Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

PERFORMANCE SPORT, TAX WAIVER AND SPORTS INCENTIVE LAW

ESPORTE RENDIMENTO, RENÚNCIA FISCAL E LEI DE INCENTIVO AO ESPORTE

ABSTRACT

This study aims to analyze the application of the Sports Incentive Law (SIL) from 2007 to 2011 regarding performance sport. Information about this law was taken straight from the Brazil Sports Ministry website. The methodological view attempted to comprise the analysis of authorized raising resources, raised funds, success rate and redistributive factor. Results found allow us to infer that the SLI came up not only to keep the status quo in federal funds distribution, but also to amplify the difference in its application towards more developed regions and countries.

Keywords:
Sport; Performance Sport; Tax Waiver; Sports Incentive Law; Social Justice.

RESUMO

Este trabalho teve como objetivo analisar o desempenho da aplicação da Lei de Incentivo ao Esporte (LIE) de 2007 a 2011 no que se refere ao esporte rendimento. As informações da lei foram extraídas diretamente do site do Ministério do Esporte. O recorte metodológico procurou contemplar a análise dos recursos autorizados à captação, recursos captados, taxa de sucesso e fator redistributivo. Os resultados encontrados permitem aferir que a LIE veio não só para manter o status quo na distribuição dos recursos federais, mas também para amplificar a diferença na sua aplicação em direção às regiões e estados mais desenvolvidos.

Palavras-chave:
Esporte; Esporte Rendimento; Renúncia Fiscal; Lei de Incentivo; Justiça Social.

Introduction

Sports Incentive Law (Act 11.438/2006)11. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Lei nº 11.438 de 29 de dezembro de 2006. [Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_ato2004-2006/2006/lei/l11438.htm
http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_at...
stands as an important sports public policy, right next to Segundo Tempo Program (STP) and Sport and Leisure in the City Program (SLCP), implemented by the federal government in Brazil during Lula’s term (2003 to 2006/2007 to 2010). Sports Incentive Law has been created in order to guarantee more investments to the sports field.

Sports funding theme has been turning up in literature specially to evaluate the performance of the Sports Ministry in the sports field. Almeida and Marchi Jr.22. Almeida BS, Marchi Júnior W. O financiamento dos programas federais de esporte e lazer no Brasil (2004 a 2008). Movimento 2010;16(04):73-92. have rated that redirected funds from the federal government to states and municipalities ended up prioritizing high performance sport. Athayde, Mascarenhas and Salvador33. Athayde PFA, Mascarenhas F, Salvador EV. Primeiras aproximações de uma análise do financiamento da política nacional de esporte e lazer no governo Lula. Rev Bras Cie do Esp 2015;37(1):2-10. identified instability in fundings from some educational and participative sport programs and the prioritization of investments in high performance sport during Lula’s government. Figuerôa et al.44. Figuerôa KM, Sevegnani P, Mezzadri FM, Silva MM. Planejamento, ações e financiamento para o esporte em tempos de megaeventos. Motri 2014;26(42):55-71. and Teixeira et al.55. Teixeira MR, Matias WB; Mascarenhas F. O financiamento do esporte olímpico no Brasil: Uma análise do ciclo de Londres (2009-2012). Rev Cienc Social 2013: 110-86. have analyzed the government’s planning and funding for the Olympic and Paralympic games in 2016. Veronez66. Veronez LFC. O planejamento governamental e o orçamento do setor esportivo [Internet]. XV Congresso Brasileiro de Ciências do Esporte 2007 [Access in April13, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.cbce.org.br/docs/cd/resumos/275.pdf
http://www.cbce.org.br/docs/cd/resumos/2...
has analyzed the performance of governments regarding sports funding after the 1988 Federal Constitution. Silva et al.77. Silva MM, Mezzadri FM, Santos N, Camargo PR, Figuerôa KM. A configuração do ordenamento jurídico relativo ao financiamento do governo brasileiro ao esporte de rendimento: uma análise a partir da teoria dos jogos de Norbert Elias. Lúdic Pedag 2015;2(21):77-89. have analyzed legal aspects from the funding of performance sport in Brazil. Castro88. Castro SBE. Políticas públicas para o esporte e lazer e o ciclo orçamentário brasileiro (2004-2011): prioridades e distribuição de recursos durante os processos de elaboração e execução orçamentária. [Tese de Doutorado em Educação Física]. Curitiba: Universidade Federal do Paraná, Programa de Pós-graduação em Educação Física; 2016. has assessed government’s planning and budget execution from 2004 to 2011.

Despite the implementation of the Sports Incentive Law (SIL) having occured from 2007 on, only a few papers aim to analyze its performance. The most significant one is the study ran by Matias et al.99. Matias WB; Athayde PF; Húngaro EM. A Lei de Incentivo fiscal e o (não) direito ao esporte no Brasil. Movimento 2015; 21(1): 95-110.. In that paper, the authors reached the conclusion that SIL contributes just a little to the guarantee of sport access as a social right. However, judging by the amount of invested resources, there is a reduced number of papers that bring about the debate on how these expenses are made.

The present paper aims to contribute overcoming such a gap. To do so, it sought to understand to what extent transfering political authority to market agents promotes regional balance on the access to performance sport through SIL. In this respect, it has been run an analysis of regional performance of investments regarding authorized raising resources, raised resources and if its distribution has prioritized regions where the practice of performance sport needs more incentive and investment from 2007 to 2011.

For this analysis, the study was organized in a way to present, in its first section, briefly, the functioning of SIL. In the following section, to discuss the purpose of tax waiver. Then, to point out the methodology outline and discussion of results and, finally, propose a conclusion.

