Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Question of Timing: Pre-Electoral Coalitions in Multiparty Presidential Regimes

Abstract

This paper focuses on the timing of coalition formation under presidential systems. While elections in parliamentary regimes have recently been characterized by a high degree of uncertainty both in the results and the formation of cabinets, this is not the case for presidential politics. As a result, we argue that coalition cycles differ across systems of government. As a matter of fact, we argue that the process of coalition formation under presidentialism is more complicated. To test our claim, we look at forty-four multiparty governments in Latin America and Asia. We find that presidentialism — with its fixed mandate and its specific institutional mechanism for selecting the president — directly affects the ‘coalition life cycle’ and fosters a stronger propensity to pre-electoral agreements.

Timing; coalitions; presidentialism


Although the study of coalition governments was initially restricted to parliamentary settings, research on coalition cabinets in presidential regimes has been mushrooming over the last few years. By and large, the literature can be summarized in the following manner. The first generation of studies was marked by an effort to prove the existence and viability of coalition governments in Latin American presidential polities ( CHASQUETTI, 2001CHASQUETTI, Daniel (2001), Democracia, multipartidismo y coaliciones en América Latina: evaluando la difícil combinación. In: Tipos de presidencialismo y coaliciones políticas en América Latina . Edited by LAZARO, Jorge Luis. Buenos Aires: Clacso. pp. 319-359. ; CHEIBUB et al., 2004CHEIBUB, José Antonio; PRZEWORSKI, Adam, and SAIEGH, Sebastian M. (2004), Government coalitions and legislative success under presidentialism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 34, Nº 04, pp. 565–587. ; DEHEZA, 1998DEHEZA, Grace Ivana (1998), Gobiernos de coalición en el sistema presidencial: América del Sur. In: El presidencialismo renovado: instituciones y cambio político en América Latina. Edited by NOHLEN, Dieter and FERNÁNDES B., Mário. Caracas: Nueva Sociedad. pp. 151-170. ). This was an attempt to respond to the ‘presidentialism versus parliamentarism’ debate ( ELGIE, 2005ELGIE, Robert (2005), From Linz to Tsebelis: three waves of presidential/parliamentary studies? Democratization . Vol. 12, Nº 01, pp. 106-122. ), in which many scholars stated that coalitions would be unstable or undesirable under a multiparty presidential system ( LINZ, 1990LINZ, Juan J. (1990), The perils of presidentialism. Journal of Democracy . Vol. 01, Nº 01, pp. 51–69. ; MAINWARING and SHUGART, 1999MAINWARING, Scott and SHUGART, Matthew Soberg (1999), Presidentialism and democracy in Latin America . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 508 pp.. ). The findings of this first wave showed that coalition governments had made up more than half of Latin American governments since the mid-twentieth century. Having done that, the first generation laid the foundations to bring to the fore that some presidential countries have mainly been governed through coalition governments, as has been the case for Brazil and Chile ( ALBALA, 2016bALBALA, Adrián (2016b), Presidencialismo y coaliciones de gobierno en América Latina: un análisis del papel de las instituciones. Revista de Ciencia Política . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 459–479. ). Following closely, a second wave emerged and explored the structural differences within coalition cabinets under various presidential regimes in light of the accumulated knowledge about their counterparts under parliamentary regimes ( ALTMAN, 2001ALTMAN, David (2001), The politics of coalition formation and survival in multiparty presidential democracies: the case of Uruguay, 1989-1999. Party Politics . Vol. 06, Nº 03, pp. 259-283. ; AMORIM NETO, 2006AMORIM NETO, Octavio (2006), The presidential calculus executive policy making and cabinet formation in the Americas. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 39, Nº 04, pp. 415-440. ; CHASQUETTI, 2008CHASQUETTI, Daniel (2008), Democracia, presidencialismo y partidos políticos en América Latina: evaluando la ‘difícil combinación’. Montevideo: Ediciones Cauce. 187 pp.. ; FREUDENREICH, 2016FREUDENREICH, Johannes (2016), The formation of cabinet coalitions in presidential systems. Latin American Politics and Society . Vol. 58, Nº 04, pp. 80–102. ; MARTÍNEZ-GALLARDO, 2012MARTINEZ-GALLARDO, Cecilia (2012), Out of the cabinet: what drives defections from the government in presidential systems. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 45, Nº 01, pp. 62-90. ; MEIRELLES, 2016MEIRELES, Fernando (2016), Oversized government coalitions in Latin America. Brazilian Political Science Review. Vol. 10, Nº 03, pp. 01–31. ). Finally, the latest generation saw the scope of the analysis spread to a study of coalition formation and cabinet appointments, more specifically focusing on topics such as coalition governance ( ALEMÁN and TSEBELIS, 2011ALEMÁN, Eduardo and TSEBELIS, George (2011), Political parties and government coalitions in the Americas. Journal of Politics in Latin America . Vol. 03, Nº 01, pp. 03-28. ; KELLAM, 2015KELLAM, Marisa (2015), Parties for hire: how particularistic parties influence presidents’ governing strategies. Party Politics . Vol. 21, Nº 04, pp. 515-526. ), conflict management ( HIROI and RENNÓ, 2014HIROI, Taeko and RENNÓ, Lucio (2014), Dimensions of legislative conflict: coalitions, obstructionism, and lawmaking in multiparty presidential regimes. Legislative Studies Quarterly . Vol. 39, Nº 03, pp. 357–386. ; MARTÍNEZ-GALLARDO, 2014MARTINEZ-GALLARDO, Cecilia (2014), Designing cabinets: presidential politics and ministerial instability. Journal of Politics in Latin America . Vol. 06, Nº 02, pp. 03–38. ; RAILE et al., 2011RAILE, Eric D.; PEREIRA, Carlos, and POWER, Timothy J. (2011), The executive toolbox: building legislative support in a multiparty presidential regime. Political Research Quarterly . Vol. 64, Nº 02, pp. 323- 334. ), and ministerial turnover ( CAMERLO and PÉREZ- LIÑÁN, 2015CAMERLO, Marcelo and PÉREZ-LIÑÁN, Aníbal (2015) Minister turnover, critical events, and the electoral calendar in presidential democracies. The Journal of Politics . Vol. 77, Nº 03, pp. 608–619. ).

Notwithstanding the progress made thus far, it is surprising that only a handful of works have raised the ‘when’ question. This issue is quite relevant as the presidential system seems to bring high visibility and predictability to the election results, as the winner of the presidential election automatically becomes the president. The when question becomes even more salient as recent works have shed light on the fact that coalition governance is highly influenced by pre-electoral bargaining: the formation of pre-electoral agreements explains why some coalitions are enduring and others not ( ALBALA, 2021ALBALA, Adrián (2021), When do coalitions form under presidentialism, and why does it matter? A configurational analysis from Latin America. Politics . Vol. 41, Nº 03, pp. 351-370. ), who gets into the cabinet ( FREUDENREICH, 2016FREUDENREICH, Johannes (2016), The formation of cabinet coalitions in presidential systems. Latin American Politics and Society . Vol. 58, Nº 04, pp. 80–102. ), and which status is achieved by the president in the post-electoral scenario ( BORGES et al., 2021BORGES, André; TURGEON, Mathieu, and ALBALA, Adrián (2021), Electoral incentives to coalition formation in multiparty presidential systems. Party Politics . Vol. 27, Nº 06, pp. 1279-1289. ). Moreover, the relative shortage of studies dealing with pre-electoral coalitions in presidential countries runs counter to the current state-of-the-art on coalition theories. Research on coalitions under parliamentarism, for instance, has long paid attention to the issues related to pre-electoral coalitions ( ALLERN and AYLOTT, 2009ALLERN, Elin Haugsgjerd and AYLOTT, Nicholas (2009), Overcoming the fear of commitment: pre-electoral coalitions in Norway and Sweden. Acta Politica . Vol. 44, Nº 03, pp. 259-285. ; DEBUS, 2009DEBUS, Marc (2009), Pre-electoral commitments and government formation. Public Choice . Vol. 138, Nº 01/02, pp. 45-64. ; GOLDER, 2006GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2006), Pre-electoral coalition formation in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 193-212. ). Nonetheless, when explaining the phenomenon of coalition cabinets in presidentialism, the literature implies, more often than not, that coalitions are a product of post-electoral agreements whose principal goal is to grant the president a majority that could not be obtained in the election. The main evidence used to support this argument focused on emphasizing the minority status of the president-elect’s party. However, this contention is potentially out of kilter. This is because the focus on post-electoral multiparty negotiations overlooks that presidential candidates anticipate the bargaining process and coordinate electoral strategies with other parties through the formation of pre-electoral agreements. In exchange for their electoral support in the presidential contest, the coalesced partners receive electoral support in electoral disputes in other arenas ( BORGES et al., 2017BORGES, André; ALBALA, Adrián, and BURTINIK, Lucia (2017), Pathways to nationalization in multilevel presidential systems: accounting for party strategies in Brazil and Argentina. Publius: The Journal of Federalism . Vol. 47, Nº 04, pp. 648–672. ). In this context, even if a president’s party had no majority in parliament, this situation could have derived merely from a bargaining strategy. Put differently, commitments made prior to the elections may be accountable for the presidential status after the results of the polls are set and done. A typical example of this electoral electoral strategy is found in the behavior of the ‘Concertácion’ in Chile, a coalition composed of several center-left and left parties in the first elections following the return of democracy in the country. Such a coalition frequently resorted to the launching of joint party lists and even to the complete withdrawal of candidates from certain parties in some districts in order to sustain the coalitional pact amidst electoral races ( ALBALA, 2016aALBALA, Adrián (2016a), Coalitions gouvernementales et régime présidentiel: Le cas du Cône Sud. Paris: Éditions Universitaires Européennes. 536 pp.. ).

Thus, the first objective of this work is to draw attention to the existence of pre-electoral coalitions and to their impact on coalition formation in presidential countries. The research question here is ‘how does presidentialism shape the formation of coalition cabinets in the post-electoral scenario?’. With that in mind, we aim to show how the temporal bound institutionally imposed by presidential regimes affects the timing of coalition formation. In so doing, we contribute to the literature by reinforcing that there are different levels of ‘earliness’ in the timing of coalition formation, ranging from fully pre-electoral to fully post-electoral coalitional pacts ( ALBALA, 2021ALBALA, Adrián (2021), When do coalitions form under presidentialism, and why does it matter? A configurational analysis from Latin America. Politics . Vol. 41, Nº 03, pp. 351-370. ). Overall, our findings show that pre-electoral coalitions are far from being the exception in presidentialism. In fact, they tend to be the precursor of coalition governments.

