Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Cap-and-trade and project-based framework: how do carbon markets work for greenhouse emissions reduction?

Abstracts

There are two examples of carbon market mechanisms: i ) trading based on the cap-and-trade principle establishes Greenhouse Gases (GHG) emission limits for companies that can negotiate allowance to pollute (as in European Union Emission Trading Scheme, EU ETS) , and ii ) carbon credits, project-based emission reductions of GHG (such as the Clean Development Mechanism of the Kyoto Protocol, CDM). Given the importance of these two, this paper presents the dynamics of the evolution of carbon markets evolution by analyzing different markets (including other examples) and their framework, performances, potential and barriers. Besides these two programs, other national and regional systems are being developed, bu EU ETS and Kyoto stand in terms of volume and visibility. Despite existing criticism, in some countries volume of GHG emissions decreased between 1990 and 2011, probably influenced by the modernization of some formerly obsolete and inefficient industrial plant, and also by the poor performance of world economies in recent years.

Clean Development Mechanism; Kyoto Protocol; Carbon Market; EU ETS; Institutional Economics


Hay dos ejemplos de mercados de carbono: i) cap-and trade, con establecimiento de límites a gases de efecto invernadero (GEI) para empresas, con comercio de Permiso para Emitir (European Union Emissions Trading Scheme), y ii) créditos de carbono basados ​​en proyectos (Mecanismo de Desarrollo Limpio del Protocolo de Kyoto). Este trabajo presenta la dinámica de la evolución de los mercados de carbono mediante el análisis de las estructuras de los mercados existentes, actuaciones, y los posibles obstáculos. Otros sistemas nacionales y regionales para reducir las emisiones se están desarrollando, pero sin embargo, el EU ETS y el mercado de Kyoto todavía se destacan, tanto en volumen como en visibilidad. Además, pese a las críticas existentes, el volumen total de emisiones disminuyó en entre 1990 y 2011, afectado principalmente por la crisis económica mundial, y las mejoras en la tecnología.

Mecanismo de Desarrollo Limpio; Protocolo de Kioto; mercado de carbono; EU ETS; Economía Institucional


Existem dois exemplos de mecanismos de mercado de carbono: i) cap-and-trade, que estabelece limites de emissões de Gases de Efeito Estufa (GEE) às empresas, e baseia-se em licenças para poluir (European Union Emission Trading Scheme - EU ETS), e ii) projetos de reduções de emissões de GEE, que baseia-se em certificados de carbono com base em reduções (Mecanismo de Desenvolvimento Limpo do Protocolo de Kyoto - MDL). Este artigo apresenta a dinâmica da evolução dos mercados de carbono, analisando comparativamente diferentes estruturas de mercados existentes, desempenhos, barreiras e potencialidades. Outros sistemas de redução de emissões nacionais e regionais estão sendo desenvolvidos, no entanto, o EU ETS e o mercado decorrente de Kyoto ainda se destacam, tanto em volume quanto em visibilidade. Apesar das críticas existentes, o volume global de emissões de alguns países decresceu comparativamente entre 1990 e 2011, principalmente afetado pela crise econômica global, e pelas melhorias de tecnologias obsoletas.

Mecanismo de Desenvolvimento Limpo; Protocolo de Kyoto; Mercado de Carbono; EU ETS; Economia Institucional


Introduction

Climate Change is the most pressing environmental concern that humanity has faced in recent decades. Scientific research on climate offers increasing evidence that human activities are largely responsible for increasing concentration of greenhouse gases (GHG) in the atmosphere, leading to climate change (IPCC, 2008GODOY, Sara Gurfinkel M. O Protocolo de Kyoto e o Mecanismo de Desenvolvimento Limpo: uma avaliação de suas possibilidades e limites. PUC-SP, 2005. Dissertação (Mestrado) -Pontifícia Universidade Católica de São Paulo.).

While there is still disagreement within the scientific community, the thesis that prevails, especially in international forums, is the "precautionary principle," which recommends that, although there is no absolute certainty about a certain phenomenon, the world should take measures to protect against the possible damage that may occur. The decision about which are the most appropriate actions to minimize the effects of climate change is a controversial issue, hotly debated by the parties involved.

Despite uncertainties, increased consciousness of the effects of higher GHG levels has resulted in public and private policies which aim to reduce emissions of gases, such as the creation of carbon markets. In this context, it is possible to highlight two examples: emission permit trade, following the principle of cap-and-trade (European Emission Trade Scheme); and carbon credit from deployment of emission reduction projects, with a focus on emission reduction (Clean Development Mechanism). These two systems are attempts to solve environmental problems using economic tools, as opposed to tax policies.

Carbon trading is relatively innovative, but the concept is usually couched in technical language based on international law, which is consequently not always easily understood. As a result, studies generally incorporate ideas and concepts in a discrete manner, which hinders applicability. From this background, the aim of this paper is to present the dynamic evolution of carbon markets, analyzing the main existing structures worldwide and their performance, comparing different carbon markets. Furthermore, this work seeks to analyze greenhouse gas emissions reduction by country and compare to targets.

The theoretical basis of this work is Institutional Economics, since one of the central points of this theory is focused on the importance of institutions and organizations in establishing an efficient market. The article surveys the theoretical contribution to carbon markets, presenting an introductory approach related to some theories of carbon markets and economic theories; it also presents a comparative, mainly of carbon markets; and analyses global GHG emission reduction against goals.