Sports Incentive Law (SIL)

Sports Incentive Law follows the same format as the Culture Incentive Law (CIL)1010. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Decreto nº 8.313 de 23 de dezembro de 1991.[Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/leis/L8313cons.htm
http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/lei...
, the Rouanet Law. While the latter intends to promote culture, the former one plans to foster performance sport, educational sport and participative sport. The main and essential difference concerns the amount of raised resources in the market along with legal entities. While in CIL tax waiver is at 4%, sport got only 1% from Income Taxes (IT) due to taxed companies on real profit. Legal entities may deduct up to 6% of due IT.

SIL has been regulated by Act 6.180/20071111. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Decreto nº 6.180 de 3 de agosto de 2007.[Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_Ato2007-2010/2007/Decreto/D6180.htm
http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_At...
, which describes the conditions for sport financing and criteria for participation. So that the Technical Committee may assess the offer, it is necessary that the applicant registers in the Sports Ministry website and presents a sport or parasport project. With the project approved, it starts the raising funds stage, next to the private sector. Companies are promoted in terms of allocating part of the project resources from due taxes in exchange for tax waiver. Therefore, all invested resources are of political nature, not private. However, the decision on which policies will be receiving enough financial input from the market is made privatly. State is not an agent in the definition of effectively implemented policies. Which means, it loses its political role in the definition of sports public policies to receive State funds.

In the first paragraph of Art.II, Act 11.43811. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Lei nº 11.438 de 29 de dezembro de 2006. [Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_ato2004-2006/2006/lei/l11438.htm
http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_at...
, it is described that one of the goal of this act is to promote social inclusion through sport, preferably in socially vulnerable communities. Thus, the result of this incentive should promote social justice. That way, promoting means accepting that reality points to disadvantages of certain groups according to access to different sport expressions (educational, participative or performance sport) and that, as proposed by Rawls’ Theory of Justice (1992)1212. Rawls J. Justiça como equidade: uma concepção política, não metafísica. Lua Nov: Rev de Cult e Polit 1992; (25): 25-29, it is necessary to have a distinguished distribution of resources in order to include the least privileged ones.

Decentralization or democratization in the access to sport is the goal to be pursued by SIL, but its regularization does not point to that goal being reached effectively. Despite SIL aiming to reduce social inequality, institutional causes affect resource distribution. On the one hand, it can be noticed that SIL has not established regional limits in tax waiver in a way that it interferes on potential sponsors’ behavior. On the other hand, differently from Matias et al.99. Matias WB; Athayde PF; Húngaro EM. A Lei de Incentivo fiscal e o (não) direito ao esporte no Brasil. Movimento 2015; 21(1): 95-110., that sees the Technical Committee’s non-observance of regional distribution among SIL offers as a legal landmark violation, the caption of Art. 21, Act 6.180/20071111. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Decreto nº 6.180 de 3 de agosto de 2007.[Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_Ato2007-2010/2007/Decreto/D6180.htm
http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_At...
, sets out limitations to the act itself. It indicates that the Technical Committee should only observe the intention of the rule.

As projects are regulated on demand, it is not possible to have this kind of control. The constant flow of offers submission and forwarding to the Technical Committee creates difficulties to the control of regional offer asymmetry. No tool has been outlined to correct this asymmetry. More technical qualified sectors tend to get ahead in the approval of offers due to the law design.

As portrayed by neoinstitutionalism, institutions, in this case regarding the norm (SIL), are not neutral; they share advantages in an unequal way1313. March J, Olsen JP. Neo-Institucionalismo: fatores organizacionais na vida política. Sociol e Polit 2008;16(31):121-142.),(1414. Hall PA,Taylor RCR. As três versões do neo-institucioalismo. Lua Nov 2003; (58): 193-222.. In the heart of this dispute, lies the appropriation of short public funds. It cannot be seen as mere coincidence the fact that performance sport approves most of the projects (593; 53,51%) and proposes the highest amount of resources in the analyzed period of time (R$ 869.453.227,00; 64,31%). Its interests have been always well apprehended by the norms ruling the Brazilian sport system1515. Bueno L. Política pública do esporte no Brasil: aplicação da Advocacy Coalition Framework. In.: Santos E, Leiro ACR. Políticas públicas de esporte e lazer: diálogos. Petrolina: UNIVASF; 2015. p. 17-47. .

Tax Waiver

Tax Waiver is part of the Brazilian strategies for financing in which the government gives away part of a company’s due taxes (which means, there is a loss in revenue) so that it can invest in areas designated by law. To Sayd1616. Sayd PD. Renúncia fiscal e eqüidade na distribuição de recursos para a saúde. [Tese de Doutorado] Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Oswaldo Cruz. Escola Nacional de Saúde Pública; 2003):10,

“Tax waiver [...] is a public financing tool, via tributary system, generally related to the promotion of social policies, and may be used to minimize regional inequalities regarding the development of some sectors and projects.”

Tax waiver or indirect tax expense1717. Almeida FCR. Uma abordagem estruturada da renúncia de receita pública federal. Rev Trib Cont da Un 2000:19-62., sought through incentive laws, needs to be interpreted as a result of govern’s tax effort aiming to diminish regional inequalities (Item I, article 151, Federal Constitution/88). In the case of SIL, letting go of funds that might raise the number of direct actions in sports benefit, it is expected that State goals can be pursued and that private sector, through incentives, help expanding determined funds towards less developed regions and sectors1717. Almeida FCR. Uma abordagem estruturada da renúncia de receita pública federal. Rev Trib Cont da Un 2000:19-62.),(1818. Belem MP, Donadone JC. A Lei Rouanet e a construção do “mercado de patrocínios culturais”. Nov Rum Sociol 2013;1(1):50-61),(1919. Mendes CC. O Território e o Arranjo Federativo para o Desenvolvimento Brasileiro: O caso do Nordeste. In: Linhares PTF, Mendes CC, Lassance A. (Org.) Federalismo à brasileira: questões para discussão Brasília, DF: Ipea; 2012. p. 89-111..

