as the sample.

Findings

Our findings show a positive correlation between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment among Chinese listed firms.

Practical & social implications of research

Different from the previous views that multiple large shareholders have positive governance effects, we provide evidence that multiple large shareholders have negative governance effects. And we provide new evidence that controlling shareholders would collude with multiple large shareholders to seek for excess private benefits by enhancing enterprise absinvestment.

Originality/value

This study contributes to the literature in several important ways. First, it shows a positive correlation between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment, which extends the research of Jiang et al. (2018), which found that multiple large shareholders can profoundly enhance investment efficiency. Second, this paper is the first to introduce a threshold model to study the impact of controlling shareholders on the relation between multiple large shareholders and absinvestent, demonstrating that the positive relation between them is strengthened by promoting the governance effect of controlling shareholders.

Keywords:
Multiple large shareholders; controlling shareholders; absinvestment; collusion; threshold model

1 Introduction

The multiple ownership structure has been highly praised by scholars in recent years. This kind of structure allows large shareholders to try to improve their control rights, stimulate supervision vitality, create a power balance, and curb insider tunneling behaviors with specific mechanisms related to firm value premiums (Maury and Pajuste, 2005Maury, B., & Pajuste, A. (2005). Multiple large shareholders and firm value. Journal of Banking & Finance, 29(7), 1813-1834. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2004.07.002.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.200...
; Laeven and Levine, 2008Laeven, L., & Levine, R. (2008). Complex ownership structures and corporate valuations. Review of Financial Studies, 21(2), 579-604. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhm068.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhm068...
; Attig et al., 2009Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., & Guedhami, O. (2009). Do multiple large shareholders play a corporate governance role? Evidence from East Asia. Journal of Financial Research, 32(4), 395-422. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.2009.01255.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.20...
, 2013Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O., & Rizeanu, S. (2013). The governance role of multiple large shareholders: Evidence from the valuation of cash holdings. The Journal of Management and Governance, 17(2), 419-451. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10997-011-9184-3.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10997-011-918...
; Boateng and Huang, 2017Boateng, A., & Huang, W. (2017). Multiple large shareholders, excess leverage and tunneling: Evidence from an emerging market. Corporate Governance, 25(1), 58-74. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/corg.12184.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/corg.12184...
). Thus, compared to companies with decentralized and concentrated ownership structures, firms with multiple ownership structures show better governance performance. However, in practice, shareholder “collusion and violation” incidents, such as the illegal “card raising” of S&P pharmaceuticals, have repeatedly emerged, and large shareholders often pursue excessive private interests by forming interest alliances. However, the existing literature mainly focuses on the checks and balances of large shareholders, but does not establish a valid framework to explain the collusion of shareholders (Su et al., 2008Su, Y., Xu, D., & Phan, P. H. (2008). Principal: Principal conflict in the governance of the Chinese Public Corporation. Management and Organization Review, 4(1), 17-38. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1740-8784.2007.00090.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1740-8784.20...
). In particular, there is a lack of empirical evidence on whether the multiple ownership structure has disadvantages or not. Therefore, our research attempts to fill this gap.

Agency theory argues that absinvestment is an important way for managers and shareholders to pursue their own private interests. According to the agent-principal problem, managers use control rights to pursue their private interests, such as seeking a “quiet life,” salary manipulation, building a private empire, and increasing enterprise risk taking, which results in serious agency problems (Li and Tang, 2010Li, J., & Tang, Y. (2010). CEO hubris and firm risk taking in China: The moderating role of managerial discretion. Academy of Management Journal, 53(1), 45-68. http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amj.2010.48036912.
http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amj.2010.48036...
; Stulz, 1990Stulz, R. (1990). Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 26(1), 3-27. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(90)90011-N.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(90)9...
), thus reducing the efficiency of enterprise investment. According to the principal-principal problem, controlling shareholders can make their control rights deviate from their cash flow rights through a pyramid structure, cross shareholding, different rights of the same share and so on, so as to obtain control rights beyond ownership (Lemmon and Lins, 2003Lemmon, M. L., & Lins, K. V. (2003). Ownership structure, corporate governance, and firm value: Evidence from the East Asian financial crisis. The Journal of Finance, 58(4), 1445-1468. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1540-6261.00573.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1540-6261.0057...
; Almeida and Wolfenzon, 2006Almeida, H. V., & Wolfenzon, D. (2006). A theory of pyramidal ownership and family business groups. The Journal of Finance, 61(6), 2637-2680. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.01001.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.20...
). Considering the excessive control of resources (Wang, 2009Wang, N. (2009). Optimal consumption and asset allocation with unknown income growth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(4), 524-534. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009.03.005.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009...
), maintenance of control rights and holding costs (Filatotchev et al., 2008Filatotchev, I., Stephan, J., & Jindra, B. (2008). Ownership structure, strategic controls and export intensity of foreign-invested firms in transition economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(7), 1133-1148. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400404.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs....
), lower investment barriers (Wu and Wang, 2005Wu, X., & Wang, Z. (2005). Equity financing in a Myers–Majluf framework with private benefits of control. Journal of Corporate Finance, 11(5), 915-945. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2004.04.001.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.200...
), the level of risk tolerance and other factors (Zhang, 1998Zhang, G. (1998). Ownership concentration, risk aversion and the effect of financial structure on investment decisions. European Economic Review, 42(9), 1751-1778. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(97)00106-2.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(97)...
), controlling shareholders with excess control rights have enough power and ability to drive enterprises to make absinvestment decisions, so as to obtain their own private benefits. Consequently, the essence of absinvestment is a redistribution behavior in which the subject with control rights can grab the controlling resources and expropriate the wealth of other interested subjects. Non-controlling large shareholders have the ability and opportunity to obtain excess control rights due to information asymmetry. In this context, would non-controlling large shareholders continue to mitigate the two kinds of agency problems to improve investment efficiency, or would they pursue private benefits through absinvestment activities as part of the subject with control rights? This is a topic worth exploring in depth.