Our second goal in this paper is to address the selection bias that remarkably afflicts most comparative research on coalitional presidentialism. Although pivotal to our understanding of coalition cabinets under presidential settings, the excessive focus on the Latin American cases casts a shadow on presidential coalition cabinets elsewhere. The bright side, though, is that some studies have started to fill this gap by taking into account coalition governments in presidential countries other than those located in Latin America ( ARIOTTI and GOLDER, 2018ARIOTTI, Margaret H. and GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2018), Partisan portfolio allocation in African democracies. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 51, Nº 03, pp. 341–379. ; CHAISTY et al., 2014CHAISTY, Paul; CHEESEMAN, Nic, and POWER, Timothy (2014), Rethinking the ‘presidentialism debate’: conceptualizing coalitional politics in cross-regional perspective. Democratization . Vol. 21, Nº 01, pp. 72-94. ; HANAN, 2012HANAN, Djayadi (2012), Making presidentialism work: legislative and executive interaction in Indonesian democracy. Doctoral thesis . Graduate Program in Political Science. Ohio State University. ; KIM, 2011KIM, Youngmi (2011), The politics of coalition in Korea: between institutions and culture. London: Routledge. 224 pp.. ). To keep down on a similar path, this work takes the first step to looking simultaneously at the formation of coalition governments in both Asian and Latin American countries.

The remainder of this work proceeds as follows. The first section discusses how presidentialism introduces new elements to the study of coalitions. This discussion feeds into the second section, in which we highlight that presidential regimes have a coalition life cycle of their own, as opposed to the circular cycle found in coalition governments in parliamentary regimes. In particular, we focus on the inception of coalition agreements. More specifically, we outline different stages of ‘earliness’ in the timing of coalition agreements, with different binding impacts among the coalition players. The next section engages in a more empirical perspective and probes how coalition governments are spread across the coalitional cycle based on a sample of forty-four coalition cabinets in Asia and Latin America formed as soon as the presidents were sworn into office. The results point out that the vast majority of coalition governments are tailored prior to the elections. In Set-Theoretic terminology, the findings allow us to argue that pre-electoral commitments could even be labeled as a necessary condition for the formation of coalition governments in presidentialism. The paper concludes by advancing the importance of the presidential coalition life cycle to future studies on coalitional presidentialism.

The presidential factor

Apart from some recent works ( FREUDENREICH, 2016FREUDENREICH, Johannes (2016), The formation of cabinet coalitions in presidential systems. Latin American Politics and Society . Vol. 58, Nº 04, pp. 80–102. ; KELLAM, 2017KELLAM, Marisa (2017), Why pre-electoral coalitions in presidential systems? British Journal of Political Science. Vol. 47, Nº 02, pp. 391-411. ; SPOON and WEST, 2015SPOON, Jae-Jae and WEST, Karleen Jones (2015), Alone or together? How institutions affect party entry in presidential elections in Europe and South America. Party Politics . Vol. 21, Nº 03, pp. 393–403. ), studies on coalition formation are commonly based on the rational assumption that players have perfect information about everyone’s strength and position, both of which would become evident the day after the election. This approach to coalition formation does not work well for presidential systems.

According to the presidential vs. parliamentary debate initiated by Linz (1990)LINZ, Juan J. (1990), The perils of presidentialism. Journal of Democracy . Vol. 01, Nº 01, pp. 51–69. , there are three main differences between these two regimes. First, in presidential systems, the direct election of the head of government (who is at the same time the head of state) by popular vote1 1 In the United States, the president is elected indirectly via an electoral college, as in Argentina until 1983. is seen as a zero-sum game. The election works through the immediate selection – or after a second round, if necessary – of a winner among all candidates. The winner is the only actor in charge of forming a government ( CHEIBUB, 2007CHEIBUB, José Antonio (2007), Presidentialism, parliamentarism and democracy . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 224 pp.. ; MARTÍNEZ-GALLARDO, 2014MARTINEZ-GALLARDO, Cecilia (2014), Designing cabinets: presidential politics and ministerial instability. Journal of Politics in Latin America . Vol. 06, Nº 02, pp. 03–38. ); also, no government can be formed without the president’s party ( KELLAM, 2015KELLAM, Marisa (2015), Parties for hire: how particularistic parties influence presidents’ governing strategies. Party Politics . Vol. 21, Nº 04, pp. 515-526. ). Hence, presidential elections operate as a cleaver, leading to a bipolarisation of the competition between winners and potential winners vs. losers ( BORGES and TURGEON, 2017BORGES, André and TURGEON, Mathieu (2017), Presidential coattails in coalitional presidentialism. Party Politics . Vol. 25, Nº 02, pp. 192-202. ).

To illustrate this concept, we use a triad game ( Figure 01 ), in which a president-elect from party ‘A’ may form a government with party ‘B’ or party ‘C’. In very rare and improbable cases, we can find a ‘Grand Coalition’ unifying A, B, and C altogether. It can be seen that a BC government excluding A is logically impossible once the president-elect cannot be precluded from her own government unless the legislature initiates an impeachment process and successfully removes the president from her post.

Figure 01
Cabinet possibilities under presidentialism

Secondly, the election of the president (either simultaneous with legislative elections or not) does not depend on parliamentary bargaining ( CHEIBUB et al., 2014CHEIBUB, José Antonio; ELKINS, Zachary, and GINSBURG, Tom (2014), Beyond presidentialism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 44, Nº 03, pp. 515-544. ). The president’s legitimacy derives from her own election. This does not mean that the president rules alone, however. Where there is a case of a coalition cabinet, the president is thus constrained by a coalition agreement in order to keep her legislative basis.

Finally, yet importantly, under presidentialism, the mandate of the head of the executive is temporally fixed. This means that even if the president loses her majority in congress, she remains in office until the next election, which takes place following a constitutionally-mandated time schedule2 2 According to Linz (1990) , temporally-fixed mandates are the main reason why presidentialism is prone to instability, in addition to being a constraint on coalition formation since the president does not ‘need’ a majority to remain in office. . This presidential feature may potentially diminish the bargaining strength of coalition partners by reducing their ‘walk away value’ ( LUPIA and STRØM, 2008LUPIA, Arthur and STRØM, Kaare (2008), Coalition governance theory: bargaining, electoral connections and the shadow of the future. In: Cabinet and coalition bargaining: the democratic life cycle in Western Europe . Edited by STRØM, Kaare, MÜLLER, Wolfgang C. and BERGMAN, Torbjörn. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 51-83. ). Since the departure of any member of the coalition does not lead to the fall of the government immediately, parties may think twice before stepping back and ultimately getting out empty-handed from the cabinet, losing access to pork and influence on policies ( BORGES et al., 2017BORGES, André and TURGEON, Mathieu (2017), Presidential coattails in coalitional presidentialism. Party Politics . Vol. 25, Nº 02, pp. 192-202. ; MARTÍNEZ-GALLARDO, 2012MARTINEZ-GALLARDO, Cecilia (2012), Out of the cabinet: what drives defections from the government in presidential systems. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 45, Nº 01, pp. 62-90. ).

At the same time, the presidential mandate’s principle of fixity concerns not only the termination but also the beginning of the mandate. This is tantamount to saying that the process of cabinet formation under a presidential system is limited in time, running from the proclamation of the result of the election to the president assuming office, which is generally fixed by the constitution. As such, the cabinet must be formed by the day the president assumes office. This is quite different from the procedure found in parliamentary regimes, where, broadly speaking, the bargaining rounds for government formation begin after the election and are (theoretically) unlimited ( CHEIBUB et al., 2015CHEIBUB, José Antonio; MARTINS, Shane, and RASCH, Bjørn Eric (2015), Government selection and executive powers: constitutional design in parliamentary democracies. West European Politics . Vol. 38, Nº 05, pp. 969-996. ; GOLDER 2015GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2015), Government formation and cabinets. In: Emerging trends in the social and behavioral sciences . Edited by SCOTT, Robert A.; KOSSLYN, Stephen Michael, and BUCHMANN, Marlis. London: John Wiley & Sons Inc. pp. 01-15. , 2010GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2010), Bargaining delays in the government formation process. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 43, Nº 01, pp. 03-32. ). As an unintended consequence of this trait, the absence of a temporal bound in government formation under parliamentarism contributes to blurring the lines between clear ‘winners’ and hinders the responsiveness of ‘unexpected’ coalitions3 3 Di Rupo Government in Belgium is a typical example of how a bargaining delay can lead to an 'unexpected' coalition. In 2010-2011, negotiations to form a coalition in Belgium lasted more than a year, during which the country was ruled by a caretaker government. This struggle in forming a government is not a Belgium idiosyncrasy, as demonstrated recently by the UK (2010), Italy (2018, 2013), Ireland (2020, 2016), Spain (2016), and Israel (2020-2019); moreover, the later composition of these governments raises the question of the responsiveness of these governments. In 2020, for instance, would a Fine Gael voter have been pleased to see her party forming a government led again by Sinn Féin in Ireland? This question gains more prominence as the coalition options for the competing parties matter to voters when they are casting their vote ( BLAIS et al., 2016) . ( GLASGOW et al., 2012GLASGOW, Garret; GOLDER, Matt, and GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2012), New empirical strategies for the study of parliamentary government formation. Political Analysis. Vol. 20, pp. 248-270. ).

Hence, the separation of powers and the fixity of the mandate (for both its beginning and its conclusion) constitute definite constraints that have a significant impact on the formation, development, and conclusion of coalitions. Furthermore, since the president is, by definition, the ‘formateur’, the coalition options are more limited in presidential regimes. This feature leads to a quite restricted dimension of ‘willingness’ to form coalitions ( CHEIBUB et al., 2015CHEIBUB, José Antonio; MARTINS, Shane, and RASCH, Bjørn Eric (2015), Government selection and executive powers: constitutional design in parliamentary democracies. West European Politics . Vol. 38, Nº 05, pp. 969-996. ; KELLAM, 2015KELLAM, Marisa (2015), Parties for hire: how particularistic parties influence presidents’ governing strategies. Party Politics . Vol. 21, Nº 04, pp. 515-526. ; STRØM, 1990STRØM, Kaare (1990), Minority g overnement and majority rule . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 304 pp.. ) around the president-elect or prominent presidential candidates.