Tributary benefit leads to loss in federal tax collections, decreasing its capacity to promote social welfare. Another important element here is that this resource is not Union-exclusive, given that states and municipalities are direct beneficiaries from the Income Tax sharing through States and Municipalities Participation Funds (SPF and MPF). By giving up this revenue, there is a loss in collections from all three governmental divisions, which will not be compensated with any other resource1717. Almeida FCR. Uma abordagem estruturada da renúncia de receita pública federal. Rev Trib Cont da Un 2000:19-62.),(1919. Mendes CC. O Território e o Arranjo Federativo para o Desenvolvimento Brasileiro: O caso do Nordeste. In: Linhares PTF, Mendes CC, Lassance A. (Org.) Federalismo à brasileira: questões para discussão Brasília, DF: Ipea; 2012. p. 89-111.),(2020. Andreazzi MFS, Ocké-Reis CO. Renúncia de arrecadação fiscal: subsídios para discussão e formulação de uma política pública; Tax expenditures on health care: contributions toward a public policy agenda. Phys 2007;17(3):521-544.. Therefore, the State does that so the revenue can be used in a fast decentralized manner to foster social justice.

Almeida1717. Almeida FCR. Uma abordagem estruturada da renúncia de receita pública federal. Rev Trib Cont da Un 2000:19-62. points out that to some people tributary benefit is seen as a public policy (neutral governmental action) in which the protagonist is the private sector. However, tax waiver is not private. Even being public, private sector can use it for advertising purposes (in the case of a sponsor). Sponsors allow companies that invest in incentive laws to attract new clients, on behalf of social responsibility, promoting the company’s image, obtaining commercial return from investment or adding value to the brand2121. Oliveira LJ, Schwerter IMG. Breve análise das práticas de responsabilidade social empresariais e a concessão de incentivos governamentais em âmbito federal. Jus Navigandi 2007; [Access in April 12, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.derechoycambiosocial.com/revista010/responsabilidad%20social.htm
http://www.derechoycambiosocial.com/revi...
),(2222. Augustin AC. A farsa das leis de incentivo: o neoliberalismo e seu impacto na política cultural brasileira.[Trabalho de Conclusão de Curso de Ciências Econômicas]. Porto Alegre: Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul, Faculdade de Ciências Econômicas; 2010.),(2323. Nascimento AF. Política cultural no Brasil: do Estado ao mercado.[Internet] III ENECULT-Encontro de Estudos Multidisciplinares em Cultura 2007.[Access on May 25, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/AlbertoFreire.pdf
http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/Albe...
),(2424. Arruda MAN. A política cultural: regulação estatal e mecenato privado. Temp soci 2003;15(2):177-193.),(2525. Botelho I. Dimensões da cultura e políticas públicas. SP em Persp 2001;15(2):73-83.. Individual return maximization2626. Valiati L, Florissi S. A problemática da captação: relação entre os incentivos fiscais e a gestão dos recursos públicos na decisão privada da inversão cultural. Econ da Cul 2005:89-116. is one of the possibilities received by public policies through incentive laws.

In the cultural policy field, criticisms to this model are consolidated. Pitombo2727. Pitombo M. Sintomas dos deslocamentos de poder na gestão do campo cultural no Brasil - uma leitura sobre as leis de incentivo à cultura. In: Pinheiro MT (Org.) Temas contemporâneos. Salvador: Editora FIB; 2006. p. 55-62. frames this policy model as a liberalizing matrix, since State becomes a mere accessory for public policies and market the main actor. A modern corporate patronage arises with public funds in which private initiative defines the application of resources taking its commercial interests in account. In this case, the partnership discourse comes undone, since there are no extra private funds to justify this relation2828. Silva FAB. Financiamento cultural: situação atual e questões para reflexão. Políticas sociais - acompanhamento e análise 2004 [Access on April 19, 2016]. Available in: Available in: http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/images/stories/PDFs/politicas_sociais/ENSAIO2_Frederico8.pdf
http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/images/sto...
. Companies’ marketing department turns into the main deciding element of public policy2929. Rubim AAC. Políticas culturais no Brasil: tristes tradições. Galáx 2006;7(13):101-113.. As Nascimento2323. Nascimento AF. Política cultural no Brasil: do Estado ao mercado.[Internet] III ENECULT-Encontro de Estudos Multidisciplinares em Cultura 2007.[Access on May 25, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/AlbertoFreire.pdf
http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/Albe...
sees it, this contemporary patronage, by allowing companies to define where to invest public funds, allows a strong concentrator selective allocation. Its interests are always turned to regions of more dynamic economy and greater population density.

Companies’ marketing department’s choice of investing public resources may attribute a concentrating resource strength despite tax waiver spirit. Brazil has a background of tax incentive that ended up generating severe allocation distortions, increasing existent inequalities even more1717. Almeida FCR. Uma abordagem estruturada da renúncia de receita pública federal. Rev Trib Cont da Un 2000:19-62. and also the State’s effort to guarantee social justice.