In order to explore the relationship between the multiple ownership structure and absinvestment, this study uses a sample of Chinese listed companies and their unique governance characteristics to investigate the impact of multiple large shareholders on enterprise investment. First, as the largest developing country in the world, China’s economy has been growing rapidly for a long time, and there are numerous investment opportunities in these listed companies. Second, although the ownership structure has changed from the traditional “yigududa” to multiple large shareholders after the non-tradable shares reform, the current ownership structure is still relatively concentrated (Faccio and Lang, 2002Faccio, M., & Lang, L. H. (2002). The ultimate ownership of Western European corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 65(3), 365-395. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(02)00146-0.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(02)...
; Sun and Tong, 2003Sun, Q., & Tong, W. H. (2003). China share issue privatization: The extent of its success. Journal of Financial Economics, 70(2), 183-222. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(03)00145-4.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(03)...
), and controlling shareholders are still dominant in companies, which provides multiple large shareholders with the motivation and ability to supervise controlling shareholders so as to protect their own interests. Third, due to the imperfect protection mechanism for minority shareholders and the limited role of the takeover market and independent director system in restricting the tunneling behaviors of large shareholders (Jiang et al., 2010Jiang, G., Lee, C. M., & Yue, H. (2010). Tunneling through intercorporate loans: The China experience. Journal of Financial Economics, 98(1), 1-20. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.05.002.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
; Peng et al., 2011Peng, W. Q., Wei, K. J., & Yang, Z. (2011). Tunneling or propping: Evidence from connected transactions in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(2), 306-325. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2010.08.002.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.201...
), multiple large shareholders may collude with controlling shareholders to expropriate minority shareholders’ interests. In other words, these characteristics provide various opportunities for the multiple ownership structure to influence enterprise investment.

To explore the impact of the multiple ownership structure on enterprise investment, this paper conducts an in-depth study by answering the following two questions. First, do multiple large shareholders increase or decrease absinvestment? To answer this question, this study uses cash flow rights and contestability to measure the governance effect of multiple large shareholders and employs a prospective investment model to calculate absinvestment. The results show that multiple large shareholders can significantly improve absinvestment. Our findings are also robust to alternative dependent and independent variables and to different model specifications. Second, would controlling shareholders collude with multiple large shareholders to increase absinvestment? To answer this question, this paper introduces a threshold model to explore the impact of controlling shareholders on multiple large shareholders and absinvestment to determine whether controlling shareholders would collude with multiple large shareholders to seek excess private benefits. We show that controlling shareholder governance can strengthen the positive correlation between multiple ownership structure and absinvestment, which means that controlling shareholders would collude with multiple large shareholders to pursue their self-interests by increasing a firm’s absinvestment.

This study contributes to the literature in several important ways. First, it shows a positive correlation between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment, which extends the research of Jiang et al. (2018)Jiang, F., Cai, W., Wang, X., & Zhu, B. (2018). Multiple large shareholders and corporate investment: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 50, 66-83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2018.02.001.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.201...
, which found that multiple large shareholders can significantly improve investment efficiency. Second, this paper is the first to introduce a threshold model to study the impact of controlling shareholders on the relationship between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment, showing that the positive relationship between them is strengthened by promoting the governance effect of controlling shareholders. Third, this paper provides new evidence that controlling shareholders would collude with multiple large shareholders to seek excess private benefits by increasing enterprise absinvestment, which extends the research of Konijn et al. (2011)Konijn, S. J., Kräussl, R., & Lucas, A. (2011). Blockholder dispersion and firm value. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(5), 1330-1339. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2011.06.005.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.201...
, which proved that multiple large shareholders are entrenched against controlling shareholders.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 outlines the theoretical analysis and develops the hypotheses. Section 3 describes the methods and data. Section 4 reports the empirical evidence. Section 5 presents the further investigation. Section 6 presents our conclusions.

2 Theoretical analysis and hypotheses

In a perfect market, an enterprise’s optimal investment level should make the marginal income equal to the marginal cost (Modigliani and Miller, 1958Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. The American Economic Review, 48, 261-297.). However, in practice, realistic frictions cause firms to exhibit absinvestment behavior (over-investment and under-investment), thus deviating from the optimal investment level. In order to explore the internal logic of absinvestment behavior, Jensen and Meckling (1976)Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305-360. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)9...
started from the ownership decentralization assumption and pointed out that managers make decisions to maximize their own interests, which may go against the principle of investor interest maximization, resulting in “moral failure behavior.” Jensen (1986)Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic Review, 76, 323-329. showed that managers would not distribute a large amount of free cash to shareholders, but would rather use it to expand the size of the firm in order to obtain more control rights and higher salaries, resulting in serious absinvestment behavior. Murphy (1985)Murphy, K. J. (1985). Corporate performance and managerial remuneration: An empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7(1-3), 11-42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90026-6.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)9...
proved that managers would blindly expand the size of the firm with the aim of obtaining excessive control over resources, resulting in serious absinvestment behavior. Morck et al. (1988)Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management ownership and market valuation: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 293-315. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(88)90048-7.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(88)9...
indicated that in addition to obtaining excessive control rights, managers are likely to prefer more resources for the projects that are beneficial to their own development in order to ensure job security, and these projects often do not aim at enterprise value maximization. Moreover, in order to seek excessive in-service consumption, some managers may also make absinvestment decisions (Stulz, 1990Stulz, R. (1990). Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 26(1), 3-27. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(90)90011-N.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(90)9...
).

The above studies have shown that as ownership concentration increases, shareholders’ monitoring of managers’ control rights will also increase, which mitigates the enterprise absinvestment behavior caused by the agency conflict between shareholders and managers. However, Claessens et al. found that this is not the case. When ownership is highly concentrated, controlling shareholders can gain control over ownership by means of a pyramid structure, cross-shareholding and having the same share with various rights, which separates the control rights and cash flow rights of controlling shareholders, and controlling shareholders have the motivation and ability to seek private benefits with their excess control rights, resulting in absinvestment (La Porta et al., 1999La Porta, R., Lopezdesilanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 471-517. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00115.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.0011...
; Dyck and Zingales, 2004Dyck, A., & Zingales, L. (2004). Private benefits of control: An international comparison. The Journal of Finance, 59(2), 537-600. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00642.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.20...
; Aggarwal and Samwick, 2006Aggarwal, R. K., & Samwick, A. A. (2006). Empire-builders and shirkers: Investment, firm performance, and managerial incentives. Journal of Corporate Finance, 12(3), 489-515. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2006.01.001.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.200...
). From the perspective of risk tolerance, Zhang (1998)Zhang, G. (1998). Ownership concentration, risk aversion and the effect of financial structure on investment decisions. European Economic Review, 42(9), 1751-1778. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(97)00106-2.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(97)...
demonstrated that risk-averse controlling shareholders would reduce enterprise investment efficiency. In addition, the maintenance of control rights and holding costs also lead to enterprise absinvestment (Filatotchev et al., 2008Filatotchev, I., Stephan, J., & Jindra, B. (2008). Ownership structure, strategic controls and export intensity of foreign-invested firms in transition economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(7), 1133-1148. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400404.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs....
). These studies show that the agent-principal problem between shareholders in the mode of ownership concentration, and the private interest behavior of controlling shareholders, are the root of enterprise absinvestment.