Economic theories and carbon markets

Nobel Prize-winner Ronald Coase proposed a new way to analyze this problem in the 1960s, through the critique of the Welfare Theory contained in his article "The social cost problem" (Coase, 1960). The author argues that GHG emission rights should be treated as property rights, and that those rights could be transferred using market tools. Property rights are intended to internalize externalities when the gains of internalization outweigh the costs. Market certificates for reducing emissions of greenhouse gases through a clear definition of property rights proposes to internalize this externality (Mueller, 2002IPCC. Introduction to the Intergovermental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2008. Diversos documentos. Retrievedfrom<http://www.ipcc.ch >. Access in: Jul 2008.
http://www.ipcc.ch...
).

Addressing imposed environmental taxes, Coase argues that the public authority is not without its flaws, such as corporate interests, lack of information, and political pressure. The author contrasts market failures with government failures. In the same line as the Chicago School - and contrary to classical economic models - the author states that private solutions usually involve lower costs.

Negative externality is a market failure related to the degradation of natural resources, defined as costs to others that result from particular actions, even if they have not contributed to the harm. Emissions of greenhouse gases are an example of negative externality, as they cause harm to others, even if they are not responsible for the emissions. According to some Economics theories, the resource allocation deviation justifies government regulation, through command and control measures and taxation (Varian, 1994). Pigou (1920) presents the creation of taxes as a solution to negative externalities (Pigouvian taxes) in an amount equivalent to the cost (benefit) of the externality generated. Such a solution - the principle of paying polluter - has been adopted by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD).

This logic gave birth to a theoretical line called the New Institutional Economics, which proposes that the state should create conditions, through the definition of property rights, for economic agents to freely negotiate so-called "environmental goods," such as air pollution reduction. Carbon trading has at its core the logic advocated by Coase, insofar as it enables a tool aimed at the ownership of a free asset, based on transactions of emissions permits or carbon emissions reduction certificates.1

Transaction costs are resources allocated to coordinate the production of goods, such as: drafting of contracts; obtaining new information on the product and competitors; bargaining; conducting negotiations; and process monitoring. When property rights are not well defined, there may be a loss of benefits, and externalities may not be efficiently internalized, and if transaction costs are zero it is preferable that agents negotiate the goods freely (Coase, 1960 ; North, 1994; Williamson, 1985).

Transaction costs are present in every deployment stage of an emission reduction project, such as in the preparation of the initial presentation of the project contract; validation; approval; registration; monitoring process; certification; and in the issuance of emission reduction certificates. These costs are consequences of uncertainty, asymmetric information, the need for drafting contracts, and bureaucratic costs.

Considering the different theories on direct government intervention versus the free market, some authors propose to incorporate both. One example is a pollution control policy including emission permits, with a limited number of emissions assigned to a specific group (or groups) within a sector (or sectors). This system avoids the imposition of a regulatory authority, to set emission levels on business and industry or to determine the most appropriate technology to be used (Nusdeo, 2008MAY, Peter H.; LUSTOSA, Maria C.; VINHA, V. de (org.). Economia do meio ambiente: teoria e prática. Rio de Janeiro:Elsevier, 2003.).

Historically, creating a market for certified emission reductions of GHG stems from the concept of tradable emissions permits (cap-and-trade), initially formulated by Dales in 1968 and later developed by Montgomery (1972)INTERNATIONAL EMISSON TRADING ASSOCIATION, IETA. Diversos documentos. Retrievedfrom: <www.ieta.org>. Access in: Jul 2005.
www.ieta.org...
, Tietenberg (1985)POINT CARBON. CDM & JI Monitor 14 de Junho de 2005. Retrieved from: <http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=9195&categoryID=261&PHPSESSID=e22e8b1adc69395fdef99e8d538f8531>. Access in: Jul 2005a.
http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?a...
, and Baumol and Oates (1988). But the concept of emissions trade as a strategy for pollution control was first proposed by Crocker (1966) and further developed by Montgomery (1972).

The academic literature presents three basic systems of tradable emissions: the environmental permit system (focused on the exposure to emissions at the reception point), the emissions permit system (focused on emissions sources), and the pollution offset system (combining features of the previous two). With respect to regulating the sale of certificates, four programs stand out: offset policy, bubble policy, netting policy, and emission banking (Almeida, 1998; May, 2003).

The offset policy, created by the Environment Protection Agency (EPA) in the 1980s, is a new program that allows polluting plants to settle in regions where air quality does not meet appropriate environmental standards. However, this is possible only if the new emissions are offset by a reduction of existing pollution sources in other regions. Rather than impose a rigid zoning law barring expansion of activities in the area, the entry of new firms is permitted, provided that local environmental quality is not undermined.

The bubble policy, also created by the EPA in the 1980s, is a mechanism that treats multiple emission points of existing polluting plants in a given area as if encased in a bubble. The total gas emitted in a particular region is controlled, and as long as values remain below this limit companies can still pollute. Participants can negotiate emissions reductions among themselves.

The netting or net emissions policy sets both a limit and a fixed number of certificates that participants can acquire to achieve their goals. From these boundaries, companies are free to increase or decrease their emissions as long as the net growth of emissions does not exceed the pre-determined ceiling. Emissions banking, in turn, enables companies to store or sell reduction certificates or permits for use in reductions in the offset, bubble, and netting policies (Almeida, 1998; May, 2003; Pindyck & Rubinfeld, 1994MUELLER, Bernardo. Direitos de propriedade na nova economia das instituições e em direito e economia. Revista de direito mercantil, industrial, econômico e financeiro. Faculdade de Direito da USP. Departamento Comercial. Vol.126, abr-jun 2002).