Brazilian Gross Domestic Product (GDP) becomes an important analytical variable for this scenario, because it leads the way to economic dynamic. In Brazilian society, there is a huge inequality on wealth distribution among regions and states. In 2011, Brazilian GDP was around R$ 4.143 trillion. Southeast region absorbed a significant part of this production, 55,44% (R$ 2.299 trillion), and regions North and Northeast only 5,5% and 13,6%, respectively. Thus, there is a great asymmetry on wealth distribution in Brazil, which generates socioeconomic inequalities3030. Barros RP, Henriques R, Mendonça R. A estabilidade inaceitável: desigualdade e pobreza no Brasil. Available in: Henriques R. (Org.) Desigualdade e pobreza no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA; 2000, p. 21-48..

This asymmetry can be explained by Brazilian social and historical traits in economic capital accumulation. Regions South and Southeast end up having diverse conditions for raising funds via market, since they gather significant part of Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Such condition may produce locational distortions in case the State does not have a tool to regulate the participation of economical agents in the distribution of public resources generated from tax waiver. As it happens to the Rouanet Law, which follows the same tax waiver principle as SIL, by investing in a certain project, the investor aims to get a better return of its image next to the public. From the point of view of both regional economic potential and target public, regions South and Southeast are favored in the end3131. Cavalcanti GEL. Análise Econômica das Políticas de Incentivos à Cultura no Brasil.[Dissertação de Mestrado em Finanças e Economia Empresarial]. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Getúlio Vargas, Escola de Pós Graduação em Economia; 2006.),(3232. Olivieri CG. Cultura neoliberal: leis de incentivo como política pública de cultura. São Paulo: Escrituras; 2015.. As Freitas mentions3333. Freitas LL. A lei Rouanet e a atual produção cultural brasileira: retrato da relação entre incentivo fiscal e a produção cultural no Brasil.[Trabalho de Conclusão de Curso de Pós-Graduação em Gestão de Projetos Culturais e Organização de Eventos]. São Paulo: Centro de Estudos Latino Americanos sobre Cultura e Comunicação, Universidade de São Paulo; 2012.):14: “From the moment when management and sponsorship start to be responsibility of private companies, the result is a greater concentration of investments in regions where it is set or where it can get the most marketing return possible”.

An important counterpoint in terms of public policies and that seeks to reduce inequalities of local (municipality) and regional (states) access to resources is the mandatory constitutional transfers, FPE and FPM (Act 5.172/66)3434. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Lei nº Lei 5.172 de 25 de outubro de 1966. [Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: https://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/leis/L5172.htm
https://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/le...
establishes a redistributive share to each state). Following the principle of social justice, this fund enhances the position of more fragile states regarding economic and social conditions3535. Arretche M. Federalismo e políticas sociais no Brasil: problemas de coordenação e autonomia. SP em Persp 2004;18(2):17-26.. Regions North and Northeast answer for 73,48% of FPE, while regions South and Southeast add up 15%. This distribution seeks to promote better balance in the access of resources that foster economic and social development3636. Souza Junior CVN, Gasparini CE. Análise da Equidade e da Eficiência dos Estados no Contexto do Federalismo Fiscal Brasileiro. Estud Econ 2006; 36(4): 803-832.

Despite the existence of a conceptual dispute regarding the definition of social inclusion and vulnerable communities, in general lines it is possible to associate these elements to welfare deficiency in places with low rates of human development. Accordingly, tax waiver should promote the decrease of inequalities in access to sports, increasing funds in areas where its development occurs in precarious ways, because “(...) a policy that aims to fight regional inequalities must privilege funds transfers to poorer states in order to promote infrastructure and human capital development.”3737. Paes NL, Siqueira ML. Desenvolvimento regional e federalismo fiscal no Brasil: em busca da igualdade na distribuição de receitas. Econ Aplic 2008;12(4):707-742.): 709

Regions North and Northeast are the ones that show lower levels of sports development - not only on performance sports, as observed in IBGE’s “Brazilian municipalities profile - Sport”3838. Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística [Internet]. Perfil dos municípios brasileiros: esporte, 2003 [Access in May 20,2016] Available in: Available in: http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/economia/perfilmunic/esporte2003/default.shtm
http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/...
.

Thus, tax waiver promoted by SIL must be interpreted as a public policy capable of legitimizing the platform of sports right, together with the reduction of regional inequalities on the access to public resources as provided in 1988 Constitution. Among these, is the sport, is worth emphasizing that Santos and Freitas3939. Santos ES, Freitas ALC. O direito ao desporto: Justiça Social e Políticas Públicas. Dir Fund e Jus 2015; (30): 139-157. analysis does not differentiate, in terms of sport right, state guarantee and democratization of performance sport.

Methods

This exploratory study aims to verify to what extent transferring political authority to market agents promotes regional balance on the access to performance sport through SIL. The period of time studied here was from 2007, SIL implementation date, to 2011. Its specific purposes are: a) Identifying regional performance regarding presented projects, resources authorized to be raised (AR), raised resources (RR) and failure in raising; b) Verifying if resources raising had redistributive effects among regions and states.

Information about incentives was taken straight from the Sports Ministry website4040. Ministério do Esporte [Internet]. Lei de Incentivo ao esporte [Access in May 20, 2016] Available in: Available in: http://www.esporte.gov.br/index.php/institucional/secretaria-executiva/lei-de-incentivo-ao-esporte
http://www.esporte.gov.br/index.php/inst...
. The available information allowed a database to be built with the following data: project proposing entity, year, federation unit from where the proponent is, approved amount to be raised, amount raised in the market, sponsors - with the respective resources planned on the projects. Over 733 projects on performance sport have been registered, in which state and regional distribution may be observed on Table 1.