In addition, majoritarian electoral systems are supposed to be more prone to electoral coalitions due to the narrowing of viable contestants (BLAIS et al . , 2016; GLASGOW et al., 2012GLASGOW, Garret; GOLDER, Matt, and GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2012), New empirical strategies for the study of parliamentary government formation. Political Analysis. Vol. 20, pp. 248-270. ; GOLDER, 2015GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2015), Government formation and cabinets. In: Emerging trends in the social and behavioral sciences . Edited by SCOTT, Robert A.; KOSSLYN, Stephen Michael, and BUCHMANN, Marlis. London: John Wiley & Sons Inc. pp. 01-15. , 2006GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2006), Pre-electoral coalition formation in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 193-212. ). As presidential elections are by nature majoritarian, with only one possible winner in a single constituency, we can expect this form of election to have an impact on coalition formations. By the same token, scholars have stressed that ‘ballotage’ is a strong coalition constraint, since, after selecting two finalists among all the candidates, the first-round losers must ‘choose’ among the finalists in order to maximize their possibilities to be part of the next government ( CHASQUETTI, 2008CHASQUETTI, Daniel (2008), Democracia, presidencialismo y partidos políticos en América Latina: evaluando la ‘difícil combinación’. Montevideo: Ediciones Cauce. 187 pp.. ; MAINWARING and SHUGART, 1999MAINWARING, Scott and SHUGART, Matthew Soberg (1999), Presidentialism and democracy in Latin America . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 508 pp.. ; McCLINTOCK, 2018McCLINTOCK, Cynthia (2018), Reevaluating runoffs in Latin America. Journal of Democracy . Vol. 29, Nº 01, pp. 96-110. ).

It is fair to say that presidentialism is a widespread form of government in Latin America. Given this, the concern for the region should not come as surprising. After all, it seems natural to conduct research on a region marked by similar institutional traits. However, much of the literature on presidential coalition cabinets has dealt ‘only’ with Latin American countries. In these circumstances, our current knowledge of coalitional presidentialism suffers from a severe regional case selection bias.

The lack of studies on Asia has wrongly suggested that coalition governments under presidential settings are not found in this region. Nevertheless, in stark contrast to this notion, multiparty governments have been found in Indonesia, Maldives, the Philippines, and South Korea4 4 It is worth noting that the accurate definition of the South Korean form of government is an open issue in the literature ( KIM, 2008) . While some scholars assign South Korea to the set of presidential countries ( BORGES and RIBEIRO, 2021 ; CHEIBUB, 2007 ; SEDELIUS and LINDE, 2018) , others prefer to label South Korea as a semi-presidential regime ( KIM, 2011, 2008) , 2008 ). . As a matter of fact, since the re-establishment of presidential competitive and direct elections, Indonesia has been governed solely by coalition cabinets.

The interest in Asian governing coalitions is reinforced since there are both similarities and differences between Asian presidential regimes and those in Latin America (on which much knowledge has been accumulated). As an example of the former, let us take the finding that the formation of pre-electoral agreements is relevant to explaining enduring coalitions ( ALBALA, 2021ALBALA, Adrián (2021), When do coalitions form under presidentialism, and why does it matter? A configurational analysis from Latin America. Politics . Vol. 41, Nº 03, pp. 351-370. ). To a certain extent, Kim Dae-jung’s government in South Korea confirms such a claim. Prior to the 1997 presidential election, the NCNP (National Congress for New Politics) had made an early electoral agreement with the ULD (United Liberal Democrats). Indeed, the pre-electoral coalition, comprised of the NCNP and the ULD, turned out to be the winner of the presidential election in 1997; also, even though the new government was plagued by extensive deadlocks in the legislature, the initial coalition pact remained intact5 5 Even though the party composition of the coalition did not change, the NCNP changed its name to MDP (New Millennium Democratic Party) at the beginning of 2000 ( KIM, 2008) . until September 2001, covering approximately 70% of Kim Dae-jung’s presidential term ( KIM, 2011KIM, Youngmi (2011), The politics of coalition in Korea: between institutions and culture. London: Routledge. 224 pp.. ). By contrast, other patterns in the region are at loggerheads with the current presidential coalition theories. For instance, previous scholarship has suggested that presidential cabinets are unlikely to include parties that presented a strong candidate in the previous presidential election ( FREUDENREICH, 2016FREUDENREICH, Johannes (2016), The formation of cabinet coalitions in presidential systems. Latin American Politics and Society . Vol. 58, Nº 04, pp. 80–102. ). Much to the contrary, though, this has been a deep trend in Indonesian politics ( HANAN, 2012HANAN, Djayadi (2012), Making presidentialism work: legislative and executive interaction in Indonesian democracy. Doctoral thesis . Graduate Program in Political Science. Ohio State University. ). For illustrative purposes, the PD (Democratic Party) won the 2004 and 2009 presidential elections. In both, the Golkar Party had received a fair share of votes and finished with the third most voted candidate. Notwithstanding its electoral appeal, the Golkar Party was still invited to take a seat in both multiparty cabinets. In a similar vein, the 2019 Indonesian presidential election consisted of a dispute between two pre-electoral coalitions. On the one hand, there was a coalition led by the PDI-P (Indonesian Democratic Party of Struggle); on the other hand, the one advanced by the Gerindra (Great Indonesia Movement Party). In the end, Widodo (PDI-P) came out victorious and was sworn into office soon afterward. More curiously, though, the Gerindra made part of the new cabinet despite arguably being an electoral threat to the president.

In examining both Asian and Latin American coalition cabinets together, we also improve the variability among the cases typically used to study multiparty presidential systems. This can be exemplified by the fact that all four Asian presidential regimes mentioned above have intermediate legislative elections, whereas this very same institutional feature is only found in Argentina and Mexico in Latin America. Moreover, not all presidential countries found in Asia allow presidents to run for reelection – the Philippines and South Korea being examples where the president is ineligible for immediate reelection. In contrast, once we subset our sample only to those countries that have had multiparty cabinets, only Chile, Mexico, and Uruguay do not allow presidents to seek reelection in Latin America 6 6 Chilean and Uruguayan former presidents can run for non-consecutive presidential terms, but they are forbidden to seek immediate reelection. .

Finally, a further consequence of bridging the existing gap between Asian and Latin American literature is bringing novel elements to Asian-centered studies. To the best of our knowledge, the bulk of studies on Asian presidential coalition cabinets disregards comparative research designs in preference to case studies. As a result, Asian scholarship on coalitional presidentialism also suffers from a certain degree of provincialism.

Having said that, Figure 02 illustrates the presidential timing constraint and shows the constitutional lapse between election day and the day the president assumes office, for Asian and Latin American polities that are under a presidential system and experienced coalition cabinets. Although the average lapse ranges from 1.4 to 2.9 months, this value does not reflect the disparity among the cases. Indeed, the Uruguayan presidents-elect have five months to form their cabinet before taking office (four if the election came after a ‘ballotage’). At the opposite end of the scale, Argentina’s and Bolivia’s presidents-elect have the shortest lapse to form their cabinet: from 0.5 to 1.5 months, again depending on the need for a run-off.

Figure 02
Lapse between election day/ Inauguration day of the president

Note: We inserted in black the lapse between the first, or unique, election round and the inauguration of the mandate. We inserted in grey the lapse between the second election round and the day presidents are sworn into office.


Note that run-off conditions vary according to the respective Constitution. In our dataset, nine out of twelve polities include it in their electoral system. The extent of the lapse between the first and the second round of the election is worth noting: from a couple of weeks (Maldives), a month (Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Colombia, and Uruguay) to a month and a half (Chile, Ecuador, and Indonesia). On the other hand, only three countries resort to the first-past-the-post electoral system for presidential elections: Mexico, the Philippines, and South Korea.

The framing of a coalition cycle

A coalition government presupposes the presence of distinct political forces within the cabinet, each counting with the corresponding support of all their respective members in congress ( STRØM et al., 2008STRØM, Kaare; MÜLLER, Wolfgang C., and BERGMAN, Torbjörn (2008), Cabinet and coalitions bargaining: the democratic life cylce in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 464 pp.. ). This participation must derive from an inter-party agreement. That is, a coalition government is first and foremost the result of a negotiation between two or more parties, a negotiation that requires sufficient strength and mutual commitment on a broad list of topics at different levels (mostly at the executive and legislative levels). The collectivization of these outcomes derives from particular goals expressed as shared positive or negative values7 7 Positive values are described as a convergence among coalesced parties in the direction of a shared political project, whereas negative values are expressed as a shared rejection of a third political actor – the conventional Uruguay case, for instance. , common ambitions of power, policy orientations, and/or aim to achieve re-election. All this engenders a higher exposition to both political and electoral accountability. On these grounds, considering presidential features, coalesced members under presidentialism are thus accountable to both the president and their partisan basis in the legislature ( ALBALA, 2016bALBALA, Adrián (2016b), Presidencialismo y coaliciones de gobierno en América Latina: un análisis del papel de las instituciones. Revista de Ciencia Política . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 459–479. ).

Using this narrow definition, we shall then not consider as ‘coalition cabinets’ 01. governments whose allies consist of co-opted or independent ministers8 8 By saing so, we do not exclude every cabinet that includes non-partisans ministers; instead, we mean that we do not consider non-partisans as distinct ‘coalition partners’. ; 02. governments of a single party comprising several internal factions, irrespective of their degree of autonomy9 9 This is particularly evident in the Uruguayan party system. In spite of its traditional low number of effective parties, Uruguay does have a party system boiled with intraparty differences ( ALTMAN, 2001) . As a result, multiparty governments must deal not only with other parties but also with the internal factions of each of their members ( MAGAR and MORAES, 2012) . Even still, as factions are still tied to broader organizations, namely the political parties, we do not consider single-party governments comprised of different internal factions as fitting the concept of coalition governments. ; 03. governments of a single party as a result of a previous party merger10 10 To exemplify this, prior to the 1992 South Korean presidential election, the winner, the Democratic Liberal Party (DLP), was a product of a merger between three parties: The Democratic Justice Party (DJP) combined with the Unification Democratic Party (UDP) and the New Democratic Republican Party (NDRP) ( KIM, 2008) . Therefore, once there are no longer different party organizations, we shall not consider Kim Young-sam’s government as a government coalition. , and 04. governments formed by a dominant party and ‘satellite’ parties11 11 In these cases, the term ‘party’ is essentially formal. It is a strategy for dominant parties to artificially amplify their parliamentary group by by-passing the electoral law. Senatorial elections in Argentina are a good example. Since the 1994 constitutional reform, every province elects three senators as follows: two senators for the winning list, and one for the first ‘minority’. Thus, in several provinces such as La Rioja or Buenos Aires, the Justicialist Party and its ‘testimonial’ allies frequently win every available seat. .