Global carbon markets

There is no carbon market defined by a single commodity, by a single contract. What is commonly called the "carbon market" is a collection of various transactions through which volumes of GHG emission reductions are traded, and which differ with respect to size, shape, and regulations. These transactions can also be separated into Kyoto compliance and non-Kyoto compliance: that is, whether the carbon credits meet the parameters set by the Kyoto Protocol or not.

Clean Development Mechanism

The Clean Development Mechanism stems from the establishment of the Kyoto Protocol, which introduced economic tools to help compliance parties meet the objectives and principles established under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). Based on first Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) in 1990, the General Assembly of the United Nations established the Intergovernmental Committee of Negotiation, responsible for development of the UNFCCC. A document was presented on the Convention in 1992, during the United Nation Conference on the Environment and Development (UNCED), known as Rio-92.

Following negotiations, the member countries of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), and economies in transition (Russian Federation and other countries in Central and Eastern Europe) agreed to adopt national policies and measures to reverse greenhouse gas emissions to about 5 percent below 1990 levels by the year 2000. After the initial commitments on reducing greenhouse gases was agreed at UNFCCC, an ongoing process and regular discussions were established to exchange information about scientific research, including technological progress and possible new interest in making policies and agreements. This continuous process led to the creation of the Conference of the Parties (COP), the supreme body of the Convention and highest decision-making authority, whose meetings have occurred annually from 1995 to the present day. The 3rd Conference, held between December 1 and 12, 1997 in Kyoto, Japan, gave rise to the Kyoto Protocol (UNFCCC, 1997).

To facilitate compliance with these reduction targets, the Protocol established flexibility mechanisms, by which an Annex I country can exceed its emissions limit without increasing global net emissions, provided that there is an equivalent reduction in another country.

An Annex I country has two alternatives for achieving the targets and using them according to its cost-benefit analysis: invest in more efficient technologies in terms of GHG emissions in their own countries, or use the flexibility mechanisms, leveraging the lower costs of deploying projects in other countries. However, countries with commitments under Kyoto Protocol must meet their targets primarily through national measures.

There are three flexible mechanisms: Joint Implementation (JI), Emissions Trading (ET), and the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM).ii Joint Implementation allows industrialized countries to offset their emissions and sinks by participating in projects in other Annex I countries.iii The Emissions Trading policy delineates transactions relating to GHG emissions among Annex I Parties. Finally, and directly affecting developing countries, is the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM), through which industrialized countries can meet their reduction commitments by investing in low-emission projects in developing countries (UNFCCC, 1997)​​.

The first commitment period of Kyoto Protocol ended in 2012. However, during COP 17, in 2011, a new compromise was agreed to establish a second Kyoto Protocol stage based on the following assumptions: the establishment of a formal provision for a second commitment period of the Kyoto Protocol (post-2012); the launch of the Green Climate Fund to expand long-term financing to developing countries; and the establishment of a formal clause for an action plan that results in a global agreement on climate change (Durban Platform for Enhanced Action), to be defined in 2015 and enter into force in 2020.

The last meeting, in Doha, 2012, saw the adoption of the "Doha Amendment to the Kyoto Protocol," including new commitments for Annex I Parties, establishing a second commitment period from January 2013 to December 2020, and other measures updating some articles of Kyoto Protocol.

According to these new specifications established for the second commitment period, Annex I countries agreed to reduce emissions of greenhouse gases by at least 18 percent below 1990 levels in the period between the years 2013-2020. On the downside, Japan, Canada, New Zealand, and Russia said they would not participate in the next Kyoto commitment period, which jeopardizes the success of the second period but did not derail the continuity of established rules.

European Union Emissions Trading Scheme - EU ETS

The first large emissions trading market, the UK Emissions Trading Scheme (UK ETS) was developed in 2002, through an auction of 4,028,176 tCO2e. In 2007 this program ceased its activities, but it led to the creation of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS), which began operating in January 2005. The first phase of compliance with reductions lasted from 2005 to 2007; the second from 2008 to 2012, coinciding with the first commitment period of the Kyoto Protocol; and the third will span from 2013 to 2020 (DECC, 2012; Defra, 2005; UK, 2005).

The European market initially emerged to help countries meet the targets set by the Kyoto Protocol. The EU ETS Commission created a Linking Directive, which functions as a regulatory regime that determines the relationship between Kyoto Protocol and EU ETS. The Linking Directive allows institutions included in the EU ETS to use Clean Development Mechanisms (CDM) carbon credits to meet their commitments (Ieta, 2005; Point Carbon, 2005c; World Bank, 2005 _________________. Carbon Market Insights 2007. Published at Point Carbon's 4th annual conference. Retrieved from: <http://www.pointcarbon.com>. Access in: Apr 2007.
http://www.pointcarbon.com...
b).

Each European member state develops a National Allocation Plan (NAP) that establishes the amount of GHG emission allowances (EUAs), which are permits distributed to their industries and power plants. It is up to each company to adjust its polluting profile to remain within the established quota; if it exceeds this limit, it can buy permits, and if it is below, it can sell them. Covering about 12,000 facilities in the first phase, the scheme included the energy, metal and steel, pulp and paper, cement, and ceramics and glass sectors.