In fact, in addition to ownership decentralization and ownership concentration, multiple ownership structures also widely exist. Previous studies have shown that a multiple ownership structure has competing governance effects, namely a supervision effect and an entrenchment effect. The supervision effect illustrates that a multiple ownership structure can alleviate the two kinds of agency problems by monitoring the private interest behavior of managers and controlling shareholders, thus moderating enterprise absinvestment. The research of Attig et al. (2009)Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., & Guedhami, O. (2009). Do multiple large shareholders play a corporate governance role? Evidence from East Asia. Journal of Financial Research, 32(4), 395-422. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.2009.01255.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.20...
and Boubaker and Sami (2011)Boubaker, S., & Sami, H. (2011). Multiple large shareholders and earnings informativeness. Review of Accounting and Finance, 10(3), 246-266. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/14757701111155789.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/14757701111155...
pointed out that a multiple ownership structure can mitigate the agency conflict of internal and external shareholders by effectively improving the environmental quality of enterprise information. García-Meca et al. (2015)García-Meca, E., García-Sánchez, I.-M., & Martínez-Ferrero, J. (2015). Board diversity and its effects on bank performance: An international analysis. Journal of Banking & Finance, 53, 202-214. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.12.002.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.201...
and Perryman et al. (2016)Perryman, A. A., Fernando, G. D., & Tripathy, A. (2016). Do gender differences persist? An examination of gender diversity on firm performance, risk, and executive compensation. Journal of Business Research, 69(2), 579-586. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2015.05.013.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2015...
believed that large shareholders with different backgrounds and knowledge can bring new perspectives to corporate decision-making and improve the efficiency of supervision and decision-making. Moreover, large shareholders with different identities and backgrounds, from different industries and in different supply chain positions can obtain information about the prospects of the industry and enterprise, and they are more likely to recognize the private interest behavior of managers and controlling shareholders, and thus have stronger supervisory abilities (Attig et al., 2009Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., & Guedhami, O. (2009). Do multiple large shareholders play a corporate governance role? Evidence from East Asia. Journal of Financial Research, 32(4), 395-422. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.2009.01255.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.20...
). Furthermore, the “exit threat” of large shareholders can also effectively constrain the private interest behavior of managers and controlling shareholders (Edmans and Manso, 2011Edmans, A., & Manso, G. (2011). Governance through trading and intervention: A theory of multiple blockholders. Review of Financial Studies, 24(7), 2395-2428. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhq145.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhq145...
; Bharath et al., 2013Bharath, S. T., Jayaraman, S., & Nagar, V. (2013). Exit as governance: An empirical analysis. The Journal of Finance, 68(6), 2515-2547. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12073.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12073...
). Based on the above studies, we propose the following hypothesis:

H1: When multiple large shareholders play a monitoring role, absinvestment is moderated.

The entrenchment effect occurs because of incomplete contracts and information asymmetry between inside and outside the enterprise, where controlling shareholders, large shareholders, and managers who share control rights have a strong conspiratorial motivation to pursue private interests (Bae et al., 2012Bae, K., Baek, J., Kang, J., & Liu, W. (2012). Do controlling shareholders’ expropriation incentives imply a link between corporate governance and firm value? Theory and evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 105(2), 412-435. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.02.007.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012...
; Bena and Ortizmolina, 2013Bena, J., & Ortizmolina, H. (2013). Pyramidal ownership and the creation of new firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 108(3), 798-821. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.01.009.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2013...
). In addition, the legal protection of minority shareholders in the Chinese market is still weak, and the limited effect of the takeover market and independent directors in limiting tunneling behavior makes it easier for multiple large shareholders to collude with controlling shareholders to pursue self-interests (Jiang et al., 2010Jiang, G., Lee, C. M., & Yue, H. (2010). Tunneling through intercorporate loans: The China experience. Journal of Financial Economics, 98(1), 1-20. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.05.002.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010...
; Peng et al., 2011Peng, W. Q., Wei, K. J., & Yang, Z. (2011). Tunneling or propping: Evidence from connected transactions in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(2), 306-325. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2010.08.002.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.201...
), along with more serious absinvestment. Moreover, in an imperfect market, absinvestment does not always lead to a decrease in firm value; on the contrary, it may bring about higher benefits because of its high risk. The higher benefits are often enjoyed only by shareholders, and most of the investment costs are passed on to stakeholders such as creditors (Jensen and Meckling, 1976Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305-360. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)9...
). In this context, we propose the following hypothesis.

H2: When multiple large shareholders play an entrenchment role, absinvestment increases (Figure 1).

Figure 1
Conceptual structure and relationships among variables

3 Methods and data

3.1 Methods

Considering the monitoring effect and entrenchment effect of multiple large shareholders, we construct the panel data model as follows.

A b s i n v e s t m e n t i ,t = β 0 + β 1 NCLSs i ,t + β 2 control i ,t + ε i ,t (1)

where inefficient investment is measured by Absinvestment; NCLSs is the independent variable including the cash flow rights and contestability of multiple large shareholders; and ε is the residual error. The robust standard error is used to control for potential serial correlation and heteroscedasticity.

To calculate Absinvestment, we follow the expected investment model of Richardson (2006)Richardson, S. (2006). Over-investment of free cash flow. Review of Accounting Studies, 11(2-3), 159-189. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11142-006-9012-1.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11142-006-901...
.

