Abstracts
This paper analyses the effect of reforms to the PAYG system in the context of an open economy, using an overlapping generation, general equilibrium model. Parameterization is based on the Brazilian economy. The interest rate is supposed to follow an exogenous path during the transition. Several alternatives to reforming social security are studied, from the full elimination of benefits to the simple replacement of the social security tax for consumption or corporate revenue tax. Intermediary cases, where the retirement benefits are partly eliminated are studied as well. Macroeconomic and welfare effects are derived.
social security; welfare; general equilibrium; macroeconomics; overlapping generation
Esse artigo analisa os efeitos de reformas no sistema previdenciário de repartição no contexto de uma economia aberta, usando um modelo de gerações superpostas. A taxa de juros é suposta seguir uma trajetória exógena durante a transição. Várias alternativas de reformar o sistema previdenciário são estudadas, desde a plena eliminação dos benefícios até a simples substituição da contribuição sobre folha por um imposto sobre o consumo ou sobre a renda de capital. Casos intermediários, onde os benefícios de aposentadoria são parcialmente eliminados também são estudados. Efeitos macroeconômicos e de bem estar são estudados.
Social security reforms under an open economy: the Brazilian case* * I thank Rodolfo Manuelli for useful suggestions. I thank as well Peter Norman, John Karl Scholz, two anonymous referees, as well as participants of the workshops at UW-Madison and IBMEC-RJ for comments in early drafts. The usual disclaims are applied. I thank CNPq for the financial support that made this research possible. The opinions contained in this paper do not represent necessarily those of BNDES.
Sergio Guimarães Ferreira
BNDES and Universidade Candido Mendes. E-mail: sergiogu@bndes.gov.br
ABSTRACT
Summary: 1. Introduction; 2. The model; 3. Simulation results: the PAYG steady state and the "privatized" steady state; 4. A description of the alternative experiments; 5. Transitional impacts of the reforms; 6. Full privatization under balanced budget policies; 7. Summary of the experiments; 8. Conclusions.
This paper analyses the effect of reforms to the PAYG system in the context of an open economy, using an overlapping generation, general equilibrium model. Parameterization is based on the Brazilian economy. The interest rate is supposed to follow an exogenous path during the transition. Several alternatives to reforming social security are studied, from the full elimination of benefits to the simple replacement of the social security tax for consumption or corporate revenue tax. Intermediary cases, where the retirement benefits are partly eliminated are studied as well. Macroeconomic and welfare effects are derived.
Keywords: social security; welfare; general equilibrium; macroeconomics; overlapping generation.
JEL codes: E62; D58; D91.
RESUMO
Esse artigo analisa os efeitos de reformas no sistema previdenciário de repartição no contexto de uma economia aberta, usando um modelo de gerações superpostas. A taxa de juros é suposta seguir uma trajetória exógena durante a transição. Várias alternativas de reformar o sistema previdenciário são estudadas, desde a plena eliminação dos benefícios até a simples substituição da contribuição sobre folha por um imposto sobre o consumo ou sobre a renda de capital. Casos intermediários, onde os benefícios de aposentadoria são parcialmente eliminados também são estudados. Efeitos macroeconômicos e de bem estar são estudados.
1. Introduction
Social security privatization has been an issue in Latin America in the last decade. This paper uses a general equilibrium, overlapping generation model to look at macroeconomic effects and welfare implications of a wide spectrum of possible reforms of the PAYG system.
In Brazil, the social security reform has been defended under the argument that the system is currently unbalanced. The Constitution of 1988 has added to the PAYG regime an important contingent of individuals who have never contributed to the system. At the same time, the social security tax rate has not been adjusted in order to finance the increase in retirement benefits expenses. The current deficit has been financed through increases in tax on income and on corporate revenues.
Although the fiscal unbalance is an argument sufficiently strong to justify revising the system, there are multiple ways to do the job, from the extreme case of switching to individual retirement account up to the more conservative option of keeping the same structure of benefits, while adjusting the labor tax rate to restore the actuarial balance of the PAYG system.