Following Strøm et al. (2008)STRØM, Kaare; MÜLLER, Wolfgang C., and BERGMAN, Torbjörn (2008), Cabinet and coalitions bargaining: the democratic life cylce in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 464 pp.. , we aim to outline a “coalition life cycle”, which contains all the phases of the coalition process, “from the formalization of the alliance until its termination, shrinking, and/or enlargement” ( STRØM et al., 2008STRØM, Kaare; MÜLLER, Wolfgang C., and BERGMAN, Torbjörn (2008), Cabinet and coalitions bargaining: the democratic life cylce in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 464 pp.. , p. 09) , as exposed in Figure 03 . Thus, any change in the original composition of the coalition (e.g., the entry/exit of a partner) entails the beginning of a new coalition cycle. Moreover, since the focus here is on coalition governments, we do not consider ‘sporadic’ legislative agreements ( CHAISTY et al., 2014CHAISTY, Paul; CHEESEMAN, Nic, and POWER, Timothy (2014), Rethinking the ‘presidentialism debate’: conceptualizing coalitional politics in cross-regional perspective. Democratization . Vol. 21, Nº 01, pp. 72-94. ; RAILE et al., 2011RAILE, Eric D.; PEREIRA, Carlos, and POWER, Timothy J. (2011), The executive toolbox: building legislative support in a multiparty presidential regime. Political Research Quarterly . Vol. 64, Nº 02, pp. 323- 334. ).

Figure 03
The classic – parliamentary – coalition cycle

The formation of a coalition government – and the beginning of a coalition cycle – is intrinsically connected to the occurrence of recent or forthcoming elections, noted as ‘t0’ in Figure 04 .

Figure 04
Timeline of coalition formation

Hence, a coalition government is considered as ‘post-electoral’ (t+1’) when its formation and formalization occur as a result of interparty bargaining in a lapse between the final results of the election and the presidential inauguration. This temporal conception, although obvious and classic, must not disregard the study of informal and unpublicized agreements or the historical and ‘familiar’ links of collaboration ( FRANKLIN and MACKIE, 1983FRANKLIN, Mark N. and MACKIE, Thomas T. (1983), Familiarity and inertia in the formation of governing coalitions in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 13, Nº 03, pp. 275-298. ; GIBSON, 1999GIBSON, John (1999), Political timing a theory of politicians’ timing of events. Journal of Theoretical Politics . Vol. 11, Nº 04, pp. 471–496. ; MOURY, 2011MOURY, Catherine (2011), Coalition agreement and party mandate: how coalition agreements constrain the ministers. Party Politics . Vol. 17, Nº 03, pp. 385–404. ). In these cases, ‘ex post’ coalitions are seen as predictable, natural, or ‘inertial’ ( BLAIS et al., 2016BLAIS, André; GUNTERMANN, Eric, and BODET, Marc A. (2016), Linking party preferences and the composition of government: a new standard for evaluating the performance of electoral democracy. Political Science Research and Method . Vol. 05, Nº 02, pp. 315-331. ; DUCH et al., 2010DUCH, Raymond M.; MAY, Jeff, and ARMSTRONG, David A. (2010), Coalition-directed voting in multiparty democracies. American Political Science Review . Vol. 104, Nº 04, pp. 698-719. ). Similarly, ‘ad hoc’ agreements (noted t+2, t+3 ...) are the result of endogenous events such as the exit of one or more new members of an existing coalition, and/or voluntary and ‘afterthought’ enlargement of an existing coalition, with no real connection to immediate electoral matters.

On the other hand, ‘ex ante coalitions’ are those whose formalization has taken place ‘before’ election day. This type of pre-electoral coalition is thus the product of a public agreement between two or more parties that have consented to share their economic, organizational, and logistical resources to run together in an upcoming election ( GOLDER, 2006GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2006), Pre-electoral coalition formation in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 193-212. , p. 12). This kind of coordination may encompass various aspects (‘united electoral front’, ‘common candidate’, etc), according to greater or lesser binding levels, and noted in Figure 04 as a ‘t -1’ stage. The most conventional form of this kind of agreement is the merger of electoral lists ( GOLDER, 2006GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2006), Pre-electoral coalition formation in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 193-212. ), as a way to maximize the potential of smaller parties.

As a matter of fact, since every election implies previous organization and publicity during the campaign period, a dynamic approach for the study of such alliances should adopt a broader temporal perspective that sets as its starting point not the day before the election but the day before the electoral ‘campaign’ kicks off ( CARROLL and COX, 2007CARROLL, Royce and COX, Gary W. (2007) The logic of Gamson’s Law: pre-election coalitions and portfolio allocations. American Journal of Political Science. Vol. 51, Nº 02, pp. 300-313. , p. 301).

Run-off agreements (noted as ‘t-0.5’ in Figure 04 ) are another typical example of these bargains: they consist of a public call for electoral campaigning between the two rounds of an electoral contest and include a transfer of resources from the eliminated candidate(s) to a contender who qualified for the ‘ballottage’.

Let us also mention two additional pre-electoral types of agreement which suppose a higher commitment. First, the celebration of common primaries for the selection of a single coalition candidate. This requires the concerted organization of a campaign before the electoral campaign and a higher degree of convergence in the organizational and programmatic fields. Secondly, we mention the renewal of the electoral alliance of an incumbent coalition. Because these kinds of commitments occur at an even earlier stage, both are noted as a ‘t -2’ position in Figure 04 .

Finally, pre-electoral coalitions should not be considered as purely static and exclusive. Indeed, some coalition agreements may have had pre-electoral inception (either t-1 or t-2) but for some reason had to redesign their initial agreements to fit new members in post-electoral bargaining, at t+1. The incorporation of new members into an existing ‘core’ alliance can arise, for instance, when the original alliance could not reach a legislative majority in one or both houses, for bicameral cases ( ALBALA, 2017ALBALA, Adrián (2017), Bicameralism and coalition cabinets in presidential polities: a configurational analysis of the coalition formation and duration processes. The British Journal of Politics and International Relations . Vol. 19, Nº 04, pp, 735-754. ). Thus, this scenario points toward a re-opening of the bargaining process, the length and difficulty of which would depend on the political strength of the newcomers ( SPOON and WEST, 2015SPOON, Jae-Jae and WEST, Karleen Jones (2015), Alone or together? How institutions affect party entry in presidential elections in Europe and South America. Party Politics . Vol. 21, Nº 03, pp. 393–403. ).

As a consequence, whereas coalition cycles under parliamentary regimes resemble a perfect circular process, as can be seen in Figure 03 , for presidential regimes, it seems that the coalition cycle is a little more complex, as shown in Figure 05 .

Figure 05
The coalition cycle under presidentialism

Notes: Dotted lines were used to indicate the events consisting in timing eventualities for coalition enlargement.


To sum up, we have set out that coalition formation should not be considered in a merely binary fashion (i.e., either pre- or post- electoral). We should, rather, consider that the coalition cycle may follow previous negotiations (that is the familiarity of the members) and early bind pre-electoral agreements (that is the precocity of the agreements). Indeed, even if pre-electoral agreements are not automatically binding ( KELLAM, 2017KELLAM, Marisa (2017), Why pre-electoral coalitions in presidential systems? British Journal of Political Science. Vol. 47, Nº 02, pp. 391-411. ), political parties and presidents-elect have strong incentives to maintain their electoral promises once they assume office. As a matter of fact, following MOURY (2013MOURY, Catherine (2013), Coalition government and party mandate: how coalition agreements constrain. London: Routledge. 176 pp.. , 2011MOURY, Catherine (2011), Coalition agreement and party mandate: how coalition agreements constrain the ministers. Party Politics . Vol. 17, Nº 03, pp. 385–404. ), we may logically assume that explicit and formal pre-electoral agreements are politically and electorally more constraining than discrete ‘ad hoc’ informal ones. In other words, coalition cabinets should be more responsive and accountable when their formation is clearly identifiable.

Therefore, we propose a classification scheme for all the possible ‘scenarii’ of coalition formation, following their level of earliness and consequent potential binding effect. First, no electoral alliance, merely post-electoral formation (t+1), with a ‘—‘ direction. Secondly, partially constraining coalitions where the ‘core’ group of the cabinet members ran together in the election (t -1 or t -2), but where some new partners joined the cabinet after the election at t+1 (the constraining effect seems limited, ‘+/-‘). Third, run-off agreements, passed at t -0.5, where all the government partners ran separately in the first ‘round’ of the election but joined forces for the run-off (positive expected constraint, ‘+’). Fourth, electoral coalitions, when all the partners of the cabinet ran together during the elections, at t-1, a strong constraining agreement (‘++’). Finally, full pre-electoral agreements, with stronger constraining expectations (+++), when all the partners in the coalition ran together during the elections and celebrated common primaries to select a common candidate, or when an incumbent president ran for re-election with the same partners with whom she was governing (t -2). This scheme is described in Table 01 , below.

Table 01
Classification scheme of the degree of earliness of coalition cabinets and expected binding levels

Now that both the political science literature and the timing patterns for the formation of coalition cabinets have been discussed, we go on to explore the existing empirical data on the timing of coalition formation in Asia and Latin America.