Newinvestment i ,t = β 1 + β 2 Return i ,t-1 + β 3 Tobin's Q i ,t-1 + β 4 Cash i ,t-1 + β 5 CS i ,t-1 + β 6 Age i ,t-1
+ β 7 Leverage i ,t-1 + β 8 Ln_Assets i ,t-1 + β 9 Newinvestment i ,t-1 + γ t + δ t + ε i ,t (2)

where Newinvestment is the newly increased investment expenditure after the standardization of total assets in the current year, and this newly increased investment expenditure = expenditure on the purchase of fixed assets, intangible assets and other long-term assets + net cash paid by subsidiaries and other business units – net cash from the disposal of fixed assets, intangible assets and other long-term assets – net cash from the disposal of subsidiaries and other business units – depreciation and amortization of the current period; Return is the annual rate of return on an individual share; Cash is the currency capital after standardizing total assets; and γt and δt are the annual effect and the industry effect, respectively. Equation 2 calculates the optimal investment in the current year using the data of the first lagged period, that is, the expected investment level. The residual error is unexpected investment expenditure, that is, absinvestment.

In this paper, NCLSs is the independent variable, defined as the second and third largest groups of shareholders. To fully measure the governance effect of multiple large shareholders, the measurement index captures two aspects according to Attig et al. (2009Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., & Guedhami, O. (2009). Do multiple large shareholders play a corporate governance role? Evidence from East Asia. Journal of Financial Research, 32(4), 395-422. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.2009.01255.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.20...
, 2013Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O., & Rizeanu, S. (2013). The governance role of multiple large shareholders: Evidence from the valuation of cash holdings. The Journal of Management and Governance, 17(2), 419-451. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10997-011-9184-3.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10997-011-918...
). First, we use cash flow rights, which relate to the shareholding ratio of the second and third largest shareholders (CF3). Second, we employ the contestability of control rights, which is equal to the cash flow rights of multiple large shareholders divided by the cash flow rights of the controlling shareholders (Contest3). Additionally, for the robustness test, we use the cash flow rights of the second largest shareholder (CF2) and the contestability of control rights, which is equal to the cash flow rights of the second largest shareholder divided by the cash flow rights of the controlling shareholders (Contest2), and the dummy variable for multiple large shareholders (MLS_dummy), where MLS_dummy is a dummy variable that takes the value of 1 when there are multiple large shareholders with a shareholding ratio of more than 5% and 0 otherwise.

To examine the impact of multiple large shareholders on investment efficiency, we select the following control variables: firm value (Tobin’s Q), free cash flow (FCF), cash flow rights of controlling shareholders (CS), affiliated director of controlling shareholders (ABCS), listed years (Age), asset-to-liability ratio (Leverage), firm size (Ln_Assets), and firm nature (State).

The definitions of the variables are shown in Table 1.

Table 1
Variable definition

3.2 Data sources

The data in this paper are from the non-financial A-share listed companies in both the Shanghai and Shenzhen stock markets (Supplementary Data 1 – database). Specifically, we use the data period from 2007 to 2016 because the new accounting standards were adopted in 2007. In addition, we choose companies listed before December 31st, 2006, to avoid the impact of data changes in the first year of listing on the research results, and eliminate companies whose asset-to-liability ratio is greater than 100% to reduce the effect of other factors on firm value. Finally, 10120 firm-year observations are confirmed as the final sample in this paper.

In addition, in order to more accurately measure the corporate governance effect of multiple large shareholders, and to avoid the influence of some blockholders associated with the controlling shareholder, such as relational blockholders via ownership, kinship, work, or agreements, which has been proven to affect the governance effect of multiple large shareholders (Cheng et al., 2013Cheng, M., Lin, B., & Wei, M. (2013). How does the relationship between multiple large shareholders affect corporate valuations? Evidence from China. Journal of Economics and Business, 70, 43-70. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconbus.2012.12.003.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconbus.201...
), we establish the information base as the CSMAR database and annual reports of Chinese listed firms, manually collecting the relationship information of large shareholders and the corporate control chain from annual reports. We treat the relational blockholders as a whole, aggregate their shareholdings, and rearrange the top three shareholders.

3.3 Descriptive statistics and correlation analysis

Table 2 presents the results of descriptive statistics and correlation analysis of the key variables. Rows 2 and 3 report the descriptive statistics, among which the average value of CF3 is 8.12% and the average value of Contest3 is 29.82%, indicating that multiple large shareholders have an important influence on firm decision-making. The average value of CS is 37.68%, which shows that the ownership structure of Chinese listed companies is still concentrated. Rows 4 to 15 describe the results of the correlation coefficients, and the results are all less than 0.5, which means that there is no serious multicollinearity problem in this paper. Furthermore, there are some interesting findings in that the proxies of CF3 and Contest3 are significantly positively associated with absinvestment, which indicates that multiple large shareholders play a passive role by increasing a firm’s absinvestment (Supplementary Data 2 – do file).

Table 2
Descriptive statistics and correlation analysis of key variables

4 Empirical results

4.1 Main test

Table 3 describes the regression results of the relationship between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment by using Equation 1. Models 1 and 2 illustrate the impact of multiple large shareholders on absinvestment without control variables, showing that cash flow rights (CF3: β=0.059, ρ<0.01) and contestability (Con3: β=0.008, ρ<0.01) are both significantly positively associated with absinvestment at the 1% level, indicating that the level of absinvestment would be greatly improved by promoting the governance effect of multiple large shareholders. Models 3 and 4 illustrate the impact of multiple large shareholders on absinvestment with control variables, revealing that cash flow rights (CF3: β=0.059, ρ<0.01) and contestability (Con3: β=0.008, ρ<0.01) are both significantly positively associated with absinvestment at the 1% level, suggesting that the level of absinvestment would be greatly improved by promoting the governance effect of multiple large shareholders. In conclusion, the level of absinvestment would be greatly improved by promoting the governance effect of multiple large shareholders. Therefore, Hypothesis 2 is confirmed.

Table 3
The impact of multiple large shareholders on absinvestment

4.2 Endogenous control

While our main results have provided some interesting insights into the impact of multiple large shareholders on absinvestment, it is necessary to take the endogenous problem into consideration. Therefore, in order to mitigate the influence of endogenous problems on the results, we employ the propensity score matching (PSM) method and the instrumental variable (IV) method.