The social security contribution leads to distortions in the labor supply decision if individuals perceive it as a tax, without a direct link with the future retirement benefits. The deadweight loss of such "tax" is larger as the difference between the real interest rate and the implicit interest rate yielded by "social security savings" gets larger.
It is worthwhile to ask which type and size of uncertainty faced by individuals would rationalize the existence of a costly mechanism of universal insurance like the PAYG system. There is a vast macroeconomic literature that looks at this question in details, by comparing different steady states, with and without social security. The general conclusion is that one needs to add a lot of uncertainty to justify the existence of the PAYG system in a normative way (e.g. De Nardi et al. (1999)).1 1 The usual argument of market failure in the annuity market due to asymmetric information about life duration, for example, requires substantially high coefficients of risk aversion to sustain a PAYG system. Imrohoroglu et al. (2002), for example, add time inconsistent preferences to the general setup to explain the existence of such system, and show that PAYG is Pareto-improving only under unreasonable parameter magnitudes. Bugarin et al. (2002) find that with credit constraints and sufficiently high probability of unemployment, a PAYG-type social security system that guarantees a minimum retirement income makes agents better off than under a totally private system. Deaton et al. (2002) reaches the same conclusion for US. However, even when unemployment risk is sufficiently high, it is likely that an unemployment insurance program will be a least expensive way to deal with such risk.
In the absence of a convincing reason for implementing a PAYG system, political economy arguments may explain the existence of social security in positive terms (e.g. Boldrin and Rustichini (1998) and Cooley and Soares (1999)). The first generations of beneficiaries will gain from the implementation of the PAYG, giving to themselves retirement benefits without ever having contributed before, at expenses of future generations. If intergenerational redistribution is behind the PAYG, then one must take into account the welfare impact of the alternative reforms on the generations alive during the transition to the new steady state when studying the end of such a system. Kotlikoff (1996) studies the elimination of the PAYG system looking at the welfare implications to the alive generations, for the USA. Ferreira (2002) uses the base model developed by Kotlikoff (1996), adapted to the characteristics of Brazilian PAYG system, to simulate impacts of a wide spectrum of reforms. Barreto and Oliveira (2000) looks at the transition of different reforms. Their model treats labor supply decision as exogenous, while Ferreira (2002) makes both consumption and labor supply endogenous over the life cycle.This paper extends the analysis of Ferreira (2002) to the open economy case. In a closed economy, social security reforms affect the marginal productivity of capital and labor. An increase in capital stock reduces coeteris paribus the marginal productivity of capital in order to clear demand and supply of savings. In an open economy, the interest rate is not affected by the increase in aggregate savings. Families buy foreign assets instead and the aggregate stock of capital is unchanged. The national income increases substantially while the gross domestic product is almost unaffected. Since the interest rate does not fall, asset accumulation by residents are larger as a result of the reform under the open economy case.
Differently from the closed economy case, labor supply is slightly affected by the reform. Income effect from larger non-labor income counteracts the increase in after-tax wage (resulting from the reduction in labor tax) with practically no impact in aggregate labor supply, since pre-tax wage is constant. Under the closed economy, a higher pre-tax wage works as incentive to larger labor supply by households.
Transition effects and the redistributive impacts of the reforms are similar to the closed economy case, but differs in magnitude. Among the reforms I look at are: full privatization of the system (financed alternatively by capital, labor or consumption taxation, or debt financed); keeping the PAYG but changing the financing scheme (switching from labor either to consumption, capital or income taxation). Most of these reforms are meant to have close connections with what has been proposed in the political agenda. For example, the possibility of replacing the social security tax for a consumption tax (equivalent to a value added tax) as well as switching to corporate revenue taxation were actually included in the Constitution Amendment approved by the Brazilian Congress in 2003.2 2 Since this is a one-sector model, it is impossible to model the cascade effect of corporate revenue tax, which become a regular income tax in my set up.