Since 2012 some changes were incorporated into the program, such as the inclusion of the aviation sector, and the entrance of Norway, Iceland, and Liechtenstein. Other greenhouse gases are being proposed, such as CO2 from petrochemicals, ammonia, and aluminum; Adipic N2O, nitric and glycolic acid; perfluorocarbons from the aluminum sector; CO2 capture, transport, and geological storage. Another set emission limits for countries, aiming to reduce these by 1.74% per year until 2020. There will also be a substantial increase in the number of licenses to be auctioned (from below 4% in 2013 to a goal of over 50%) (DEFRA, 2012Department For Environment Food And Rural Affair (DEFRA).Emission Trading Schemes. ETS.Retrieved from: <http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/ >. Access in: Jul 2005.
http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/clim...
; WORLD BANK, 2012_________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. Lead author Alexandre Kossoy.Washington DC, May, 2012. Retrieved from: <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/State_and_Trends_2012_Web_Optimized_19035_Cvr&Txt_LR.pdf>. Access in: Oct 2012.
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCA...
).

Table 1 shows the main differences and similarities of the EU ETS and Clean Development Mechanism.

Table 1
Comparative characteristics in CDM and EU ETS.

Other markets

The Certified Emission Reduction Unit Procurement Tender (CERUPT) results from the Dutch government's interest in investing in CDM projects through the purchase of Certified Emission Reductions. They also created the Emission Reduction Unit Procurement Tender (ERUPT), similar to the CERUPT program, but directed at the Joint Implementation projects (CERUPT, 2005CARBON TRADE. CERUPT: the Netherlands' CDM Programme.Retrieved from: <http://www.carbontradewatch.org/projects/CERUPT.doc>. Access in: agosto de 2005.
http://www.carbontradewatch.org/projects...
).

In 2011, new initiatives for regional and domestic carbon markets gained strength in both developed and developing countries. Three new cap-and-trade schemes were approved in national laws, and two in state laws. Mexico is laying the foundation for a future cap-and-trade scheme, as are Quebec and China. A successful example is New Zealand, which was the first country outside the EU to approve and implement its own emissions trading scheme, active since 2010, and is a rapidly growing market, whose carbon value has tripled to US $351 million in 2011 (WORLD BANK, 2012_________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. Lead author Alexandre Kossoy.Washington DC, May, 2012. Retrieved from: <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/State_and_Trends_2012_Web_Optimized_19035_Cvr&Txt_LR.pdf>. Access in: Oct 2012.
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCA...
).

In 2011, the cap-and-trade regulation in California was adopted by the California Air Resources Board (CARB). It shall come into force in 2013 and, with a coverage expansion scheduled for 2015, will cover 85% of annual emissions. In late 2011 the Australian Parliament passed its Clean Energy Act, establishing a national cap-and-trade system in 2015. The program should cover about 60% of the 600 million tonnes of CO2e emitted annually in the country. Quebec, accounting for 12% of GHG emitted annually in Canada, approved its own cap-and-trade plan, and aims to link it to the California plan.

The large number of programs around the world demonstrates that there is a worldwide mobilization to use the market as a tool for solving the GHG emission problem. Many reduction schemes have more aggressive targets than Kyoto, but they follow precepts defined in the Protocol.

GHG countries, and carbon markets overview

The 1990-2011 inventory of CO2 emissions from Annex I countries showed a decrease of 13.61% in total emissions (from 17,693 MtCO2e to 15,284 MtCO2e), including the Land Use, Land Use Change and Forestry (LULUCF) sector.iv The largest reductions were observed in Eastern European countries, probably influenced by the modernization of their formerly obsolete and inefficient industrial plant, but also by the poor performance of world economies in recent years.

Despite the overall drop, many countries showed a significant increase in emissions, such as Turkey, Canada, Australia, and Spain (including LULUCF). Countries showing the highest reductions were: Russian Federation, UK, Poland, and Germany (Graph 1). What can be concluded is that global emissions were reduced overall, but mainly due to the economic crisis of recent years (WORLD BANK, 2012_________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. Lead author Alexandre Kossoy.Washington DC, May, 2012. Retrieved from: <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/State_and_Trends_2012_Web_Optimized_19035_Cvr&Txt_LR.pdf>. Access in: Oct 2012.
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCA...
; UNFCCC, 2013).

Graph 1
Anexo I countries with higher emissions in CO2e between 1990 and 2011 (CO2e)

Carbon Market performance

Carbon credit buyers (or buyers on behalf of buyers) can basically be divided into categories: multilateral institutions; agencies that act as intermediaries, buying on behalf of governments (as in the case of Austria, Belgium, and Denmark); development banks, such as those in Japan and Germany, also buying on behalf of buyers; and other commercial enterprises. Some of the major carbon credit participants are investment funds, such as the ones financed by the World Bank and the Netherlands Government.

Reflecting the global crisis and uncertainty about emission reduction actions, carbon credit prices have fallen in recent years, especially in 2011 and 2012 (Table 2). The drop in certificate prices resulting from CDM projects was higher than that observed on the EU ETS market, especially by virtue of lower risk to investors in European Market (WORLD BANK, 2012_________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. Lead author Alexandre Kossoy.Washington DC, May, 2012. Retrieved from: <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/State_and_Trends_2012_Web_Optimized_19035_Cvr&Txt_LR.pdf>. Access in: Oct 2012.
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCA...
).