Using PSM, we construct a matched sample including a subsample with multiple large shareholders (at the 5% threshold) and a subsample with other types of shareholders to limit the influence of sample differences on the results. Specifically, after controlling for the industry and year effects, we determine the propensity score by using the nearest neighbor matching method without replacement to choose the firm that is the closest in terms of the probability of being owned by multiple large shareholders. The probability is estimated using the probit model, and the dependent variable of the regression test is MLS_dummy, and the independent variables include Tobin’s Q, Ln_Assets, Leverage, Age, and industry and year dummy variables (Demsetz and Lehn, 1985Demsetz, H., & Lehn, K. (1985). The structure of corporate ownership: Causes and consequences. Journal of Political Economy, 93(6), 1155-1177. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261354.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261354...
; Faccio et al., 2011Faccio, M., Marchica, M., & Mura, R. (2011). Large shareholder diversification and corporate risk-taking. Review of Financial Studies, 24(11), 3601-3641. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhr065.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhr065...
). Finally, we obtain 7114 firm-year observations, equally distributed between firms with multiple large shareholders and others.

Table 4 shows the influence of multiple large shareholders on enterprise investment efficiency using the PSM method. Model 1 shows the results of the probit model. From it, we can see that the coefficients of Ln_Assets and Age are all significant negative at the 1% level, suggesting that it is more possible for smaller and emerging companies to have more multiple large shareholders than large and mature companies (Ben-Nasr et al., 2015Ben-Nasr, H., Boubaker, S., & Rouatbi, W. (2015). Ownership structure, control contestability, and corporate debt maturity. Journal of Corporate Finance, 35, 265-285. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2015.10.001.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.201...
), and the reasons may be related to the high cost of obtaining a large number of shares in large and mature companies (Demsetz and Lehn, 1985Demsetz, H., & Lehn, K. (1985). The structure of corporate ownership: Causes and consequences. Journal of Political Economy, 93(6), 1155-1177. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261354.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261354...
). Model 2 explores the relationship between the cash flow rights of multiple large shareholders and absinvestment, indicating that there is a profound positive relationship between them (CF3: β=0.031, ρ<0.01). Model 3 examines the relationship between the contestability of controlling large shareholders and absinvestment, showing that there is a profound positive relationship between them (Contest3: β=0.004, ρ<0.05). In conclusion, the PSM results show that multiple large shareholders can significantly improve absinvestment.

Table 4
The PSM results

Additionally, following Mishra (2011)Mishra, D. R. (2011). Multiple large shareholders and corporate risk taking: Evidence from East Asia. Corporate Governance, 19(6), 507-528. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2011.00862.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.20...
and Paligorova and Xu (2012)Paligorova, T., & Xu, Z. (2012). Complex ownership and capital structure. Journal of Corporate Finance, 18(4), 701-716. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2012.05.001.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.201...
, we use a two-stage instrumental variable approach with the industry-year average values for the CF3 variables as the instrumental variables. These instrumental variables capture the natural tendency of multiple large shareholders to be present in firms that engage in similar types of activities. The special feature of these instruments is that they are correlated with an individual firm’s ownership structure, but it is unlikely that the change in the ownership structure of one firm will affect the average ownership structure of the entire industry.

Table 5 displays the results of the IV method. Specifically, in Panel A, the coefficients (IV-CF3: β=0.720, ρ<0.01; IV-Contest3: β=2.440, ρ<0.01) are all significant at the 1% level, demonstrating that the instrumental variable used in this paper is effective. In Panel B, the coefficients of cash flow rights (CF3: β=0.141, ρ<0.05) and contestability (Contest3: β=0.042, ρ<0.05) are all significant at the 5% level, showing a profound positive relationship between the cash flow rights and contestability of multiple large shareholders and absinvestment, which demonstrates that the level of absinvestment could be greatly increased by promoting the governance effect of multiple large shareholders.

Table 5
The results of the IV method

4.3 Robustness check

To ensure that our results are robust, we conducted a series of sensitivity tests from the following perspectives: (1) sample adjustment, which eliminates those companies whose absinvestment level is less than 10%; (2) independent variable substitution, which uses MLS_dummy, CF2 and Contest2 to represent the governance effect of multiple large shareholders; and (3) different regression models, which employ ordinary least squares (OLS), random effects (RE), Tobit (Tobit), and weighted least squares (WLS). Table 6 presents the results of sample adjustment and independent variable substitution, and Table 7 describe the results of different regression models. The results show that our main findings are robust.

Table 6
The results of sample adjustment and independent variable substitution
Table 7
The results of different regression models

5 Further study

5.1 When and how other governance mechanisms affect multiple large shareholders

Corporate governance encompasses a set of systems or mechanisms, formal or informal, internal or external, and the interaction between them enables companies to operate. Effective corporate governance is a key link to attract investors, improve decision-making efficiency and create corporate value, and it is also a guarantee to coordinate stakeholders. Overuse of one of the governance systems may not achieve an effective governance effect or even have a negative governance effect (Agrawal and Knoeber, 1996Agrawal, A., & Knoeber, C. R. (1996). Firm performance and mechanisms to control agency problems between managers and shareholders. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 31(3), 377-397. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2331397.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2331397...
). Therefore, the optimal governance system should be the multiple combination of the interaction of different governance systems, where each can supplement or replace the other. To ensure good company operations, it is important for managers to understand these systems and the interactions among them. Among internal governance systems, controlling shareholders are undoubtedly the most important ones that would influence the governance of multiple large shareholders. Thus, this paper introduces controlling shareholders to study their impact on multiple large shareholder governance, using cash flow rights and affiliated directors of controlling shareholders to measure the governance effect of controlling shareholders.

Table 8 shows the impact of controlling shareholders on the relationship between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment. As shown in Model 1, when the cash flow rights of controlling shareholders are lower, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.030, and when the cash flow rights of controlling shareholders are higher, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.057, demonstrating that increasing the cash flow rights of controlling shareholders can greatly strengthen the positive relationship between multiple large shareholder governance and absinvestment (0.057>0.030).

Table 8
The results of other governance systems

As seen in Model 2, when the ratio of affiliated directors of controlling shareholders is lower, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.047, and when the ratio of affiliated directors of controlling shareholders is higher, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.357, indicating that increasing the ratio of affiliated directors of controlling shareholders can greatly strengthen the positive relationship between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment (0.357>0.047).