This paper is divided into eight sections. Section 2 presents the model. Section 3 presents the criterion for calibrating the initial steady state. Section 4 describes the alternative experiments. Section 5 gives an intuition about the intergenerational redistributive aspects of the transition. Section 6 goes through the details of the balanced budget transitions. Section 7 gives a summary of the results, and patterns observed. Section 8 concludes.
2. The Model
This section gives an overview of the 55-overlapping generation, general equilibrium model used in the simulations of the social security reforms, which is an adaptation of Auerbach and Kotlikoff (1987) to the Brazilian social security system. Consumers maximize preferences over a 55-year life cycle. They become eligible for retirement benefits at age 45, get their first retirement benefit at 46, and die at 56 years old. For an individual born in time t and aged j years old, the time additive utility function takes the form
where ct+j,j is her consumption of an aggregate consumption good and lt+j,jis her leisure demand. The household budget constraint depends on the current and future values of the interest rate and wage rate. In addition, it will depend on the future path of consumption, capital, and labor taxes. The model assumes that there is no uncertainty about such paths and no borrowing constraints.
The parameter tC,t is the proportional consumption tax, tK,t is the proportional capital tax and tL,t is the proportional labor tax. In addition, the retirement benefits are financed through a labor tax, qt. The variable PV Bt is the present value of lifetime social security benefits of generation t (born in year t),3 3 The term ej captures a job-experience productivity factor, represented by a second-degree polynomial on experience. such that:
The first term, in the right hand side, is a component that does not depend on the labor tax paid to finance the system. The second term means that one dollar of labor tax paid at age j will give back to the individual lj in future benefits (measured at the dollar value of time T = t + j). Hence, lj is the perceived age-dependent link between contributions and benefits. From equations (2) and (3), the modified consumer budget constraint then becomes:
The consumer maximizes (1) subject to the budget constraint (4) and to the constraint that the demand for leisure cannot be larger than one for each individual.4 4 In algebraic terms, lt+j < 1, which I call the labor force non participation constraint. The Lagrangian multiplier m t associated to this constraint will take a positive value when the individual is effectively retired from the labor force.
Solving the consumer problem for consumption and leisure, one can get a contemporaneous expression relating consumption and leisure for the individual born in time t:5 5 To simplify notation, I only use the time subscript for every variable. For example, lt+j represents the demand for leisure by a j-year-old individual in time t + j.
where
and
for every time t and age j.
Additional algebra allows one to get the individual consumption and leisure profile over the life cycle:
where
The social security labor tax at time "t" is determined endogenously from the social security balanced budget, in such way that
Individuals are eligible for the benefits in the year they turn 46. The retirement benefit in year t of a j-year old cohort, Bt,j, will have two components: a time-dependent fraction called the "replacement rate", Rt, which does not depend on the age of the individual, and the average index of monthly earnings, AIMEt,j, which will be a function of time and age.
The average index of earnings of an individual age j in year t is calculated based on two indicators: the labor income earned when the individual was 33 to 35 years old, , and the labor income earned at the edge of the eligibility for the benefits, between ages 43 and 45, :6 6 In Brazil, eligibility to retirement benefits is reached through two mutually exclusive ways: one based on the number of years of contributions (35 years for men and 30 years for women) and other strictly based on age (65 years). In this representative agent set up, I assume only the old age eligibility criterion, but artificially incorporate some aspects of the contribution-based criterion in the formula of calculation of benefits.
At any time t, the government tax revenue consists of three possible tax instruments: a proportional consumption tax rate tC,t, a proportional labor tax tL,t and a proportional capital tax tK,t. The aggregate tax revenue is given by
where Ct, Kt and Lt are respectively the aggregate consumption, capital and labor supply in time t, as defined below.