Table 2
Average of carbon credit price, secondary market (US $/tCO2e)

The estimated average price of certified emission reductions (CERs) fell from $11.8 in 2010 to US $10.9 in 2011. In addition, the difference between the certificate price of the EU ETS and the CDM increased, mainly due to uncertainty about the resulting acceptance of carbon credits from CDM implementation after 2012 (Table 2).

China tops the ranking of countries that sell CERs (87% of the primary market), while Latin America, which in 2005 had 20% of CER contracts in the primary market, represented only 2% in 2011 (equal to 2010). African countries stood out in 2011, with an increase in their share to 21% of issued CERs, influenced mainly by increased interest in claims by buyers of CDM projects in LDCs. Organizations in the United Kingdom (followed by Switzerland) dominated the purchase of primary CER market in 2011, accounting for 26% of transactions (World Bank, 2008, 2012).

An important fact to note is the decreased demand for carbon credits, a result of oversupply in the market, uncertainties about the future of the carbon market, and the global economic crisis. Even in this context, there was an increase of 17% in the total volume of carbon credits traded from 2010 to 2011 (Table 3). This growth was influenced by increased hedging and portfolio adjustments by participants benefitted from the fall in the prices of carbon credits.

Table 3
Value and volume traded in carbon markets

The EU ETS remains the main global carbon market, reaching a volume of US $148 billion in emission permits sold in 2011, an 11% increase over 2010. In terms of trading volume, the increase was 27 % (Table 3). The lower growth in value can be explained by a drop in prices. It is important to note that global emission reduction targets that were achieved, including EU ETS and Kyoto, were probably more as a result of weak global economic performance than effective actions to reduce emissions adopted by countries (Graphic 2). The fact that reduction targets of GHG emissions have been achieved demonstrates the necessity to increase reduction targets of countries involved (EU ETS, 2012; UNFCCC, 2012, WORLD BANK, 2012_________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. Lead author Alexandre Kossoy.Washington DC, May, 2012. Retrieved from: <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/State_and_Trends_2012_Web_Optimized_19035_Cvr&Txt_LR.pdf>. Access in: Oct 2012.
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCA...
).

Graph 2
Emission reduction targets, and real emission reduction as of 2012 (Kyoto Protocol)

Despite the growth of the carbon market resulting from the implementation of CDM projects (Graphic 3), which also reflects an increase in overall volume of carbon trading (Table 2), there are many difficulties in implementing a Clean Development Mechanism project. Researches related to the carbon market, such as the World Bank (2012) and Point Carbon (2012), indicate that as a result of excess carbon emissions credits buyer interest outweighs that of sellers, leading to the imposition of clauses restrictive to sellers, who bear most of the risk of the project. Another problem is related to the lack of carbon credit buyers in the early stages of the CDM cycle, mainly due to the fact that many governments are gradually migrating to the secondary carbon trade instead of primary markets.

Graph 3
Number of CDM projects registered (global)

CDM also faces difficulties from a micro point of view. Barriers related to markets that have been noted by holders of CDM projects are: failures in the calculations required to determine the emission reductions; difficulties in drafting contracts; problems of poor choice of definition of methodology employed in the project; and excessive requirements to implement a CDM. Other barriers are financial costs related to the CDM cycle such as registration fees and audit costs (Godoy, 2011ECOSYSTEM MARKET PLACE. Backgrounder: Kyoto Protocol: Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI). 2005a. Retrieved from: <http://ecosystemmarketplace.net/pages/marketwatch.backgrounder.php?market_id=10&is_aggregate=0>. Access in: Jul2005.http://www.decc.gov.uk/en/content/cms/emissions/ccas/uk_ets/uk_ets.aspx. DECC, 2012.
http://ecosystemmarketplace.net/pages/ma...
).

CDM also faces difficulties from a micro point of view. Barriers related to markets that have been noted by holders of CDM projects are: failures in the calculations required to determine the emission reductions; difficulties in drafting contracts; problems of poor choice of definition of methodology employed in the project; and excessive requirements to implement a CDM. Other barriers are financial costs related to the CDM cycle such as registration fees and audit costs (Godoy, 2011).

In an attempt to reduce the transaction cost problems in CDM implementation and simplify the deployment process, UNFCCC has created a mechanism called programmatic CDM, or Program of Activities (PoA). Through these programs, it is possible for different projects to have only one contract and one request for registration with the Executive Committee, provided that have some common features (like similar activities, region, or project type). Despite the progress reflected in the number of ongoing projects (240 registered in 2013), the mechanism is still incipient (UNFCCC, 2013, WORLD BANK, 2012_________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. Lead author Alexandre Kossoy.Washington DC, May, 2012. Retrieved from: <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/State_and_Trends_2012_Web_Optimized_19035_Cvr&Txt_LR.pdf>. Access in: Oct 2012.
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCA...
).

Conclusion

Global warming is part of a complex field of understanding, covering different and often conflicting interests, both in terms of understanding and combating climate change. Fulfilling GHG emission reduction targets requires international cooperation, taking into account political, social, and economic factors related to every interested country. The issue of global warming raises many questions, because of the uncertainty about the measurement of its effects and the real damage they can wreak on societies.

Even now, some researchers within the global scientific community - albeit a minority -reject the existence of global warming. Others reject the argument that the warming is mostly caused by human activities rather than natural factors, and some even argue contrary to the IPCC reports.