As shown in Model 3, when the cash flow rights of controlling shareholders are lower, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.001, which is not significant, indicating that there is no threshold value. This result is inconsistent with the result of Model 1, and the reason for this lies in the serious multicollinearity between the controlling power competitiveness of multiple large shareholders and the cash flow rights of controlling shareholders, with a correlation coefficient of -0.560 (see Table 2). In order to solve this problem, this chapter employs the degree of separation between the ownership and controlling rights of controlling shareholders to replace the cash flow rights of controlling shareholders, and the results are shown in Model 5. As this model shows, when the degree of separation is lower, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.042, and when the degree of separation is higher, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.091. It is obvious that 0.042<0.091, which shows that increasing the degree of separation can significantly strengthen the positive correlation between multiple large shareholders and corporate value, and this result is consistent with that of Model 1.

As shown in Model 4, when the ratio of affiliated directors of controlling shareholders is lower, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.006, and when the ratio of affiliated directors of controlling shareholders is higher, the coefficient of multiple large shareholders is 0.103, indicating that increasing the ratio of affiliated directors of controlling shareholders can greatly strengthen the positive relationship between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment (0.103>0.006).

Consequently, the results of Table 8 imply that increasing the cash flow rights and the ratio of affiliated directors of controlling shareholders can greatly strengthen the positive relationship between multiple large shareholder governance and absinvestment. The reason for this may be that the benefits created by increasing absinvestment are generally enjoyed by shareholders, especially by large shareholders, but the losses are not leveled against shareholders alone, and most of them are passed on to external stakeholders such as creditors and suppliers, so the benefits far exceed the costs. As a result, it is natural for controlling shareholders and multiple large shareholders to form a coalition to increase absinvestment, which strengthens the positive relationship between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment by controlling shareholders.

5.2 Heterogeneity analysis

5.2.1 Analysis with different agency problems

The long-term coexistence of state-owned enterprises and non-state-owned enterprises in China’s capital market is a distinctive feature. Specifically, most Chinese listed companies have been converted from state-owned enterprises, and state-owned shares still play an important role in these companies (Liu et al., 2015Liu, Y., Miletkov, M. K., Wei, Z., & Yang, T. (2015). Board independence and firm performance in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 30, 223-244. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2014.12.004.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.201...
). Meanwhile, with the development of the market economy, non-state-owned enterprises have made great contributions to national economic growth (Allen et al., 2005Allen, F., Qian, J., & Qian, M. (2005). Law, finance, and economic growth in China. Journal of Financial Economics, 77(1), 57-116. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.06.010.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2004...
; Ding et al., 2007Ding, Y., Zhang, H., & Zhang, J. (2007). Private vs state ownership and earnings management: Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Corporate Governance, 15(2), 223-238. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2007.00556.x.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.20...
). In our sample, 62.26% of the listed companies are state-owned, and 37.74% of them are non-state-owned enterprises. Because of the different characteristics of state-owned enterprises and non-state-owned enterprises, state-owned enterprises face more serious agency problems of the first type, and non-state-owned enterprises face more serious agency problems of the second type. Therefore, it is necessary to explore multiple large shareholder governance in both state-owned and non-state-owned enterprises. Thus, we divide the companies of our sample into state-owned and non-state-owned companies to examine the relationship between multiple large shareholder governance and absinvestment given different agency problems.

Table 9 shows the impact of multiple large shareholder governance on absinvestment in state-owned and non-state-owned enterprises, and the results show that multiple large shareholder governance would significantly increase the absinvestment level in both state-owned (Model 1: β=0.037, ρ<0.01; Model 2: β=0.006, ρ<0.10) and non-state-owned (Model 3: β=0.096, ρ<0.01; Model 4: β=0.011, ρ<0.01) enterprises, suggesting a positive effect of multiple large shareholder governance robust to the firm’s nature.

Table 9
The results of firm nature

5.2.2 Analysis with over-investment and under-investment

Furthermore, we divide absinvestment into over-investment and under-investment to determine whether the multiple ownership structure affects absinvestment through over-investment or under-investment. Specifically, over-investment refers to the investment activities for those unprofitable projects or high-risk projects that would harm the firm’s benefits, and under-investment refers to the investment activities for those abandoned projects with a positive net present value that would harm the firm’s benefits. We obtain 4291 samples with over-investment activities and 5829 samples with under-investment activities. Agency theory has shown that large shareholders are in an superior informational position compared to minority shareholders, and they may not always seek to maximize enterprise benefits, but rather seek private benefits of control at the expense of minority shareholders when making decisions (Johnson et al., 2000Johnson, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2000). Tunneling. The American Economic Review, 90(2), 22-27. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.2.22.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.2.22...
). The private benefits of control come from the company’s controlling resources, and over-investment can significantly increase the resources controlled by large shareholders, therefore, large shareholders are more likely to over-invest considering the private benefits of control, indicating that a multiple ownership structure can significantly increase over-investment. Meanwhile, because of the information asymmetry as well as the agency problem between shareholders and creditors, shareholders will not adopt new investment projects at the expense of their own interests in order to compensate creditors, and they lack enthusiasm to choose these projects, indicating that the multiple ownership structure will not influence under-investment.

Table 10 shows the impact of multiple large shareholders on absinvestment in over-investing (Model 1 and 2) and under-investing (Model 3 and 4) enterprises, and the results show that multiple large shareholders would significantly increase over-investment (Model 1: β=0.081, ρ<0.01; Model 2: β=0.011, ρ<0.01). Meanwhile, the results of Model 3 and 4 suggest that multiple large shareholders have no significant influence on under-investment (Model 3: β=0.018, ρ>0.10; Model 4: β=0.003, ρ>0.10). These results are consistent with our analysis above.

Table 10
The results of over-investment and under-investment

6 Conclusions

Previous empirical evidence indicates that multiple large shareholders can reduce insider tunneling activities by improving control rights, stimulating supervision vitality, ensuring a power balance, and playing a pivotal monitoring role. However, these findings fail to explain the collusion among major shareholders and the use of excessive control rights to expropriate the interests of minority shareholders. Thus, this paper sheds light on collusion. To the best of our knowledge, no study has systematically explored the potential role of multiple large shareholders in enterprise investment. To fill this gap, this study investigates the impact of multiple large shareholders on absinvestment.