Data on the timing of coalition formation in Asia and Latin America

In light of these arguments, we can assume that the more straightforward the election for ‘selecting’ the head of the government is, the more predictable and identifiable the coalition options are. Furthermore, the more identifiable and recognizable the political options are, the earlier inter-party agreements are reached. As a matter of fact, this argument is not completely original. Indeed, Freudenreich (2016)FREUDENREICH, Johannes (2016), The formation of cabinet coalitions in presidential systems. Latin American Politics and Society . Vol. 58, Nº 04, pp. 80–102. has already shown that pre-electoral commitments tend to foster posterior government formation. The proposal here reverses the question, as we argue that every or most post-electoral coalition cabinets in presidential regimes derive ‘from’ pre-electoral agreements12 12 It could be argued that we are misreading the 'earliness' process of coalition cabinets by choosing our observations based on their value in the dependent variable. In the eyes of the quantitative literature, this approach is one of the most troublesome practices in the social sciences ( GEDDES, 2003 ; KING et al., 1994) . However, this is quite a narrow view since the cases themselves might provide substantial knowledge about the phenomena under study ( RAGIN, 2008 ; RAGIN and RUBINSON, 2009) . Furthermore, we do not aim to generalize our findings to all presidential cabinets. Rather, our focus is on specifying the importance of pre-electoral commitments for forming governments after the elections have taken place. .

For the demonstration, we ranked all forty-four coalition cabinets13 13 As Franco, Temer, and Arroyo I’s coalition cabinets stemmed from the impeachment of the previous administration and, therefore, were not derived from a presidential election, they have been excluded from the analysis. formed in Asia and Latin America since the return of democracy in the late 1980s ( Table 02 ). In this sense, our unit of analysis is presidential coalition governments ‘per se’, as defined in the last section. Importantly, we focus on the first cabinets formed ‘after’ presidential elections since the temporal aspect of coalition cabinets is of special interest to us. Thus, coalitions formed in-between presidents’ tenures are mostly out of the scope of this article, unless they served as the spearhead of a future government. In the final column, we indicated whether these governments followed electoral agreements or not and, consequently, their expected binding level as exposed in Table 01 , above.

Table 2
Electoral and government coalitions in Asia and Latin America

Data come from several sources. For Latin American countries, to check the partisan composition of governments and thus whether they could be correctly labelled as coalition governments14 14 Case studies, such as Albala (2016a) , Amorim Neto and Pimenta (2020) , and Kim (2008) , provided a theoretical basis to rule out a handful of multiparty cabinets because they were not actual coalition cabinets. , we relied primarily on Amorim Neto (2019AMORIM NETO, Octavio (2019), Cabinets and coalitional presidentialism. In: Routledge Handbook of Brazilian Politics . Edited by AMES, Barry. New York: Routledge. pp. 293-312. , 2006AMORIM NETO, Octavio (2006), The presidential calculus executive policy making and cabinet formation in the Americas. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 39, Nº 04, pp. 415-440. ) and Camerlo and Martínez-Gallardo (2017)CAMERLO, Marcelo and MARTÍNEZ-GALLARDO, Cecilia (2017), Government formation and minister turnover in presidential cabinets: comparative analysis in the Americas. London: Routledge. 258 pp.. . The same information for their Asian counterparts was garnered through access to several editions of the Political Handbook of the World15 15 Available at ˂ https://sk.sagepub.com/cqpress/series/political-handbook-of-the-world˃ . . In addition, we retrieved data relative to Latin American pre-electoral coalitions from Borges et al. (2021)BORGES, André; TURGEON, Mathieu, and ALBALA, Adrián (2021), Electoral incentives to coalition formation in multiparty presidential systems. Party Politics . Vol. 27, Nº 06, pp. 1279-1289. , Freudenreich (2016)FREUDENREICH, Johannes (2016), The formation of cabinet coalitions in presidential systems. Latin American Politics and Society . Vol. 58, Nº 04, pp. 80–102. , Kellam (2015)KELLAM, Marisa (2015), Parties for hire: how particularistic parties influence presidents’ governing strategies. Party Politics . Vol. 21, Nº 04, pp. 515-526. , and Lopes (2022)LOPES, Amanda Vitoria (2022), The best of two worlds: selection strategies for vice-presidential candidates. Brazilian Political Science Review . Vol. 16, Nº 01, pp. 01-26. . In a complementary fashion, evidence on Asian pre-electoral coalitions came from case studies, namely Hanan (2012)HANAN, Djayadi (2012), Making presidentialism work: legislative and executive interaction in Indonesian democracy. Doctoral thesis . Graduate Program in Political Science. Ohio State University. , Kim (2011KIM, Youngmi (2011), The politics of coalition in Korea: between institutions and culture. London: Routledge. 224 pp.. , 2008KIM, Youngmi (2008), Intra-party politics and minority coalition government in South Korea. Japanese Journal of Political Science . Vol. 09, Nº 03, pp. 367-389. ), and Teehankee (2020)TEEHANKEE, Julio Cabral (2020), Factional dynamics in Philippine party politics, 1900–2019. Journal of Current Southeast Asian Affairs . Vol. 39, Nº 01, pp. 98-123. , and WikiLeaks16 16 Available at ˂ https://wikileaks.org/˃ . . In case of conflicting information across the different sources, we crosschecked it with data obtained directly from the countries’ respective electoral bodies to ascertain which direction to follow.

Table 02 provides strong empirical evidence that most post-electoral presidential coalition governments are the product of (pre-)electoral coalitions. Indeed, 40/44 (90%) of the post-electoral coalition governments in Asia and Latin America were derived, completely or partially, from pre-electoral agreements. This score is even more substantial when compared to the rate of coalition cabinets deriving from pre-electoral coalitions under parliamentary regimes ( CHIRU, 2015CHIRU, Mihail (2015), Early marriages last longer: pre-electoral coalitions and government survival in Europe. Government and Opposition . Vol. 50, Nº 02, pp. 165-188. ; GOLDER, 2006GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2006), Pre-electoral coalition formation in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 193-212. ; IBENSKAS, 2016IBENSKAS, Raimondas (2016), Understanding pre-electoral coalitions in Central and Eastern Europe. Party Politics . Vol. 46, Nº 04, pp. 743-761. ). More surprisingly, this proportion is practically identical to the 91% ratio of presidential coalition governments resulting from (pre-) electoral commitments when the sample is restricted to Latin American countries. ( ALBALA, 2021ALBALA, Adrián (2021), When do coalitions form under presidentialism, and why does it matter? A configurational analysis from Latin America. Politics . Vol. 41, Nº 03, pp. 351-370. ).

Therefore, we find only four cases of fully post-electoral agreements (10%): Paz Estenssorro, Ramos, Lacalle, and Sanguinetti. However, among those, the two Uruguayan cases may be considered as ‘least-likely cases’, as pre-electoral coalitions were not allowed in Uruguay before the 1997 constitutional reform. Also, the two Uruguayan presidents-elect, Lacalle and Sanguinetti, had already publicly announced during the campaign their intent to form a coalition government with the two main Uruguayan parties (the Colorado Party and the National Party, respectively). These cases are a sort of “inertial but informal agreement” ( FRANKLIN and MACKIE, 1983FRANKLIN, Mark N. and MACKIE, Thomas T. (1983), Familiarity and inertia in the formation of governing coalitions in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 13, Nº 03, pp. 275-298. ), following a long tradition of political and government cooperation between the two parties, or factions of parties ( ALBALA, 2016aALBALA, Adrián (2016a), Coalitions gouvernementales et régime présidentiel: Le cas du Cône Sud. Paris: Éditions Universitaires Européennes. 536 pp.. ). Indeed, even where the agreement was formally made in the lapse between the election and the president taking office – thus officially at a t+1 timing, due to the impossibility of merging at a pre-electoral stage – the path had already been established between the partners before the election, at a t-1 timing.

Hence, there are only two ‘genuine’ occurrences of fully post-electoral formation of presidential coalition cabinets: the bizarre case of Paz Estenssoro’s coalition in Bolivia (1985-1989), and the rather strategic Ramos’ coalition in the Philippines (1995-1998). Firstly, after running in an electoral alliance with the leftist party MIR (Revolutionary Left Movement), once he had been elected, Paz Estenssoro (MNR, Revolutionary Nationalist Movement) rescinded his electoral agreement with MIR and decided to form a coalition cabinet with his main rival during the electoral campaign – the conservative ADN (Nationalist Democratic Action). The other instance is much more ordinary, though. At the beginning of his mandate, Ramos (Lakas, Lakas ng Bansa) opted not to allocate portfolios to any other political parties than his own. However, he changed his mind in order to establish an electoral coalition with the LDP (Laban ng Demokratikong Pilipino) for the 1995 intermediate legislative election ( TEEHANKEE, 2020TEEHANKEE, Julio Cabral (2020), Factional dynamics in Philippine party politics, 1900–2019. Journal of Current Southeast Asian Affairs . Vol. 39, Nº 01, pp. 98-123. ).

The more common configuration is the t+1 one, consisting of presidential coalitions resulting from t-1 or t-2 agreements but fostered by a post-electoral ‘enlargement’ (noted +/-), from which derived 29% (13/44) of the coalition cabinets of our sample. These agreements included a few newcomers ‘after’ the election, especially if they were seeking strong bicameral majority ( ALBALA, 2017ALBALA, Adrián (2017), Bicameralism and coalition cabinets in presidential polities: a configurational analysis of the coalition formation and duration processes. The British Journal of Politics and International Relations . Vol. 19, Nº 04, pp, 735-754. ). However, even in those cases, it is significant that the ‘core members’ usually coalesced ‘before’ the election17 17 An example was the second cabinet of Brazilian President Lula in his first mandate (2003-2006): the late inclusion of the PMDB party a year after the election (that is at a t+2 timing – an example of ‘ad hoc’ coalition) led to a fracture among the ‘core members’ and thus to the exit of the PDT ( FIGUEIREDO, 2007) . . Moreover, it is noteworthy that Brazil and Indonesia account for nine out of the thirteen instances of post-electoral enlargement.

Furthermore, Table 02 shows that common interparty primaries or former coalition cabinets represent up to 22% (10/44) of the cases of coalition governments in Asia and Latin America. The same proportion of presidential coalitions (22%, 10/44) also hails from pure electoral agreements. By coupling these figures, we can grasp that many coalition cabinets in both continents have had a full pre-electoral inception.

Altogether, only a minority of post-electoral coalition governments have not had a sort of pre-electoral conception. If we were to adopt a Set-Theoretic terminology, following which a 0.9 cut-off point is advisable for establishing necessity between conditions ( RAGIN, 2008RAGIN, Charles C. (2008), Redesigning social inquiry: fuzzy sets and beyond. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 240 pp.. ), we could go as far as saying that commitments made before elections are a necessary condition to form coalition governments in presidential regimes18 18 We are indebted to an anonymous reviewer for raising this point. . In other words, barring some exceptions, coalition governments following presidential elections cannot be found in the absence of some kind of pre-electoral multiparty commitment in presidential democracies.