Despite the lack of consensus, studies on climate change have intensified in recent decades, with a huge breakthrough in climate science research in the areas of observation, modeling, and in the treatment of uncertainty. Discussions on global warming have begun to take on wider dimensions: environmental, economic, political, and social. As a way of dealing with the problem of growth in greenhouse gas emissions, carbon markets have emerged as an attempt to define emissions property rights. Carbon credit trade is a tool that allows countries to comply with the fulfillment of their emissions reduction targets.

The existing carbon markets have many points in common with institutions, rules, and similar organizations, but they also have different characteristics. The first definitions of the emission reduction market were mostly set in the 1970s, and refer to economic logic inherited from Institutional Economics, which indicates the need to define property rights when externalities exist. Markets are influenced by many factors, and although there are basic assumptions common to all, some are more relevant than others. Despite the emergence of different programs, the CDM resulting from the Kyoto Protocol and the European Trade Scheme are highlighted, both in trading volume, visibility, and institutional structure. However, despite the importance of these two programs, recent years have seen increasing growth of national and regional policies in order to reduce GHG emissions.

Although the trading volume of carbon credits from Kyoto is not so relevant, the Protocol has created unique tools to achieve emission reduction objectives, known as flexible mechanisms, which allow the joint participation of various stakeholders with or without emissions reduction targets. These instruments can serve as an incentive for international cooperation, by promoting investment and joint action between developing and developed countries. Although there is criticism related to Kyoto and other carbon markets, it is important to highlight an important feature, that before any decision is made or a new rule is amended, it is necessary to have consensus among all signatory countries. Thus, agreeing on emission reduction targets and other proposed reduction rules is a broad and complex challenge given the large number of participating countries.

Market mechanisms are adversely affected by different factors, resulting in lower effective trading volume compared to the potential. These reasons could be summarized as low prices of carbon credits in the short term, uncertainty, and economic crisis. On the other hand, some measures could benefit these markets and contribute to greater efficiency, such as: adoption of more ambitious reduction targets reaching a larger number of countries; improvements in market regulations; decrease of transaction costs; and spreading existing information. Despite not having reached its full growth potential, carbon market mechanisms are now established and continue to develop. With a growing number of regional emission reduction programs a new paradigm emerges: how to standardize different carbon markets in order to reduce information asymmetry and uncertainties.