Assuming there is no Ponzi Game, the government budget constraint (excluding social security) will be:
where D0 is the stock of outstanding debt at the initial year and Gt is the government consumption.
The model has a single production sector that is assumed to behave competitively, using capital and labor subject to constant-returns to scale production function. The production function is assumed to have a Cobb-Douglas form
where:
Yt is aggregate product;
Kt is capital stock;
Lt is labor, and
F is the technological constant.7 7 Under an open economy, this is not necessarily as same as national income. Aggregate labor supply Lt is determined by the consumer's labor supply decision, Lt,j, such that
that is, the sum of effective labor supplied by each individual cohort alive in year t. The supply of domestic capital will be given by
It is possible to be larger or smaller than the domestic demand for capital because the interest rate is given. In such case, capital migrates to other countries. For the purpose of aggregate welfare, the relevant variable is the national income, which depends on the supply of capital. If the country exports capital, the national income will be larger than the national product:
The open economy constraint implies that the interest rate sequence will be given by
where is a sequence of foreign interest rates, which are assumed exogenous.
Assuming a price taker, infinite life representative firm, the profit maximization condition will imply that clearing in the labor market will be given by
Given rt, the total demand for capital by the firms in Brazil will be given by
E Economy-Wide Feasibility Constraint
Assume Ht is the stock of foreign assets owned by residents in time t. The feasibility constraint of this economy is given by8 8 Ct is the aggregate consumption, given by .
Foreign capital, , freely flows inward or outward the country to meet the demand for capital, given the foreign interest rate:9 9 This means that foreign supply of capital is infinitely elastic to interest rate changes.
In such a scenario, foreign liabilities are represented by :10 10 represents the net foreign liabilities in the country, which includes net foreign debt, the stock of foreign physical capital, the stock of foreign financial assets, minus the stock Brazilian assets abroad (including loans, financial assets and physical capital). The path of will indicate what happens with the stock of foreign liabilities once the reforms are performed.
The country's current account balance over a period, by definition, is the change in the value of its net claims on the rest of the world the change in its net foreign assets.11 11 Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996). For example, if the country's resident are accumulating net foreign assets over a period, this means that the household savings are exceeding the amount needed to finance the changes in capital stock. This implies a surplus in the current account and negative net foreign savings. The current account surplus will be given here by
Hence, the current account surplus will be a function of the aggregate national saving and the total investment:12 12 Note that Yt is the net national income, which will be the concept of income used in the simulations. The aggregate national saving is defined as º Yt Ct Gt.
The solution of the model starts by setting a path for the exogenous interest rate during the transition. The capital-labor ratio will be a function of the exogenous interest rate path.13 13 This is driven by the assumption of a homothetic production function. Hence, the wage path will be a function of the interest rate:
Given the pair of input prices (wt ,), the stock of government debt Dt, and the tax rates, household optimal behavior will determine the supply of domestic capital and the aggregate labor supply, Lt. The demand for capital from the firms will be determined by the following equation:
In other words, the path of capital stock will be totally determined by the path of aggregate labor supply. Foreign capital, , will be the difference between the stock of capital and the domestic capital, and the current account surplus will be equivalent to the variations in .
3. Simulation Results: the PAYG Steady State and the "Privatized" Steady State
Simulations requires setting up parameters for the utility and production functions. Appendix C Appendix C summarizes the numerical assumptions. I assume an intertemporal elasticity of substitution of 0.305.14 14 Depending on the utility function, Issler and Piqueira (2000) find that the elasticity of substitution varies between 0.20 (CRRA) and 1.33 (Kreps-Porteur) using Brazilian data. I assume an intratemporal elasticity of substitution between leisure and consumption of 1.1.15 15 There is no estimate of the intratemporal elasticity of substitution for Brazil. So I chose a value close to estimates for US economy. Ghez and Becker (1975) find 0.83, and I allow some degree of freedom in order to the steady state life cycle labor supply match real data. The other parameters of the utility function were used as instruments for calibration of the initial steady state.16 16 This is specially the case if the leisure-preference parameter, used as a free parameter for calibration purposes. The time discount rate (1.5%) is chosen because it renders reasonable life cycle profile for the labor supply. From Brazil, I adopted the estimated share of labor income (0.5), and the estimated life cycle wage profile.17 17 This was obtained by running weight least squares regressions from a series of years of PNAD, a household survey. Details are found in Ferreira (2002). In addition, the social security link (lt) is assumed to be close to one for the three years preceding eligibility, and zero otherwise. Results however will not be sensitive to changes in such a parameter.