Table 1
Distribution of the approved projects to the raised resources by the SIL from 2007 to 2011.

Analysis variables used here were resources authorized to be raised (AR), raised resources (SR), success and failure in raising resources and redistributive capacity. AR refer to those approved by the Sports Ministry to be raised at the market. RR are the numbers actually raised at the market. Success in raising are the projects that got over 90% of raised funds and failure means less than 20% of raising. SIL Execution Manual allows starting activities only on projects with a minimum funding of 20%.

When the researcher realized some proponents presented the same project with equal figures for consecutive years, up to 3 years, raised amount was add up: 146 projects entered in this case. In 12 situations, offering entities presented the same project twice. Following this criteria, a new configuration appears in the distribution of projects by Federative Units and regions, as it can be seen on Table 2.

Table 2
Distribution of SIL projects from 2007 to 2011 per unit of the federation.

Results

The first analysis regards AR. These resources, in terms of number of projects, allow to evaluate only regional distributions of needed competences in elaborating projects. Under this light, it is possible to observe that region Southeast represents 64,58% (Table 2) out of approved proposals. Together with region South, they are responsible for 91,14% of projects. That number by itself represents brutal concentration of technical abilities for the approval of projects in regions with better social and economic development, collaborating with the deepening of existent inequalities in Brazil.

Putting the first paragraph in Art. 2 from Act 11.438 together with Item 3 from Art. 3 in 1988 Federal Constitution it is possible to affirm that the design of law, by not imposing regional limits for approval of projects, ends up favoring more privileged regions. As it can e verified on Table 3, these are the ones that take better advantage of this possibility offered by the norm.

Table 3
Regional distribution of resources authorized (RA) to be raised with SIL from 2007 to 2011.

In the case of the involved figures, region Southeast overrepresents its participation when compared to the percentage of of approved projects. While region Southeast is responsible for 64,58% of projects, its participation on resources authorized to be raised was 76,67%. As it can be observed, regional distribution of capacities and interest in presenting projects reinforce inequalities already existent in the country.

In this respect, SIL performance keeps reproducing the status quo existent in the distribution of resources (in terms of number of projects) in performance sport registered in Brazilian municipalities profile - Sport, IBGE (2006).

Raising AR are not always fully raised. As market agents (sponsors) are the ones that define which projects will be transferred from public funds, their return maximization strategies end up interfering in the evaluation. Bearing in mind the parallel possible to be established between SIL and Rouanet Law, this aspect has been already discussed by culture field analysis2121. Oliveira LJ, Schwerter IMG. Breve análise das práticas de responsabilidade social empresariais e a concessão de incentivos governamentais em âmbito federal. Jus Navigandi 2007; [Access in April 12, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.derechoycambiosocial.com/revista010/responsabilidad%20social.htm
http://www.derechoycambiosocial.com/revi...
),(2222. Augustin AC. A farsa das leis de incentivo: o neoliberalismo e seu impacto na política cultural brasileira.[Trabalho de Conclusão de Curso de Ciências Econômicas]. Porto Alegre: Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul, Faculdade de Ciências Econômicas; 2010.),(2323. Nascimento AF. Política cultural no Brasil: do Estado ao mercado.[Internet] III ENECULT-Encontro de Estudos Multidisciplinares em Cultura 2007.[Access on May 25, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/AlbertoFreire.pdf
http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/Albe...
),(2424. Arruda MAN. A política cultural: regulação estatal e mecenato privado. Temp soci 2003;15(2):177-193.),(2525. Botelho I. Dimensões da cultura e políticas públicas. SP em Persp 2001;15(2):73-83.),(2626. Valiati L, Florissi S. A problemática da captação: relação entre os incentivos fiscais e a gestão dos recursos públicos na decisão privada da inversão cultural. Econ da Cul 2005:89-116. that repeat itself in SIL.

While the approval of a project is a relation between proposer and State, in which the latter defines the quality of offers, RR are a relation between proposer and platform of interests and needs of potential sponsors. As it can be seen on third column, Table 4, RR global performance rate has varied among regions. Regional economic agents present diverse behaviors.

Table 4
Regional distribution of raised resources (RR) from the LIE from 2007 to 2011.

In the case of region North, the lowest number of projects and amount of requested resources have helped guarantee higher percentage of RR among regions. The second best performance came from region Southeast. The raised 51,28% are nominally superior to the volume of AR from other regions. That demonstrates a strong economic dynamic in this region, capable of liberating great amounts of resources for performance sport. Even recognizing economic differences between Northeast and South, raising ability has not varied much, despite a slight advantage to the former.

Regarding deficit, there is a directly proportional relation between AR and RR. Perhaps the explanation for this reality is the limits of its own market in supporting the distribution of this amount of resources. In this case, potential sponsors end up vetoing the tax waiver authorized by the Federal Government. Knowing the reasons for this veto opens up an important window in the research after understanding limits of SIL.

Despite that projects may be readapted and start development at 20% of total rasing from raised resources, only the ones that obtained over 90% of RR are having the opportunity of being fully implemented. As it can be observed on the following table.

Table 5
Regional Distribution of projects/waiver that got over 90% of SIL from 2007 to 2011.

The first observation about Table 5 regards the RR (raised resources) in collection of over 90% AR. With the exception of region North, which has had the higher percentage of projects obtaining more than 90% of raising, the other regions had reached lower percentage. Region North seems to have its own dynamic, since region Northeast has reached a closer number of projects, but with a much inferior performance. However, when compared to region South, which has higher economic development, it obtained better results. Even with a high number of projects with more than 90% RR, region Northeast got the second best result. That emphasizes the potential this region has on guaranteeing investments needed for the full development of projects.