Bibliographical references

  • BANCO MUNDIAL. Banco Mundial e as mudanças climáticas, 2005.Retrieved from: <http://www.bancomundial.org/temas/resenas/clima.htm>. Access: Jun 2005.
    » http://www.bancomundial.org/temas/resenas/clima.htm
  • BOLSA MERCANTIL E FUTUROS, BM & F. Projetos para redução de emissões e desenvolvimento são debatidos na BM & F. Retrieved from: <http://www.bmf.com.br/2004/pages/imprensa1/destaques/2005/julho/DestaqueAgropauta.asp>. Access in: Jul 2012.
    » http://www.bmf.com.br/2004/pages/imprensa1/destaques/2005/julho/DestaqueAgropauta.asp
  • CARBON TRADE. CERUPT: the Netherlands' CDM Programme.Retrieved from: <http://www.carbontradewatch.org/projects/CERUPT.doc>. Access in: agosto de 2005.
    » http://www.carbontradewatch.org/projects/CERUPT.doc
  • CHICAGO CLIMATE EXCHANGE, CCX. Diversos documentos. Retrieved from: <http://www.chicagoclimatex.com >. Access in: Jul 2012.
    » http://www.chicagoclimatex.com
  • COASE, R. (1960) The Problem of Social Cost, Journal of Law and Economics, October, pp. 1-44
  • CONEJERO, Marco. Seqüestro de Carbono: uma solução para o problema de externalidades. FEA-USP, 2003. Monografia - Faculdade de Economia, Administração e Contabilidade da Universidade de São Paulo.
  • CONVENÇÃO QUADRO DAS NAÇÕES UNIDAS SOBRE MUDANÇA DE CLIMA - CQNUMC. Protocolo de Kyoto à Convenção sobre Mudança do Clima, 1997. Editado e traduzido pelo Ministério da Ciência e Tecnologia - MCT com o apoio do Ministério das Relações Exteriores.Retrieved from: <http://www.mct.gov.br/clima/quioto/protocolo.htm>. Access in: Oct 2004.
    » http://www.mct.gov.br/clima/quioto/protocolo.htm
  • _________________. O acordo de Marraqueche, 2001. Tradução conjunta Ministério da Ciência e Tecnologia - MCT e Ministério das Relações Exteriores. Retrieved from: <http://www.mct.gov.br/clima/negoc/cop7.htm >. Access in: Oct 2004.
    » http://www.mct.gov.br/clima/negoc/cop7.htm
  • _________________. Quadro das Nações Unidas sobre Mudança do Clima. Publicado pela Unidade de Informações sobre Mudança do Clima (PNUMA) (IUC) em nome do Secretariado Permanente da Convenção. Editado e traduzido pelo Ministério da Ciência e Tecnologia - MCT com o apoio do Ministério das Relações Exteriores. Retrieved from: <http://www.mct.gov.br/clima/convencao.htm >. Access in: Nov 2004a.
    » http://www.mct.gov.br/clima/convencao.htm
  • Department For Environment Food And Rural Affair (DEFRA).Emission Trading Schemes. ETS.Retrieved from: <http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/ >. Access in: Jul 2005.
    » http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/
  • ECOSYSTEM MARKET PLACE. Backgrounder: Kyoto Protocol: Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and Joint Implementation (JI). 2005a. Retrieved from: <http://ecosystemmarketplace.net/pages/marketwatch.backgrounder.php?market_id=10&is_aggregate=0>. Access in: Jul2005.http://www.decc.gov.uk/en/content/cms/emissions/ccas/uk_ets/uk_ets.aspx. DECC, 2012.
    » http://ecosystemmarketplace.net/pages/marketwatch.backgrounder.php?market_id=10&is_aggregate=0
  • FRANGETTO, Flavia W.; GAZANI, Flavio R. Viabilização do Mecanismo de Desenvolvimento Limpo (MDL) no Brasil. O Protocolo de Kyoto e a Cooperação internacional. Instituto Internacional de Educação no Brasil, Editora Fundação de Peirópolis. 2002.
  • GODOY, Sara Gurfinkel M. O Protocolo de Kyoto e o Mecanismo de Desenvolvimento Limpo: uma avaliação de suas possibilidades e limites. PUC-SP, 2005. Dissertação (Mestrado) -Pontifícia Universidade Católica de São Paulo.
  • _________________ Uma análise do mercado mundial de certificados de carbono. Revista de Pós Graduação em Ciências Socias da UFRN Cronos, Natal, Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Norte, v. 10, n. 2, p.77-99, Jul/Dez 2009.
  • _________________ . Protocolo de Kyoto e os países em desenvolvimento: uma avaliação da utilização do mecanismo de desenvolvimento limpo. 2011. Tese (Doutorado) - Programa de Pós-Graduação em Ciência Ambiental (PROCAM) da Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, São Paulo, Brasil, 2011.
  • INTERNATIONAL EMISSON TRADING ASSOCIATION, IETA. Diversos documentos. Retrievedfrom: <www.ieta.org>. Access in: Jul 2005.
    » www.ieta.org
  • IPCC. Introduction to the Intergovermental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC). 2008. Diversos documentos. Retrievedfrom<http://www.ipcc.ch >. Access in: Jul 2008.
    » http://www.ipcc.ch
  • MAY, Peter H.; LUSTOSA, Maria C.; VINHA, V. de (org.). Economia do meio ambiente: teoria e prática. Rio de Janeiro:Elsevier, 2003.
  • MAY, Peter H. Avaliação integrada da economia do meio ambiente:Propostas Conceituais e Metodológicas. In: ROMEIRO, A. R.;REYDON, B. P.; LEONARDI, M.L.A. Economia do meio ambiente: teoria, políticas e gestão de espaços regionais. Campinas: Unicamp/IE, 1997.
  • MONTGOMERY, David. JOURNAL OF ECONOMIC THEORY 5, m-a8 (1972) Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs* W. DAVID Division of the Humanities and Social Sciences, California Institute of Technology,Pasadena, California 91109 Received May 19, 1972.
  • MUELLER, Bernardo. Direitos de propriedade na nova economia das instituições e em direito e economia. Revista de direito mercantil, industrial, econômico e financeiro. Faculdade de Direito da USP. Departamento Comercial. Vol.126, abr-jun 2002
  • NUSDEO, A. M. O. Retrieved from: http://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1060&context=yls_sela
    » http://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1060&context=yls_sela
  • OLIVEIRA, Sonia Dias. In: VEIGA, José. Aquecimento global: frias contendas científicas. Ed SENAC, 2008.
  • PEREIRA, André S. Do Fundo ao Mecanismo: Gênese, características e perspectivas para o Mecanismo de Desenvolvimento Limpo; ao encontro ou de encontro à equidade? Tese de mestrado do Programa de Planejamento Energético/COPPE/UFRJ, 2002. Retrieved from: <http://www.ppe.ufrj.br >. Access in: Mar 2005.
    » http://www.ppe.ufrj.br
  • PINDYCK, R. S.; RUBINFIELD, D. L. Microeconomia. 4ª edição. São Paulo: Makron Books, 1994.
  • POINT CARBON. CDM & JI Monitor 14 de Junho de 2005. Retrieved from: <http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=9195&categoryID=261&PHPSESSID=e22e8b1adc69395fdef99e8d538f8531>. Access in: Jul 2005a.
    » http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=9195&categoryID=261&PHPSESSID=e22e8b1adc69395fdef99e8d538f8531