The records also allow us to review the idea of ‘ballotage’ as a strong coalition-maker. In fact, only seven cabinets (17.5%, 7/40) resulted from run-off agreements19 19 We removed the cabinets of Mexico, South Korea, and the Philippines from the sample because their electoral system does not allow for the possibility of a ‘ballottage’. . It is also worth mentioning that under the legal framework of the Bolivian Constitution, in a run-off, Bolivian members of parliament were responsible for electing the president. This situation led to the above-mentioned election of Paz Estenssoro and to the election of Paz Zamora, who – despite coming in third in the national election – was elected due to an agreement with the rightist party led by Hugo Banzer. Either way, we can argue that run-offs do not play such a decisive role in the coalition formation process as was usually argued in the literature.

Further elements deserve more careful thought, despite not appearing in Table 02 . To start with, not all pre-electoral coalitions convert themselves into coalition governments. This is perfectly demonstrated by the Roh Moo-hyun single-party government. Even though Roh Moo-hyun (MDP) had formed a pre-electoral coalition with the PP 21 (People's Power 21) prior to the 2002 presidential election, the agreement between the MDP and PP 21 fell short even before the election took its place ( KIM, 2011)KIM, Youngmi (2011), The politics of coalition in Korea: between institutions and culture. London: Routledge. 224 pp.. . To date, the literature has only tangentially approached this theme as Borges et al. (2021)BORGES, André; TURGEON, Mathieu, and ALBALA, Adrián (2021), Electoral incentives to coalition formation in multiparty presidential systems. Party Politics . Vol. 27, Nº 06, pp. 1279-1289. have contended that coalition governments are often derived from pre-electoral agreements, but they have not ruled out completely the possibility that the commitments could break and lead to single-party cabinets. A similar story occurred in Mexico, where the PAN (National Action Party) did not stick to its end of the bargain and decided not to allocate a single portfolio to its then-electoral partner, the PVE (Ecologist Green Party of Mexico). In this way, we wish to draw attention to the counterargument that pre-electoral coalitions can still be dismantled, notwithstanding the fact that they demand much convergence among the signatory parties.

Closely related, the scholarly literature ought not to disregard discovering which factors lay the foundations for maintaining coalition cabinets, especially those preceded by earlier agreements that could look needless after the distribution of seats in parliament. As an example, in order to win the 2018 Maldivian presidential election, Solih (MDP, Maldivian Democratic Party) had built a comprehensive pre-electoral agreement, including the AP (Adhaalath Party), the JP (Jumhoory Party), and the MRM (Maumoon Reform Movement), in addition, of course, to his own party. However, the president's party obtained a large majority by itself following an intermediate legislative election to the only Legislative House in the Maldives20 20 The MDP (be careful not to mix up with the New Millennium Democratic Party from South Korea) won 65 out of 87 seats in the unicameral Maldivian legislature, while its coalition partners won only five seats. . Yet, the coalition cabinet remained the same, not losing a single member despite the majority the ‘formateur’ party gained from the legislative elections. In brief, a multiparty cabinet was maintained even if a coalition was unnecessary to achieve a majority status in the legislature.

Conclusion: how can these findings be useful?

We agree with Borges et al. (2021)BORGES, André; TURGEON, Mathieu, and ALBALA, Adrián (2021), Electoral incentives to coalition formation in multiparty presidential systems. Party Politics . Vol. 27, Nº 06, pp. 1279-1289. that parties in multiparty presidential systems tend to form early agreements in order to minimize the costs inherent in presidential elections and maximize their chances of obtaining ministerial portfolios and/or the adoption of particular policies. Conversely, we agree with the statement that electoral coalitions do not automatically translate into stable coalition cabinets ( KELLAM, 2017KELLAM, Marisa (2017), Why pre-electoral coalitions in presidential systems? British Journal of Political Science. Vol. 47, Nº 02, pp. 391-411. ; MAINWARING and SHUGART, 1999MAINWARING, Scott and SHUGART, Matthew Soberg (1999), Presidentialism and democracy in Latin America . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 508 pp.. ), yet we have shown that post-electoral coalition cabinets in presidential regimes, when they occur, proceed from electoral coalitions for the most part of the time.

Because cabinet options are quite limited in presidential systems, both visibility and identification ( STRØM, 1990STRØM, Kaare (1990), Minority g overnement and majority rule . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 304 pp.. ) of the options for government compositions appear to be quite predictable. Indeed, presidential elections provide institutional, organizational, and symbolic dimensions with a strong divisive nature, e.g., the ‘pro/anti-incumbent’ effect ( BORGES and TURGEON, 2017BORGES, André and TURGEON, Mathieu (2017), Presidential coattails in coalitional presidentialism. Party Politics . Vol. 25, Nº 02, pp. 192-202. ). As a consequence, presidentialism encourages the beginning of multiparty negotiations ‘prior’ to the realization of elections by default. It is no coincidence that most winning electoral coalitions translate into presidential coalition cabinets. Hence, while coalition cycles under parliamentary regimes feature a circular process, for presidential regimes, it seems to be a little trickier.

The findings presented here should lead scholars to reconsider the coalition process in presidential regimes and focus on two main phenomena that are still neglected by the literature dealing with coalition cabinets and presidentialism. First, the conditions, terms, and contents of the coalition agreements (in terms of policy, office distribution, among others), and their ‘quality’ (detailed/vague, broad/narrow). This aspect has already been the subject of much analysis by scholars studying coalitions under parliamentary regimes (e.g., MOURY, 2013MOURY, Catherine (2013), Coalition government and party mandate: how coalition agreements constrain. London: Routledge. 176 pp.. , 2011MOURY, Catherine (2011), Coalition agreement and party mandate: how coalition agreements constrain the ministers. Party Politics . Vol. 17, Nº 03, pp. 385–404. ), but it has never received adequate attention from studies on presidential regimes, apart from a rare exception ( BORGES et al., 2017BORGES, André; ALBALA, Adrián, and BURTINIK, Lucia (2017), Pathways to nationalization in multilevel presidential systems: accounting for party strategies in Brazil and Argentina. Publius: The Journal of Federalism . Vol. 47, Nº 04, pp. 648–672. ).

Secondly, these findings should broaden our understanding of the survival of coalitions since our five-point typology explicitly establishes that earlier (and not simply ‘early’) coalitions should last longer. This hypothesis has already been tested and verified for coalition cabinets under parliamentary regimes ( CHIRU, 2015CHIRU, Mihail (2015), Early marriages last longer: pre-electoral coalitions and government survival in Europe. Government and Opposition . Vol. 50, Nº 02, pp. 165-188. ), and it has recently received some consideration ( ALBALA, 2021ALBALA, Adrián (2021), When do coalitions form under presidentialism, and why does it matter? A configurational analysis from Latin America. Politics . Vol. 41, Nº 03, pp. 351-370. ; ALBALA et al., 2021ALBALA, Adrián; BORGES, André, and COUTO, Lucas (2021), Pre-electoral coalitions and cabinet stability in presidential systems. The British Journal of Politics and International Relations. Available at ˂https://doi 10.1177/13691481211056852 ˃. Accessed on August, 10, 2022.
https://doi...
); however, it remains an almost virgin field of research.

To conclude, coalitional presidentialism is not restricted to Latin America. Although Latin America is undoubtedly a region of great concern, we cannot rule out that this type of government exists in other regions, such as Asia. Bridging the gap between Asian and Latin American governments is crucial to advancing and testing theories on presidential coalition cabinets. Of course, this entails dealing with some existing singularities of Asian multiparty presidential systems to make fruitful comparisons with their Latin American counterparts. For instance, the political cleavages encountered in Asia do not precisely mirror those found in Latin America ( HANAN, 2012HANAN, Djayadi (2012), Making presidentialism work: legislative and executive interaction in Indonesian democracy. Doctoral thesis . Graduate Program in Political Science. Ohio State University. ; KIM, 2011KIM, Youngmi (2011), The politics of coalition in Korea: between institutions and culture. London: Routledge. 224 pp.. ). However, this is just a side-effect we must deal with to widen the framework of coalition theories on presidential regimes.