Regarding the earned waiver, region North stands out as the most efficient. Despite region Southeast having obtained only 25,84% of project resources, nominal reached value is very expressive. It demonstrates that economic environment of region Southeast is much favorable to raising resources for implementation of SIL in terms of performance sport.

It is noticeable the low efficiency in raising resources in the region with the second best economic development in the country, region south. In that case, higher development does not lead to higher success in resources rising. That means, there is not direct relation between success in raising and economic regional development.

Projects that did not obtain at least 20% of RR cannot carry out its object. This way, they are projects that were unsuccessful in raising resources.

Table 6
Regional distribution of project resources that got less than 20% of SIL from 2007 to 2011.

When it comes to percentage of unsucessful projects, there is no difference between regions Northeast, Center-West and Southest (Table 6). Region North, which holds lower economic development, obtained the best result. The worst one goes to region South. Region Southeast, even with a higher number of unsuccessful projects, got the second best result. So, it is a region almost unaffected by this reality.

Regarding resources, region Southeast was the one that obtained the second best result, only behind region North. Region Northeast, from the percentage point, got the worst result. Half AR could not be raised. Thus, there is no enrinment capable of promoting space for SIL. The same can be said about region South, with 29,50% inefficiency on raising AR.

Two variables allow a comparative analysis with results found able to hightlight market strength and redistributive role expected from public policies in sports field.

Regional GDP allows to verify he economic potential of the market. Region Southeast takes more than half wealth and regions North and Center-West get the worst result. The State Participation Fund follows another logic. It seeks to ward more vulnerable states in a way to assure minimum equitable standards for facing state challenges. Regions Northeast and North-West are the most privileged with resources. This indicates they are the regions with more difficulties to implement public policies.

The first indicator characterizes regional wealth concentration (market wealth). The second one, social justice on the distribution of public funds. It carries a redistibutive idea. As waiver resources are public, it is important to check whether they follow towards status quo in the distribution of public resources available in the market or are able to foster social justice.

As the transfer of political authority in the implementation of SIL shifts for the market, it is expected that resources concentrate in regions with higher GDP. Resources here are projects, figures authorized to be raised and raising success. The three variable may reproduce status quo, if they follow percentage distribution of GDP among regions, deepen inequalities, enhance positions of region higher in development, or reach redistributive objectives.

In the first case, percentage distribution of projects followed a dynamic of higher concentration of offers in higher development regions. Southeast and South obtained projects offers. Here, there seems to be a tendency to offer projects in regions of higher development and human capital able to present projects. The difference in technical capacity of regions to approve projects is a mark of inequality amplified by SIL.

Table 7
Comparative analysis between state distribution of GDP, FPE and projects that obtained more than 20% of SIL raised funds from 2007 to 2011 in PS by state and region.

When AR and GDP are compared, Southeast participation promotes strong resource concentration [GDP (55,5%); AR (76,67%)] (Table 7). There is a deepening in inequality towards the most developed region, going against tax waiver spirit, as mentioned by Sayd (2003). 88 Federal Constitution itself has established, on Item I from Art. 151, that tax waiver aims to promote balance among regions.

RR evaluation reproduces the reality found in the previous analysis. Southeast region is responsible for 70% of successful projects in raising and 88,37% of resources invested in these projects. Specially regarding resources, the invisible hand of the market works to guarantee incompatible concentration, even with the national wealth distribution. When political authority is transferred to the market, there happens a worsening in resource concentration and enhancing of State inefficiency. As revealed by Nascimento2323. Nascimento AF. Política cultural no Brasil: do Estado ao mercado.[Internet] III ENECULT-Encontro de Estudos Multidisciplinares em Cultura 2007.[Access on May 25, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/AlbertoFreire.pdf
http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/Albe...
, contemporary sponsorship tends to concentrate funds.

Final Considerations

As pointed out by Houlihan4141. Houlihan B. Public sector sport policy Developing a Framework for Analysis. Int Rev Soc of Sport 2005; 40(2):163-185., the five-year period selected allows to verify certain dynamic of public policy and the results show that the SIL is not fulfilling its main goal, the development of national sport. There has been a concentration of resources in regions Southeast and South, and significant loss of resources by less developed regions, North and Northeast. Such effect emphasizes regional inequalities.

The impressive and unequal difference in the presentation of projects by regions is a strong indicative of the need of action by the state to improve conditions for a balanced dispute for funds. SIL has deepened the asymmetry in resources distribution for PS among states and regions. In that case, results presented are aligned to Almeida’s1616. Sayd PD. Renúncia fiscal e eqüidade na distribuição de recursos para a saúde. [Tese de Doutorado] Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Oswaldo Cruz. Escola Nacional de Saúde Pública; 2003 analysis in which concerns the possible concentrating effect of the application of incentive laws (allocative distortion) in a country marked by profound inequalities in the access to funds. On the other hand, loss in collections by the State, via tax waiver, takes away an important tool to reduce these inequalities. Resources renounced due to waiver could be reused so that the govern might redirect them with the goal of reducing regional inequalities. Rouanet Law has not served as institutional learning for the Brazilian government follow a different path in SIL implementation. The state, by letting go of political authority, guarantees that market establishes its own priorities2121. Oliveira LJ, Schwerter IMG. Breve análise das práticas de responsabilidade social empresariais e a concessão de incentivos governamentais em âmbito federal. Jus Navigandi 2007; [Access in April 12, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.derechoycambiosocial.com/revista010/responsabilidad%20social.htm
http://www.derechoycambiosocial.com/revi...
.