This study employs cash flow rights and the contestability of multiple large shareholders to explore the impact of multiple large shareholders on investment efficiency in the Chinese setting. The empirical study shows a profound positive relationship between both cash flow rights and the contestability of multiple large shareholders and absinvestment levels, demonstrating that multiple large shareholders can significantly increase the absinvestment level of listed companies. The results are robust even after controlling for endogenous problems, making sample adjustments and independent variable substitutions, and exploring different regression models and firm natures. Furthermore, this paper employs the threshold model to study the governance effect of controlling shareholders on multiple large shareholders, which demonstrates that the positive correlation between multiple large shareholders and absinvestment is strengthened by promoting the governance effect of controlling shareholders. We conclude that collusion between controlling shareholders and multiple large shareholders will worsen absinvestment. In addition, the heterogeneity analysis shows that firm nature does not affect the significant positive correlation between the multiple ownership structure and absinvestment, and the influence of a multiple ownership structure on absinvestment is realized through over-investment.

Despite some interesting findings, there are some limitations to this study. One of the most important limitations is that it ignores the influence of the identity of multiple large shareholders and whether they are institutional investors or not. We suspect that the impact on the role of multiple large shareholders varies with identity. Another important issue arising from this paper is that we consider multiple large shareholders as acting in concert. In the Chinese context, although we have reformed the shareholder structure of listed companies, the ownership structure is still concentrated. Therefore, we suspect that the optimal strategy for multiple large shareholders is to act in concert.

Supplementary Material

Supplementary material accompanies this paper.

Supplementary data 1. Database.

Supplementary data 2. Do file.

Yan, Caiyu; Li, Juan, 2023, "Supplementary Data - Multiple large shareholders and absinvestment among Chinese listed firms", https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/CY3V1C, Harvard Dataverse, V1, UNF:6:JKC25yF11L4r7dsVws/hAw== [fileUNF]

  • Evaluation process:

    Double Blind Review
    This article is open data
  • How to cite: Yan, C., & Li, J. (2023). Multiple large shareholders and absinvestment among Chinese listed firms. Revista Brasileira de Gestão de Negócios, 25(2), p.147-165 https://doi.org/10.7819/rbgn.v25i2.4220
  • Financial support:

    This work was supported by the grants from National Natural Science Foundation of China [number 72002071], Natural Science Foundation of Hunan Province [number 2020JJ5110, 2021JJ40183], Outstanding Young Talent Foundation of Education Department of Hunan Province [number 21B0575], and Philosophy and Social Science Foundation of Hunan Province [number 17YBA015].
  • Open Science:

    Yan, Caiyu; Li, Juan, 2023, "Supplementary Data - Multiple large shareholders and absinvestment among Chinese listed firms", https://doi.org/10.7910/DVN/CY3V1C, Harvard Dataverse, V1, UNF:6:JKC25yF11L4r7dsVws/hAw== [fileUNF].
  • Copyrights:

    RBGN owns the copyrights of this published content.
  • Plagiarism analysis:

    RBGN performs plagiarism analysis on all its articles at the time of submission and after approval of the manuscript using the iThenticate tool.