References

  • ALBALA, Adrián (2021), When do coalitions form under presidentialism, and why does it matter? A configurational analysis from Latin America. Politics . Vol. 41, Nº 03, pp. 351-370.
  • ALBALA, Adrián (2017), Bicameralism and coalition cabinets in presidential polities: a configurational analysis of the coalition formation and duration processes. The British Journal of Politics and International Relations . Vol. 19, Nº 04, pp, 735-754.
  • ALBALA, Adrián (2016a), Coalitions gouvernementales et régime présidentiel: Le cas du Cône Sud. Paris: Éditions Universitaires Européennes. 536 pp..
  • ALBALA, Adrián (2016b), Presidencialismo y coaliciones de gobierno en América Latina: un análisis del papel de las instituciones. Revista de Ciencia Política . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 459–479.
  • ALBALA, Adrián; BORGES, André, and COUTO, Lucas (2021), Pre-electoral coalitions and cabinet stability in presidential systems. The British Journal of Politics and International Relations. Available at ˂https://doi 10.1177/13691481211056852 ˃. Accessed on August, 10, 2022.
    » https://doi
  • ALEMÁN, Eduardo and TSEBELIS, George (2011), Political parties and government coalitions in the Americas. Journal of Politics in Latin America . Vol. 03, Nº 01, pp. 03-28.
  • ALLERN, Elin Haugsgjerd and AYLOTT, Nicholas (2009), Overcoming the fear of commitment: pre-electoral coalitions in Norway and Sweden. Acta Politica . Vol. 44, Nº 03, pp. 259-285.
  • ALTMAN, David (2001), The politics of coalition formation and survival in multiparty presidential democracies: the case of Uruguay, 1989-1999. Party Politics . Vol. 06, Nº 03, pp. 259-283.
  • AMORIM NETO, Octavio (2019), Cabinets and coalitional presidentialism. In: Routledge Handbook of Brazilian Politics . Edited by AMES, Barry. New York: Routledge. pp. 293-312.
  • AMORIM NETO, Octavio (2006), The presidential calculus executive policy making and cabinet formation in the Americas. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 39, Nº 04, pp. 415-440.
  • AMORIM NETO, Octavio and PIMENTA, Gabriel Alves (2020), The first year of Bolsonaro in office: same old story, same old song? Revista de Ciência Política . Vol. 40, Nº 02, pp. 187-213.
  • ARIOTTI, Margaret H. and GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2018), Partisan portfolio allocation in African democracies. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 51, Nº 03, pp. 341–379.
  • BLAIS, André; GUNTERMANN, Eric, and BODET, Marc A. (2016), Linking party preferences and the composition of government: a new standard for evaluating the performance of electoral democracy. Political Science Research and Method . Vol. 05, Nº 02, pp. 315-331.
  • BORGES, André; ALBALA, Adrián, and BURTINIK, Lucia (2017), Pathways to nationalization in multilevel presidential systems: accounting for party strategies in Brazil and Argentina. Publius: The Journal of Federalism . Vol. 47, Nº 04, pp. 648–672.
  • BORGES, André and RIBEIRO, Pedro Floriano (2021), Presidents, prime ministers and legislative behaviour: the conditional effect of presidential legislative powers on party unity. Government and Opposition. Available at ˂ https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.45 ˃. Accessed on August, 10, 2022.
    » https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.45
  • BORGES, André and TURGEON, Mathieu (2017), Presidential coattails in coalitional presidentialism. Party Politics . Vol. 25, Nº 02, pp. 192-202.
  • BORGES, André; TURGEON, Mathieu, and ALBALA, Adrián (2021), Electoral incentives to coalition formation in multiparty presidential systems. Party Politics . Vol. 27, Nº 06, pp. 1279-1289.
  • CAMERLO, Marcelo and PÉREZ-LIÑÁN, Aníbal (2015) Minister turnover, critical events, and the electoral calendar in presidential democracies. The Journal of Politics . Vol. 77, Nº 03, pp. 608–619.
  • CAMERLO, Marcelo and MARTÍNEZ-GALLARDO, Cecilia (2017), Government formation and minister turnover in presidential cabinets: comparative analysis in the Americas. London: Routledge. 258 pp..
  • CARROLL, Royce and COX, Gary W. (2007) The logic of Gamson’s Law: pre-election coalitions and portfolio allocations. American Journal of Political Science. Vol. 51, Nº 02, pp. 300-313.
  • CHAISTY, Paul; CHEESEMAN, Nic, and POWER, Timothy (2014), Rethinking the ‘presidentialism debate’: conceptualizing coalitional politics in cross-regional perspective. Democratization . Vol. 21, Nº 01, pp. 72-94.
  • CHASQUETTI, Daniel (2008), Democracia, presidencialismo y partidos políticos en América Latina: evaluando la ‘difícil combinación’. Montevideo: Ediciones Cauce. 187 pp..
  • CHASQUETTI, Daniel (2001), Democracia, multipartidismo y coaliciones en América Latina: evaluando la difícil combinación. In: Tipos de presidencialismo y coaliciones políticas en América Latina . Edited by LAZARO, Jorge Luis. Buenos Aires: Clacso. pp. 319-359.
  • CHEIBUB, José Antonio (2007), Presidentialism, parliamentarism and democracy . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 224 pp..
  • CHEIBUB, José Antonio; ELKINS, Zachary, and GINSBURG, Tom (2014), Beyond presidentialism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 44, Nº 03, pp. 515-544.
  • CHEIBUB, José Antonio; MARTINS, Shane, and RASCH, Bjørn Eric (2015), Government selection and executive powers: constitutional design in parliamentary democracies. West European Politics . Vol. 38, Nº 05, pp. 969-996.
  • CHEIBUB, José Antonio; PRZEWORSKI, Adam, and SAIEGH, Sebastian M. (2004), Government coalitions and legislative success under presidentialism and parliamentarism. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 34, Nº 04, pp. 565–587.
  • CHIRU, Mihail (2015), Early marriages last longer: pre-electoral coalitions and government survival in Europe. Government and Opposition . Vol. 50, Nº 02, pp. 165-188.
  • DEBUS, Marc (2009), Pre-electoral commitments and government formation. Public Choice . Vol. 138, Nº 01/02, pp. 45-64.
  • DEHEZA, Grace Ivana (1998), Gobiernos de coalición en el sistema presidencial: América del Sur. In: El presidencialismo renovado: instituciones y cambio político en América Latina. Edited by NOHLEN, Dieter and FERNÁNDES B., Mário. Caracas: Nueva Sociedad. pp. 151-170.
  • DUCH, Raymond M.; MAY, Jeff, and ARMSTRONG, David A. (2010), Coalition-directed voting in multiparty democracies. American Political Science Review . Vol. 104, Nº 04, pp. 698-719.
  • ELGIE, Robert (2005), From Linz to Tsebelis: three waves of presidential/parliamentary studies? Democratization . Vol. 12, Nº 01, pp. 106-122.
  • FIGUEIREDO, Argelina Cheibub (2007), Coalition government in the Brazilian democracy. Brazilian Political Science Review . Vol. 01, Nº 02, pp. 182-216.
  • FRANKLIN, Mark N. and MACKIE, Thomas T. (1983), Familiarity and inertia in the formation of governing coalitions in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 13, Nº 03, pp. 275-298.
  • FREUDENREICH, Johannes (2016), The formation of cabinet coalitions in presidential systems. Latin American Politics and Society . Vol. 58, Nº 04, pp. 80–102.
  • GEDDES, Barbara (2003), Paradigms and sand castles: theory building and research design in comparative politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 314 pp..
  • GIBSON, John (1999), Political timing a theory of politicians’ timing of events. Journal of Theoretical Politics . Vol. 11, Nº 04, pp. 471–496.
  • GLASGOW, Garret; GOLDER, Matt, and GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2012), New empirical strategies for the study of parliamentary government formation. Political Analysis. Vol. 20, pp. 248-270.
  • GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2015), Government formation and cabinets. In: Emerging trends in the social and behavioral sciences . Edited by SCOTT, Robert A.; KOSSLYN, Stephen Michael, and BUCHMANN, Marlis. London: John Wiley & Sons Inc. pp. 01-15.
  • GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2010), Bargaining delays in the government formation process. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 43, Nº 01, pp. 03-32.
  • GOLDER, Sona Nadenichek (2006), Pre-electoral coalition formation in parliamentary democracies. British Journal of Political Science . Vol. 36, Nº 02, pp. 193-212.
  • HANAN, Djayadi (2012), Making presidentialism work: legislative and executive interaction in Indonesian democracy. Doctoral thesis . Graduate Program in Political Science. Ohio State University.
  • HIROI, Taeko and RENNÓ, Lucio (2014), Dimensions of legislative conflict: coalitions, obstructionism, and lawmaking in multiparty presidential regimes. Legislative Studies Quarterly . Vol. 39, Nº 03, pp. 357–386.
  • IBENSKAS, Raimondas (2016), Understanding pre-electoral coalitions in Central and Eastern Europe. Party Politics . Vol. 46, Nº 04, pp. 743-761.
  • KELLAM, Marisa (2017), Why pre-electoral coalitions in presidential systems? British Journal of Political Science. Vol. 47, Nº 02, pp. 391-411.
  • KELLAM, Marisa (2015), Parties for hire: how particularistic parties influence presidents’ governing strategies. Party Politics . Vol. 21, Nº 04, pp. 515-526.
  • KIM, Youngmi (2011), The politics of coalition in Korea: between institutions and culture. London: Routledge. 224 pp..
  • KIM, Youngmi (2008), Intra-party politics and minority coalition government in South Korea. Japanese Journal of Political Science . Vol. 09, Nº 03, pp. 367-389.
  • KING, Gary; KEOHANE, Robert O., and VERBA, Sidney (1994), Designing social inquiry: scientific inference in qualitative research. Princeton: Princeton University Press. 259 pp..
  • LINZ, Juan J. (1990), The perils of presidentialism. Journal of Democracy . Vol. 01, Nº 01, pp. 51–69.
  • LOPES, Amanda Vitoria (2022), The best of two worlds: selection strategies for vice-presidential candidates. Brazilian Political Science Review . Vol. 16, Nº 01, pp. 01-26.
  • LUPIA, Arthur and STRØM, Kaare (2008), Coalition governance theory: bargaining, electoral connections and the shadow of the future. In: Cabinet and coalition bargaining: the democratic life cycle in Western Europe . Edited by STRØM, Kaare, MÜLLER, Wolfgang C. and BERGMAN, Torbjörn. Oxford: Oxford University Press. pp. 51-83.
  • MAGAR, Eric and MORAES, Juan Andrés (2012), Factions with clout: presidential cabinet coalition and policy in the Uruguayan parliament. Party Politics . Vol. 18, Nº 03, pp. 427-451.
  • MAINWARING, Scott and SHUGART, Matthew Soberg (1999), Presidentialism and democracy in Latin America . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 508 pp..
  • MARTINEZ-GALLARDO, Cecilia (2014), Designing cabinets: presidential politics and ministerial instability. Journal of Politics in Latin America . Vol. 06, Nº 02, pp. 03–38.
  • MARTINEZ-GALLARDO, Cecilia (2012), Out of the cabinet: what drives defections from the government in presidential systems. Comparative Political Studies . Vol. 45, Nº 01, pp. 62-90.
  • McCLINTOCK, Cynthia (2018), Reevaluating runoffs in Latin America. Journal of Democracy . Vol. 29, Nº 01, pp. 96-110.
  • MEIRELES, Fernando (2016), Oversized government coalitions in Latin America. Brazilian Political Science Review. Vol. 10, Nº 03, pp. 01–31.
  • MOURY, Catherine (2013), Coalition government and party mandate: how coalition agreements constrain. London: Routledge. 176 pp..
  • MOURY, Catherine (2011), Coalition agreement and party mandate: how coalition agreements constrain the ministers. Party Politics . Vol. 17, Nº 03, pp. 385–404.