Data also reveal the low efficiency of the market to guarantee success to projects approved by Sport Ministry with resources other than theirs. By investing in SIL projects, there is no loss in collecting. On the contrary, public resources are used to promote he image of investing companies. That means, State is used to promote private gains.

As it can be noticed, SIL implementation demonstrated that it is not a proper tool for the development of PS in Brazil. Its implementation seems to have happened, mainly, to enhance resources in states and regions that already are more developed regarding PS. SIL does not promote only resource concentration directed to performance sport; it also promotes huge regional inequality in the access to those resources.

Acknowledgment:

This study was suported by a National Counsel of Technological and Scientific Development (CNPq) of Ministry of Science, Technology and Innovation of Brasil and Ministry of Sports by public selection of scientific, technological and innovation research projects, aimed at the development of the sport in its different dimensions /Line 2-Public Policies and Management in Sport and Recreation No 91/2013 ME/CNPq

References

  • 1. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Lei nº 11.438 de 29 de dezembro de 2006. [Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_ato2004-2006/2006/lei/l11438.htm
    » http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_ato2004-2006/2006/lei/l11438.htm
  • 2. Almeida BS, Marchi Júnior W. O financiamento dos programas federais de esporte e lazer no Brasil (2004 a 2008). Movimento 2010;16(04):73-92.
  • 3. Athayde PFA, Mascarenhas F, Salvador EV. Primeiras aproximações de uma análise do financiamento da política nacional de esporte e lazer no governo Lula. Rev Bras Cie do Esp 2015;37(1):2-10.
  • 4. Figuerôa KM, Sevegnani P, Mezzadri FM, Silva MM. Planejamento, ações e financiamento para o esporte em tempos de megaeventos. Motri 2014;26(42):55-71.
  • 5. Teixeira MR, Matias WB; Mascarenhas F. O financiamento do esporte olímpico no Brasil: Uma análise do ciclo de Londres (2009-2012). Rev Cienc Social 2013: 110-86.
  • 6. Veronez LFC. O planejamento governamental e o orçamento do setor esportivo [Internet]. XV Congresso Brasileiro de Ciências do Esporte 2007 [Access in April13, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.cbce.org.br/docs/cd/resumos/275.pdf
    » http://www.cbce.org.br/docs/cd/resumos/275.pdf
  • 7. Silva MM, Mezzadri FM, Santos N, Camargo PR, Figuerôa KM. A configuração do ordenamento jurídico relativo ao financiamento do governo brasileiro ao esporte de rendimento: uma análise a partir da teoria dos jogos de Norbert Elias. Lúdic Pedag 2015;2(21):77-89.
  • 8. Castro SBE. Políticas públicas para o esporte e lazer e o ciclo orçamentário brasileiro (2004-2011): prioridades e distribuição de recursos durante os processos de elaboração e execução orçamentária. [Tese de Doutorado em Educação Física]. Curitiba: Universidade Federal do Paraná, Programa de Pós-graduação em Educação Física; 2016.
  • 9. Matias WB; Athayde PF; Húngaro EM. A Lei de Incentivo fiscal e o (não) direito ao esporte no Brasil. Movimento 2015; 21(1): 95-110.
  • 10. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Decreto nº 8.313 de 23 de dezembro de 1991.[Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/leis/L8313cons.htm
    » http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/leis/L8313cons.htm
  • 11. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Decreto nº 6.180 de 3 de agosto de 2007.[Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_Ato2007-2010/2007/Decreto/D6180.htm
    » http://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/_Ato2007-2010/2007/Decreto/D6180.htm
  • 12. Rawls J. Justiça como equidade: uma concepção política, não metafísica. Lua Nov: Rev de Cult e Polit 1992; (25): 25-29
  • 13. March J, Olsen JP. Neo-Institucionalismo: fatores organizacionais na vida política. Sociol e Polit 2008;16(31):121-142.
  • 14. Hall PA,Taylor RCR. As três versões do neo-institucioalismo. Lua Nov 2003; (58): 193-222.
  • 15. Bueno L. Política pública do esporte no Brasil: aplicação da Advocacy Coalition Framework. In.: Santos E, Leiro ACR. Políticas públicas de esporte e lazer: diálogos. Petrolina: UNIVASF; 2015. p. 17-47.
  • 16. Sayd PD. Renúncia fiscal e eqüidade na distribuição de recursos para a saúde. [Tese de Doutorado] Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Oswaldo Cruz. Escola Nacional de Saúde Pública; 2003
  • 17. Almeida FCR. Uma abordagem estruturada da renúncia de receita pública federal. Rev Trib Cont da Un 2000:19-62.
  • 18. Belem MP, Donadone JC. A Lei Rouanet e a construção do “mercado de patrocínios culturais”. Nov Rum Sociol 2013;1(1):50-61
  • 19. Mendes CC. O Território e o Arranjo Federativo para o Desenvolvimento Brasileiro: O caso do Nordeste. In: Linhares PTF, Mendes CC, Lassance A. (Org.) Federalismo à brasileira: questões para discussão Brasília, DF: Ipea; 2012. p. 89-111.
  • 20. Andreazzi MFS, Ocké-Reis CO. Renúncia de arrecadação fiscal: subsídios para discussão e formulação de uma política pública; Tax expenditures on health care: contributions toward a public policy agenda. Phys 2007;17(3):521-544.