  • _________________. CDM & JI Monitor 19 de abril de 2005. Retrieved from: <http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=8166&categoryID=261>. Access in: Jul 2005b.
    » http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=8166&categoryID=261
  • _________________. CDM & JI Monitor 31 de maio de 2005. Retrieved from: <http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=8841&categoryID=261&PHPSESSID=df83282d73ba24a56a5ba2dd75e2c9e7>. Access in: Jul2005c.
    » http://www.pointcarbon.com/article.php?articleID=8841&categoryID=261&PHPSESSID=df83282d73ba24a56a5ba2dd75e2c9e7
  • _________________. Carbon Market Insights 2007. Published at Point Carbon's 4th annual conference. Retrieved from: <http://www.pointcarbon.com>. Access in: Apr 2007.
    » http://www.pointcarbon.com
  • RIBEIRO, Wagner Costa. Patrimônio ambiental brasileiro. São Paulo:Editora da Universidade de São Paulo e Imprensa Oficial do Estado de São Paulo, 2003.
  • RIBEIRO, W. C. A ordem ambiental internacional. 1. ed. São Paulo: Contexto, 2001.
  • SISTEMA DE INFORMAÇÃO AMBIENTAL SOBRE MEIO AMBIENTE - SIDDAMB, 1997. Retrieved from: <http://www.diramb.gov.pt/data/basedoc/TXT_LI_1966_1_0001.htm>. Access in: Jul 2005.
    » http://www.diramb.gov.pt/data/basedoc/TXT_LI_1966_1_0001.htm
  • TIETENBERG, Tom (2003). The Tradable-Permits Approach to Protecting the Commons: Lessons for Climate Change. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19 (3):400-419.
  • UNITED KINDGOM. Department for Environment, Food & Rural Affairs. UK emissions trading scheme. 2002. Retrieved from: <http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/index.htm>. Access in: Jul 2005.
    » http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/index.htm
  • UNITED NATIONS FRAMEWORK CONVENTION ON CLIMATE CHANGE (UNFCCC). Baseline and monitoring methodologies. Retrieved from: <http://cdm.unfccc.int/methodologies>. Access in: Jul 2005a.
    » http://cdm.unfccc.int/methodologies
  • _________________. Request Issuance of CER. Retrieved from: <http://cdm.unfccc.int/Projects/pac/ar_howto/Register/Issuance>. Access in: Jul 2005b.
    » http://cdm.unfccc.int/Projects/pac/ar_howto/Register/Issuance
  • _________________. Retrieved from: <http://cdm.unfccc.int>. Access in: Nov 2006.
    » http://cdm.unfccc.int
  • _________________.Retrieved from: < http://cdm.unfccc.int >. Diversosdocumentos. Access in: Jul 2012.
    » http://cdm.unfccc.int
  • _________________. Retrieved from:http://unfccc.int/ghg_data/ghg_data_unfccc/time_series_annex_i/items/3814.php. Access in: Dec 2013.
    » http://unfccc.int/ghg_data/ghg_data_unfccc/time_series_annex_i/items/3814.php
  • WORLD BANK. Estimating Potential Market for Clean Development Mechanism. Retrieved from: <http://carbonfinance.org.doc>. Access in: Jun 2005.
    » http://carbonfinance.org.doc
  • WORLD BANK. Estimating Potential Market for Clean Development Mechanism. Retrieved from: <http://carbonfinance.org.doc>. Access in: Jun 2005a.
    » http://carbonfinance.org.doc
  • _________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. 2005b. Retrieved from: <http://carbonfinance.org/pcf/>. Access in: junho de 2005.
    » http://carbonfinance.org/pcf/
  • _________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. 2006. Retrieved from: <http://carbonfinance.org/docs/StateandTrendsMarketUpdateJan1_Sept30_2006.pdf>. Access in: Nov 2006.
    » http://carbonfinance.org/docs/StateandTrendsMarketUpdateJan1_Sept30_2006.pdf
  • _________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. 2007a. Retrieved from: <http://carbonfinance.org/docs/Carbon_Trends_2007-_FINAL_-_May_2.pdf>. Access in: May 2007.
    » http://carbonfinance.org/docs/Carbon_Trends_2007-_FINAL_-_May_2.pdf
  • _________________. Carbon Finance at the World Bank: List of funds. 2007b. Retrieved from:<<http://carbonfinance.org/Router.cfm?Page=Funds&ItemID=24670>. Access in: May 2007.
    » http://carbonfinance.org/Router.cfm?Page=Funds&ItemID=24670
  • _________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. 2008.Retrieved from: <http://carbonfinance.org/docs/Carbon_Trends_2007-_FINAL_-_May_2.pdf>. Access in: May 2008.
    » http://carbonfinance.org/docs/Carbon_Trends_2007-_FINAL_-_May_2.pdf
  • _________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. 2011.Retrieved from: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/StateAndTrend_LowRes.pdf
    » http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/StateAndTrend_LowRes.pdf
  • _________________. State and Trends of the Carbon Market. Lead author Alexandre Kossoy.Washington DC, May, 2012. Retrieved from: <http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/State_and_Trends_2012_Web_Optimized_19035_Cvr&Txt_LR.pdf>. Access in: Oct 2012.
    » http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTCARBONFINANCE/Resources/State_and_Trends_2012_Web_Optimized_19035_Cvr&Txt_LR.pdf
  • Notes

    i Carbon credit, carbon certificate, and emissions reduction certificate is the nomenclature used in this work to generally designate the certificates resulting from the reductions of CO2 emissions, encompassing certified emission reductions (CERs) from the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) and other emissions reduction certificates from other markets. Carbon credits are mesured in tCO2e (tonnes of carbon gases equivalent).
  • ii Certified Emission Reduction (CERs) are carbon credits earned by eligible CDM projects. Emission Reduction Units (ERUs) are carbon credits earned by eligible JI projects.
  • iii Sinks are defined as any process, mechanism, or activity, including the biomass and in particular forests and oceans, which have the property of removing greenhouse gases, aerosols, or GHG precursors from the atmosphere. They may be also other terrestrial, coastal, and marine ecosystems (UNFCCC, 2004).
  • iv LULUCF-Land Use, Land Use Change and Forestry-covers projects related to carbon sequestration by forests, including afforestation and reforestation.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    Jan-Mar 2015

History

  • Received
    26 Sept 2013
  • Accepted
    21 Aug 2014
ANPPAS - Revista Ambiente e Sociedade Anppas / Revista Ambiente e Sociedade - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: revistaambienteesociedade@gmail.com