  • RAGIN, Charles C. (2008), Redesigning social inquiry: fuzzy sets and beyond. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 240 pp..
  • RAGIN, Charles C. and RUBINSON, Claude (2009), The distinctiveness of comparative research. In: The SAGE handbook of comparative politics . Edited by LANDMAN, Todd and ROBINSON, Neil. London: SAGE. pp. 13-34.
  • RAILE, Eric D.; PEREIRA, Carlos, and POWER, Timothy J. (2011), The executive toolbox: building legislative support in a multiparty presidential regime. Political Research Quarterly . Vol. 64, Nº 02, pp. 323- 334.
  • SEDELIUS, Thomas and LINDE, Jonas (2018), Unravelling semi-presidentialism: democracy and government performance in four distinct regime types. Democratization . Vol. 25, Nº 01, pp. 136-157.
  • SPOON, Jae-Jae and WEST, Karleen Jones (2015), Alone or together? How institutions affect party entry in presidential elections in Europe and South America. Party Politics . Vol. 21, Nº 03, pp. 393–403.
  • STRØM, Kaare (1990), Minority g overnement and majority rule . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 304 pp..
  • STRØM, Kaare; MÜLLER, Wolfgang C., and BERGMAN, Torbjörn (2008), Cabinet and coalitions bargaining: the democratic life cylce in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 464 pp..
  • TEEHANKEE, Julio Cabral (2020), Factional dynamics in Philippine party politics, 1900–2019. Journal of Current Southeast Asian Affairs . Vol. 39, Nº 01, pp. 98-123.
  • 1
    In the United States, the president is elected indirectly via an electoral college, as in Argentina until 1983.
  • 2
    According to Linz (1990)LINZ, Juan J. (1990), The perils of presidentialism. Journal of Democracy . Vol. 01, Nº 01, pp. 51–69. , temporally-fixed mandates are the main reason why presidentialism is prone to instability, in addition to being a constraint on coalition formation since the president does not ‘need’ a majority to remain in office.
  • 3
    Di Rupo Government in Belgium is a typical example of how a bargaining delay can lead to an 'unexpected' coalition. In 2010-2011, negotiations to form a coalition in Belgium lasted more than a year, during which the country was ruled by a caretaker government. This struggle in forming a government is not a Belgium idiosyncrasy, as demonstrated recently by the UK (2010), Italy (2018, 2013), Ireland (2020, 2016), Spain (2016), and Israel (2020-2019); moreover, the later composition of these governments raises the question of the responsiveness of these governments. In 2020, for instance, would a Fine Gael voter have been pleased to see her party forming a government led again by Sinn Féin in Ireland? This question gains more prominence as the coalition options for the competing parties matter to voters when they are casting their vote ( BLAIS et al., 2016)BLAIS, André; GUNTERMANN, Eric, and BODET, Marc A. (2016), Linking party preferences and the composition of government: a new standard for evaluating the performance of electoral democracy. Political Science Research and Method . Vol. 05, Nº 02, pp. 315-331. .
  • 4
    It is worth noting that the accurate definition of the South Korean form of government is an open issue in the literature ( KIM, 2008)KIM, Youngmi (2008), Intra-party politics and minority coalition government in South Korea. Japanese Journal of Political Science . Vol. 09, Nº 03, pp. 367-389. . While some scholars assign South Korea to the set of presidential countries ( BORGES and RIBEIRO, 2021BORGES, André and RIBEIRO, Pedro Floriano (2021), Presidents, prime ministers and legislative behaviour: the conditional effect of presidential legislative powers on party unity. Government and Opposition. Available at ˂ https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.45 ˃. Accessed on August, 10, 2022.
    https://doi.org/10.1017/gov.2021.45...
    ; CHEIBUB, 2007CHEIBUB, José Antonio (2007), Presidentialism, parliamentarism and democracy . Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 224 pp.. ; SEDELIUS and LINDE, 2018)SEDELIUS, Thomas and LINDE, Jonas (2018), Unravelling semi-presidentialism: democracy and government performance in four distinct regime types. Democratization . Vol. 25, Nº 01, pp. 136-157. , others prefer to label South Korea as a semi-presidential regime ( KIM, 2011, 2008)KIM, Youngmi (2011), The politics of coalition in Korea: between institutions and culture. London: Routledge. 224 pp.. , 2008KIM, Youngmi (2008), Intra-party politics and minority coalition government in South Korea. Japanese Journal of Political Science . Vol. 09, Nº 03, pp. 367-389. ).
  • 5
    Even though the party composition of the coalition did not change, the NCNP changed its name to MDP (New Millennium Democratic Party) at the beginning of 2000 ( KIM, 2008)KIM, Youngmi (2008), Intra-party politics and minority coalition government in South Korea. Japanese Journal of Political Science . Vol. 09, Nº 03, pp. 367-389. .
  • 6
    Chilean and Uruguayan former presidents can run for non-consecutive presidential terms, but they are forbidden to seek immediate reelection.
  • 7
    Positive values are described as a convergence among coalesced parties in the direction of a shared political project, whereas negative values are expressed as a shared rejection of a third political actor – the conventional Uruguay case, for instance.
  • 8
    By saing so, we do not exclude every cabinet that includes non-partisans ministers; instead, we mean that we do not consider non-partisans as distinct ‘coalition partners’.
  • 9
    This is particularly evident in the Uruguayan party system. In spite of its traditional low number of effective parties, Uruguay does have a party system boiled with intraparty differences ( ALTMAN, 2001)ALTMAN, David (2001), The politics of coalition formation and survival in multiparty presidential democracies: the case of Uruguay, 1989-1999. Party Politics . Vol. 06, Nº 03, pp. 259-283. . As a result, multiparty governments must deal not only with other parties but also with the internal factions of each of their members ( MAGAR and MORAES, 2012)MAGAR, Eric and MORAES, Juan Andrés (2012), Factions with clout: presidential cabinet coalition and policy in the Uruguayan parliament. Party Politics . Vol. 18, Nº 03, pp. 427-451. . Even still, as factions are still tied to broader organizations, namely the political parties, we do not consider single-party governments comprised of different internal factions as fitting the concept of coalition governments.
  • 10
    To exemplify this, prior to the 1992 South Korean presidential election, the winner, the Democratic Liberal Party (DLP), was a product of a merger between three parties: The Democratic Justice Party (DJP) combined with the Unification Democratic Party (UDP) and the New Democratic Republican Party (NDRP) ( KIM, 2008)KIM, Youngmi (2008), Intra-party politics and minority coalition government in South Korea. Japanese Journal of Political Science . Vol. 09, Nº 03, pp. 367-389. . Therefore, once there are no longer different party organizations, we shall not consider Kim Young-sam’s government as a government coalition.
  • 11
    In these cases, the term ‘party’ is essentially formal. It is a strategy for dominant parties to artificially amplify their parliamentary group by by-passing the electoral law. Senatorial elections in Argentina are a good example. Since the 1994 constitutional reform, every province elects three senators as follows: two senators for the winning list, and one for the first ‘minority’. Thus, in several provinces such as La Rioja or Buenos Aires, the Justicialist Party and its ‘testimonial’ allies frequently win every available seat.
  • 12
    It could be argued that we are misreading the 'earliness' process of coalition cabinets by choosing our observations based on their value in the dependent variable. In the eyes of the quantitative literature, this approach is one of the most troublesome practices in the social sciences ( GEDDES, 2003GEDDES, Barbara (2003), Paradigms and sand castles: theory building and research design in comparative politics. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. 314 pp.. ; KING et al., 1994)KING, Gary; KEOHANE, Robert O., and VERBA, Sidney (1994), Designing social inquiry: scientific inference in qualitative research. Princeton: Princeton University Press. 259 pp.. . However, this is quite a narrow view since the cases themselves might provide substantial knowledge about the phenomena under study ( RAGIN, 2008RAGIN, Charles C. (2008), Redesigning social inquiry: fuzzy sets and beyond. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 240 pp.. ; RAGIN and RUBINSON, 2009)RAGIN, Charles C. and RUBINSON, Claude (2009), The distinctiveness of comparative research. In: The SAGE handbook of comparative politics . Edited by LANDMAN, Todd and ROBINSON, Neil. London: SAGE. pp. 13-34. . Furthermore, we do not aim to generalize our findings to all presidential cabinets. Rather, our focus is on specifying the importance of pre-electoral commitments for forming governments after the elections have taken place.
  • 13
    As Franco, Temer, and Arroyo I’s coalition cabinets stemmed from the impeachment of the previous administration and, therefore, were not derived from a presidential election, they have been excluded from the analysis.
  • 14
    Case studies, such as Albala (2016a)ALBALA, Adrián (2016a), Coalitions gouvernementales et régime présidentiel: Le cas du Cône Sud. Paris: Éditions Universitaires Européennes. 536 pp.. , Amorim Neto and Pimenta (2020)AMORIM NETO, Octavio and PIMENTA, Gabriel Alves (2020), The first year of Bolsonaro in office: same old story, same old song? Revista de Ciência Política . Vol. 40, Nº 02, pp. 187-213. , and Kim (2008)KIM, Youngmi (2008), Intra-party politics and minority coalition government in South Korea. Japanese Journal of Political Science . Vol. 09, Nº 03, pp. 367-389. , provided a theoretical basis to rule out a handful of multiparty cabinets because they were not actual coalition cabinets.
  • 15
  • 16
    Available at ˂ https://wikileaks.org/˃ .
  • 17
    An example was the second cabinet of Brazilian President Lula in his first mandate (2003-2006): the late inclusion of the PMDB party a year after the election (that is at a t+2 timing – an example of ‘ad hoc’ coalition) led to a fracture among the ‘core members’ and thus to the exit of the PDT ( FIGUEIREDO, 2007)FIGUEIREDO, Argelina Cheibub (2007), Coalition government in the Brazilian democracy. Brazilian Political Science Review . Vol. 01, Nº 02, pp. 182-216. .
  • 18
    We are indebted to an anonymous reviewer for raising this point.
  • 19
    We removed the cabinets of Mexico, South Korea, and the Philippines from the sample because their electoral system does not allow for the possibility of a ‘ballottage’.
  • 20
    The MDP (be careful not to mix up with the New Millennium Democratic Party from South Korea) won 65 out of 87 seats in the unicameral Maldivian legislature, while its coalition partners won only five seats.

Edited by

Revised by Karin Blikstad

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    20 Feb 2023
  • Date of issue
    Feb 2023

History

  • Received
    05 Oct 2021
  • Accepted
    03 Sept 2022
Associação Brasileira de Ciência Política Avenida Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 315, sala 2047, CEP 05508-900, Tel.: (55 11) 3091-3754 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
E-mail: bpsr@brazilianpoliticalsciencareview.org