  • 21. Oliveira LJ, Schwerter IMG. Breve análise das práticas de responsabilidade social empresariais e a concessão de incentivos governamentais em âmbito federal. Jus Navigandi 2007; [Access in April 12, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.derechoycambiosocial.com/revista010/responsabilidad%20social.htm
    » http://www.derechoycambiosocial.com/revista010/responsabilidad%20social.htm
  • 22. Augustin AC. A farsa das leis de incentivo: o neoliberalismo e seu impacto na política cultural brasileira.[Trabalho de Conclusão de Curso de Ciências Econômicas]. Porto Alegre: Universidade Federal do Rio Grande do Sul, Faculdade de Ciências Econômicas; 2010.
  • 23. Nascimento AF. Política cultural no Brasil: do Estado ao mercado.[Internet] III ENECULT-Encontro de Estudos Multidisciplinares em Cultura 2007.[Access on May 25, 2015] Available in: Available in: http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/AlbertoFreire.pdf
    » http://www.cult.ufba.br/enecult2007/AlbertoFreire.pdf
  • 24. Arruda MAN. A política cultural: regulação estatal e mecenato privado. Temp soci 2003;15(2):177-193.
  • 25. Botelho I. Dimensões da cultura e políticas públicas. SP em Persp 2001;15(2):73-83.
  • 26. Valiati L, Florissi S. A problemática da captação: relação entre os incentivos fiscais e a gestão dos recursos públicos na decisão privada da inversão cultural. Econ da Cul 2005:89-116.
  • 27. Pitombo M. Sintomas dos deslocamentos de poder na gestão do campo cultural no Brasil - uma leitura sobre as leis de incentivo à cultura. In: Pinheiro MT (Org.) Temas contemporâneos. Salvador: Editora FIB; 2006. p. 55-62.
  • 28. Silva FAB. Financiamento cultural: situação atual e questões para reflexão. Políticas sociais - acompanhamento e análise 2004 [Access on April 19, 2016]. Available in: Available in: http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/images/stories/PDFs/politicas_sociais/ENSAIO2_Frederico8.pdf
    » http://www.ipea.gov.br/portal/images/stories/PDFs/politicas_sociais/ENSAIO2_Frederico8.pdf
  • 29. Rubim AAC. Políticas culturais no Brasil: tristes tradições. Galáx 2006;7(13):101-113.
  • 30. Barros RP, Henriques R, Mendonça R. A estabilidade inaceitável: desigualdade e pobreza no Brasil. Available in: Henriques R. (Org.) Desigualdade e pobreza no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: IPEA; 2000, p. 21-48.
  • 31. Cavalcanti GEL. Análise Econômica das Políticas de Incentivos à Cultura no Brasil.[Dissertação de Mestrado em Finanças e Economia Empresarial]. Rio de Janeiro: Fundação Getúlio Vargas, Escola de Pós Graduação em Economia; 2006.
  • 32. Olivieri CG. Cultura neoliberal: leis de incentivo como política pública de cultura. São Paulo: Escrituras; 2015.
  • 33. Freitas LL. A lei Rouanet e a atual produção cultural brasileira: retrato da relação entre incentivo fiscal e a produção cultural no Brasil.[Trabalho de Conclusão de Curso de Pós-Graduação em Gestão de Projetos Culturais e Organização de Eventos]. São Paulo: Centro de Estudos Latino Americanos sobre Cultura e Comunicação, Universidade de São Paulo; 2012.
  • 34. Palácio do Planalto, Casa Civil [Internet]. Lei nº Lei 5.172 de 25 de outubro de 1966. [Access on April 11, 2015]. Available in: Available in: https://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/leis/L5172.htm
    » https://www.planalto.gov.br/ccivil_03/leis/L5172.htm
  • 35. Arretche M. Federalismo e políticas sociais no Brasil: problemas de coordenação e autonomia. SP em Persp 2004;18(2):17-26.
  • 36. Souza Junior CVN, Gasparini CE. Análise da Equidade e da Eficiência dos Estados no Contexto do Federalismo Fiscal Brasileiro. Estud Econ 2006; 36(4): 803-832
  • 37. Paes NL, Siqueira ML. Desenvolvimento regional e federalismo fiscal no Brasil: em busca da igualdade na distribuição de receitas. Econ Aplic 2008;12(4):707-742.
  • 38. Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística [Internet]. Perfil dos municípios brasileiros: esporte, 2003 [Access in May 20,2016] Available in: Available in: http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/economia/perfilmunic/esporte2003/default.shtm
    » http://www.ibge.gov.br/home/estatistica/economia/perfilmunic/esporte2003/default.shtm
  • 39. Santos ES, Freitas ALC. O direito ao desporto: Justiça Social e Políticas Públicas. Dir Fund e Jus 2015; (30): 139-157.
  • 40. Ministério do Esporte [Internet]. Lei de Incentivo ao esporte [Access in May 20, 2016] Available in: Available in: http://www.esporte.gov.br/index.php/institucional/secretaria-executiva/lei-de-incentivo-ao-esporte
    » http://www.esporte.gov.br/index.php/institucional/secretaria-executiva/lei-de-incentivo-ao-esporte
  • 41. Houlihan B. Public sector sport policy Developing a Framework for Analysis. Int Rev Soc of Sport 2005; 40(2):163-185.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    2017

History

  • Received
    14 June 2016
  • Reviewed
    31 Oct 2016
  • Accepted
    03 Dec 2016
Universidade Estadual de Maringá Avenida Colombo, 5790 - cep: 87020-900 - tel: 44 3011 4315 - Maringá - PR - Brazil
E-mail: revdef@uem.br