Parameter values are chosen in order to generate a current account deficit of the 3.06% GNP, that was the average for the period 1995/2000. The endogenous social security tax is 10.38%. The capital-output ratio is 3.76. The ratio of the government debt over the GNP is 30%. The national saving rate is 4% of GNP. The current account deficit is 3.14% of GNP,18 18 CAt/Yt = n.( / Yt) in steady state, since every aggregate grows proportionally to the population. The simulated ratio / Yt is 1.65 and the population growth is 1.9%. which leads to a total aggregate saving rate of 7.14% of GNP.19 19 Given the K/Y, this saving rate is the one needed to sustain a 1.9% output growth.
The stock of net foreign liabilities is 165% of GNP.20 20 If one considers a 15% interest rate over the total stock of foreign liabilities generated in the initial steady state (1.65 GNP), the total income of non residents would be 24.7% GNP, ten times larger than the estimated for Brazil. Such disparity indicates either that the true degree of openness of the Brazilian economy is not as large as the one assumed here or that such dividends and interest rates earned by foreign assets have been re-invested, not showing in the balance of payments. Table 1 summarizes the initial steady state.
Privatizing the system leads to a substantial welfare improvement, under the assumed parameterization, and assuming that the government runs a balanced budget during the whole transition.21 21 The labor tax falls from 30.4% to 17.3%, the consumption tax falls from 15% to 12% and the capital tax falls from 13% to 11%. Hence, most of the positive effects from privatization comes from the reduction in the labor tax. An individual born in T = 150 will be 16% better off than under the old PAYG. The national income is 19% larger and aggregate consumption increases by 25%. The stock of domestic capital increases by 55%. The total stock of capital is roughly at the same level as it was in T = 0.22 22 Recall that the capital is proportional to the aggregate labor supply. The aggregate labor supply does not increase because the substitution effect resulting from the reduction in the labor tax (which falls from 30.4% to 17.3%) is compensated by the positive income effect coming from the increase in national income. The dependence on foreign capital falls from 165% to only 40% of GNP. The lower K*/Y ratio will be compatible with a current account deficit of just 0.77% of GNP.
4. A Description of the Alternative Experiments
In this section, I study the macroeconomic and welfare effects of twelve different experiments, which are summarized in table 2. Most of the policy experiments assume that the PAYG system is replaced by a fully-funded, defined-contribution, individual-account-based system. Yet, I simulate milder reforms that keep the PAYG unchanged and switch the tax base.
In experiment A, the social security labor tax is reduced to zero in year T = 1. At the same time, the replacement rate Rt goes to zero instantaneously, which implies a 100% cut in retirement benefits. Capital, labor and consumption tax rates are made endogenous.
In experiments B, C, D and E, the social security tax is zeroed in year T = 1, but the replacement rate is phased out to zero over a 55-year period. The idea is to preserve the claims to retirement benefits for the individuals alive in year T = 1. In effect, the replacement rate Rt is kept at 100% until year 9, when the youngest retiree of year T = 0 dies. In year T = 10, Rt starts falling at a constant rate until it reaches zero in T = 55.