REFERENCES

  • Aggarwal, R. K., & Samwick, A. A. (2006). Empire-builders and shirkers: Investment, firm performance, and managerial incentives. Journal of Corporate Finance, 12(3), 489-515. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2006.01.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2006.01.001
  • Agrawal, A., & Knoeber, C. R. (1996). Firm performance and mechanisms to control agency problems between managers and shareholders. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 31(3), 377-397. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2331397
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2331397
  • Allen, F., Qian, J., & Qian, M. (2005). Law, finance, and economic growth in China. Journal of Financial Economics, 77(1), 57-116. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.06.010
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.06.010
  • Almeida, H. V., & Wolfenzon, D. (2006). A theory of pyramidal ownership and family business groups. The Journal of Finance, 61(6), 2637-2680. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.01001.x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2006.01001.x
  • Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., & Guedhami, O. (2009). Do multiple large shareholders play a corporate governance role? Evidence from East Asia. Journal of Financial Research, 32(4), 395-422. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.2009.01255.x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1475-6803.2009.01255.x
  • Attig, N., El Ghoul, S., Guedhami, O., & Rizeanu, S. (2013). The governance role of multiple large shareholders: Evidence from the valuation of cash holdings. The Journal of Management and Governance, 17(2), 419-451. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10997-011-9184-3
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10997-011-9184-3
  • Bae, K., Baek, J., Kang, J., & Liu, W. (2012). Do controlling shareholders’ expropriation incentives imply a link between corporate governance and firm value? Theory and evidence. Journal of Financial Economics, 105(2), 412-435. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.02.007
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2012.02.007
  • Bena, J., & Ortizmolina, H. (2013). Pyramidal ownership and the creation of new firms. Journal of Financial Economics, 108(3), 798-821. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.01.009
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2013.01.009
  • Ben-Nasr, H., Boubaker, S., & Rouatbi, W. (2015). Ownership structure, control contestability, and corporate debt maturity. Journal of Corporate Finance, 35, 265-285. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2015.10.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2015.10.001
  • Bharath, S. T., Jayaraman, S., & Nagar, V. (2013). Exit as governance: An empirical analysis. The Journal of Finance, 68(6), 2515-2547. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12073
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/jofi.12073
  • Boateng, A., & Huang, W. (2017). Multiple large shareholders, excess leverage and tunneling: Evidence from an emerging market. Corporate Governance, 25(1), 58-74. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/corg.12184
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/corg.12184
  • Boubaker, S., & Sami, H. (2011). Multiple large shareholders and earnings informativeness. Review of Accounting and Finance, 10(3), 246-266. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/14757701111155789
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/14757701111155789
  • Cheng, M., Lin, B., & Wei, M. (2013). How does the relationship between multiple large shareholders affect corporate valuations? Evidence from China. Journal of Economics and Business, 70, 43-70. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconbus.2012.12.003
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconbus.2012.12.003
  • Demsetz, H., & Lehn, K. (1985). The structure of corporate ownership: Causes and consequences. Journal of Political Economy, 93(6), 1155-1177. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261354
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/261354
  • Ding, Y., Zhang, H., & Zhang, J. (2007). Private vs state ownership and earnings management: Evidence from Chinese listed companies. Corporate Governance, 15(2), 223-238. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2007.00556.x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2007.00556.x
  • Dyck, A., & Zingales, L. (2004). Private benefits of control: An international comparison. The Journal of Finance, 59(2), 537-600. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00642.x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2004.00642.x
  • Edmans, A., & Manso, G. (2011). Governance through trading and intervention: A theory of multiple blockholders. Review of Financial Studies, 24(7), 2395-2428. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhq145
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhq145
  • Faccio, M., & Lang, L. H. (2002). The ultimate ownership of Western European corporations. Journal of Financial Economics, 65(3), 365-395. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(02)00146-0
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(02)00146-0
  • Faccio, M., Marchica, M., & Mura, R. (2011). Large shareholder diversification and corporate risk-taking. Review of Financial Studies, 24(11), 3601-3641. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhr065
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhr065
  • Filatotchev, I., Stephan, J., & Jindra, B. (2008). Ownership structure, strategic controls and export intensity of foreign-invested firms in transition economies. Journal of International Business Studies, 39(7), 1133-1148. http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400404
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8400404
  • García-Meca, E., García-Sánchez, I.-M., & Martínez-Ferrero, J. (2015). Board diversity and its effects on bank performance: An international analysis. Journal of Banking & Finance, 53, 202-214. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.12.002
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.12.002
  • Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. The American Economic Review, 76, 323-329.
  • Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305-360. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X
  • Jiang, F., Cai, W., Wang, X., & Zhu, B. (2018). Multiple large shareholders and corporate investment: Evidence from China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 50, 66-83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2018.02.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2018.02.001
  • Jiang, G., Lee, C. M., & Yue, H. (2010). Tunneling through intercorporate loans: The China experience. Journal of Financial Economics, 98(1), 1-20. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.05.002
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jfineco.2010.05.002
  • Johnson, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2000). Tunneling. The American Economic Review, 90(2), 22-27. http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.2.22
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.90.2.22
  • Konijn, S. J., Kräussl, R., & Lucas, A. (2011). Blockholder dispersion and firm value. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(5), 1330-1339. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2011.06.005
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2011.06.005
  • La Porta, R., Lopezdesilanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world. The Journal of Finance, 54(2), 471-517. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00115
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0022-1082.00115
  • Laeven, L., & Levine, R. (2008). Complex ownership structures and corporate valuations. Review of Financial Studies, 21(2), 579-604. http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhm068
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhm068
  • Lemmon, M. L., & Lins, K. V. (2003). Ownership structure, corporate governance, and firm value: Evidence from the East Asian financial crisis. The Journal of Finance, 58(4), 1445-1468. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1540-6261.00573
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/1540-6261.00573
  • Li, J., & Tang, Y. (2010). CEO hubris and firm risk taking in China: The moderating role of managerial discretion. Academy of Management Journal, 53(1), 45-68. http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amj.2010.48036912
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.5465/amj.2010.48036912
  • Liu, Y., Miletkov, M. K., Wei, Z., & Yang, T. (2015). Board independence and firm performance in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 30, 223-244. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2014.12.004
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2014.12.004
  • Maury, B., & Pajuste, A. (2005). Multiple large shareholders and firm value. Journal of Banking & Finance, 29(7), 1813-1834. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2004.07.002
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2004.07.002
  • Mishra, D. R. (2011). Multiple large shareholders and corporate risk taking: Evidence from East Asia. Corporate Governance, 19(6), 507-528. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2011.00862.x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8683.2011.00862.x
  • Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. H. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. The American Economic Review, 48, 261-297.
  • Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management ownership and market valuation: An empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 293-315. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(88)90048-7
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(88)90048-7
  • Murphy, K. J. (1985). Corporate performance and managerial remuneration: An empirical analysis. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 7(1-3), 11-42. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90026-6
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90026-6
  • Paligorova, T., & Xu, Z. (2012). Complex ownership and capital structure. Journal of Corporate Finance, 18(4), 701-716. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2012.05.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2012.05.001
  • Peng, W. Q., Wei, K. J., & Yang, Z. (2011). Tunneling or propping: Evidence from connected transactions in China. Journal of Corporate Finance, 17(2), 306-325. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2010.08.002
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2010.08.002
  • Perryman, A. A., Fernando, G. D., & Tripathy, A. (2016). Do gender differences persist? An examination of gender diversity on firm performance, risk, and executive compensation. Journal of Business Research, 69(2), 579-586. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2015.05.013
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2015.05.013
  • Richardson, S. (2006). Over-investment of free cash flow. Review of Accounting Studies, 11(2-3), 159-189. http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11142-006-9012-1
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11142-006-9012-1
  • Stulz, R. (1990). Managerial discretion and optimal financing policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 26(1), 3-27. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(90)90011-N
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(90)90011-N
  • Su, Y., Xu, D., & Phan, P. H. (2008). Principal: Principal conflict in the governance of the Chinese Public Corporation. Management and Organization Review, 4(1), 17-38. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1740-8784.2007.00090.x
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1740-8784.2007.00090.x
  • Sun, Q., & Tong, W. H. (2003). China share issue privatization: The extent of its success. Journal of Financial Economics, 70(2), 183-222. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(03)00145-4
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(03)00145-4
  • Wang, N. (2009). Optimal consumption and asset allocation with unknown income growth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(4), 524-534. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009.03.005
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2009.03.005
  • Wu, X., & Wang, Z. (2005). Equity financing in a Myers–Majluf framework with private benefits of control. Journal of Corporate Finance, 11(5), 915-945. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2004.04.001
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jcorpfin.2004.04.001
  • Zhang, G. (1998). Ownership concentration, risk aversion and the effect of financial structure on investment decisions. European Economic Review, 42(9), 1751-1778. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(97)00106-2
    » http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0014-2921(97)00106-2

Responsible editor:

Prof. Dr. Jorge Scarpin

Reviewers:

Yun Song; Wentao Yang; Yigui Xiao

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    07 July 2023
  • Date of issue
    Apr-Jun 2023

History

  • Received
    22 Dec 2022
  • Accepted
    24 May 2023
Fundação Escola de Comércio Álvares Penteado Fundação Escola de Comércio Álvares Penteado, Av. da Liberdade, 532, 01.502-001 , São Paulo, SP, Brasil , (+55 11) 3272-2340 , (+55 11) 3272-2302, (+55 11) 3272-2302 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: rbgn@fecap.br