While benefits are gradually eliminated, in year T = 1 one specific tax rate is chosen to replace the old social security tax for financing the remaining benefits. The chosen tax rate is made endogenous, while the other three tax rates are kept at the same level as they were at T=0. The endogenous tax rate is left to vary, first increasing and then decreasing, as the general equilibrium effects cause the increase of the tax base. In all of these four experiments, the adjusted tax rate will go back to its initial level, in some year T*, which will be different depending on the experiment. In T* + 1, every tax rate is made endogenous, constrained to generate the same revenue share as in T = 0. In experiment B, the consumption tax rate is temporarily endogenous. In experiment C, D and E, capital, labor and "income" tax rates are respectively selected to replace the social security tax.
In particular, "income tax" is defined as a proportional tax on both capital and labor tax income. The portion tI,t of the capital and labor taxes is endogenously determined in order to match the new revenue requirements, according to the equation below:
In experiment F, the assumption of a balanced budget is relaxed. Once again, the social security tax is zeroed in year T = 1. However, the four tax rates are assumed to be constant at their levels in T = 0. The government budget constraint runs a deficit until year T = 8, when the four tax rates are adjusted at once in order to balance the budget. As in the previous exercises, the tax rates will be constrained to generate the same share of revenue as in T = 0.
In experiments G, H, and I, the replacement rate Rt is kept constant until T = 19. In year T = 20, Rt is abruptly reduced to zero. The social security tax will not be eliminated, and is kept in order to finance the retirement benefits. In effect, as soon as the replacement rate goes to zero, qt falls to zero. This occurs in T = 20. Under the assumption of no uncertainty, these three experiments works as if the policy maker had announced the elimination of the PAYG system twenty years before the event actually happen. The difference among the experiments is related to the path followed by the capital, labor and consumption tax rates.
In experiment G, the three tax rates are made endogenous in T = 1 in order to balance the government budget (excluding social security), constrained to keep the same revenue share as in the initial steady state. In experiment H, the tax rates are set exogenous at the initial steady state level until year T = 20, and the government is allowed to run a budget surplus. After T = 20, the tax rates are endogenously determined in order to eliminate the surplus. Experiment I is exactly equal to experiment H, except that the three tax rates are kept constant until T = 25, instead of T = 20. This difference will be responsible for the creation of a large government budget surplus.
Experiments J to L refer to partial reforms in the PAYG system. In exercise J, the replacement rate Rt is phased out until reaching 30% in T = 60, being kept constant after then. The social security tax qt is endogenously determined in order to generate enough revenue to finance the retirement benefits.
The last two exercises assume that the replacement rate is kept at 100%, and the only change is the elimination of the social security tax and replacement by some other tax. In experiment K, the social security tax is zeroed in T = 1 and the consumption tax rate becomes endogenous in order to balance the government budget. In experiment L, an "income tax" defined according to equation (32), is levied to replace the social security tax. Effectively, the social security tax is partly replaced by a capital tax in this experiment.
5. Transitional Impacts of the Reforms
Why do we care for transitional paths? The reason is that the initial generations and their respective offspring will not benefit from macroeconomic environment in a distant future, when they will be already dead. However, those are the individuals who will build political coalitions to carry out the reform, choosing whether or not to reform. Hence, knowing how the current generations and those who will be alive in a near future are affected by the alternative reforms will give some insights about which type of reform will end up being chosen.
In this model, the only source of heterogeneity is given by the stage of the life cycle the individual will be at the moment of the reform, which will determine the lifetime budget constraints she faces. Depending on the transitional tax path, some generations will lose and others will gain. One could think that the generations alive in T=1 will vote to choose which transitional scheme will be followed. The outcome of the intergenerational conflict would determine how radical the reform would be as well.
The figures below give a hint on how the initial generations will be affected by different tax schemes, based only on their life cycle position when the reform starts. Individuals older than 60 are essentially asset owners, and consume over their wealth23 23 The resultant high marginal propensity to consume of older individuals is a consequence of ruling out the bequest motive from the individual utility function. (figure 1). This elderly group is strongly hurt by an increase in the consumption tax rate. As figure 2 shows, the individuals younger than 50 earn most of their income from labor supply. This group should are especially a target of a labor tax, and should gain in case of reduction in the social security labor tax. Individuals older than 51 already have accumulated enough assets to have most of their income coming from this source. A tax on capital will evenly distribute the tax burden across these middle aged and elderly individuals. Obviously, a tax on retirement benefits will hurt almost exclusively the retirees alive in year T = 1.
6. Full Privatization under balanced Budget Policies
In this section, I look at the experiments A to F, in which the social security tax is eliminated in T = 1. I use figures 3, 4 and 5 to compare the experiments and focus on the evolution of the current account surplus (deficit when negative) and on the path followed by the net foreign liability, in each of the experiments. The details of each experiment are left to the tables in the Appendixes A Appendix A and B Appendix B .
The elimination of the PAYG system generally decreases dependence on foreign capital. In the new steady state, the balanced-budget policies will drive down the ratio K*/Y from 1.65 to 0.40. This will be compatible with a current account deficit of only 0.77% of GNP in the "privatized" steady state.
Nonetheless the evolution of both the current account balance and of the net foreign liability K* will vary substantially in the "short run", depending on the tax chosen to finance the transition.
The "Cold Turkey" policy (experiment A) is the only one that manages to revert the initial current account deficit. The strong increase in domestic capital accumulation reduces the demand for foreign savings.24 24 This capital accumulation occurs at the expenses of the generations retired in T = 1, which have their retirement benefits cut and are forced to increase their labor supply in order to survive. In the first year of the transition, the increase in the total stock of capital is partly financed by the increase in domestic capital accumulation. Once the aggregate labor supply starts falling (T = 2), the total capital stock starts falling back to its initial value, which contributes to the current account surplus.25 25 Under the closed economy, the aggregate labor supply increased substantially in the long run, and this effect was at least partly a result of higher real wage. Under this open economy, the "privatization" of social security does not lead to a higher aggregate labor supply in the long run. This is a consequence of the constant real wage during the transition. Successive current account surpluses will manage to reduce the stock of foreign liability quickly. By T = 25, the stock of foreign capital will be less than 50% of the stock in T = 0.
When the transition is financed by a temporary consumption tax (experiment B), the impacts on the current account balance are similar to the cold turkey scheme, since the same intergenerational redistribution of lifetime resources happens. The fast increase in domestic capital accumulation leads to a substantial decrease in the current account deficit, from 3.14% to 0.83% of GNP (T = 15). The reduction in the stock of foreign liability is substantial, and by T = 25, the ratio K*/Y falls from 1.65 to 1.2.
If the policy maker increases the capital tax rate (experiment C) in order to finance the remaining retirement benefits, there would be a strong negative impact on domestic capital accumulation. The domestic capital stock falls by 5% in the first ten years. At the same time, the total capital stock increases by 5%in the first ten years, following the aggregate labor supply.26 26 Capital stock is proportional to the aggregate labor supply. The labor supply increases by 5%, especially because of the increasing supply of middle aged and older workers, who suffer income loss under capital taxation. The combination of these two effects leads to a substantial increase in the demand for foreign capital. The current account deficit increases from 3.14% to 5.32% in T = 10. The stock of foreign liability increases from 165% to 194% of GNP. In the presence of borrowing constraints, a transition financed by capital tax may not be feasible.
The transition financed by levying a temporary labor tax (experiment D) is similar to the gradual elimination of the social security tax.27 27 The only difference between the social security labor tax and the regular labor tax is the existence of links between retirement benefits and social security contributions. Domestic capital accumulation gradually increases, and the current account deficit is gradually reduced to the long run level. The same can be said about the foreign liability - national income ratio.
Suppose now that instead of financing the phased out benefits through an increase in the tax rates, the policy maker runs a deficit in the first seven years following the elimination of the social security tax (experiment F). In the 8th year, the policy maker adjusts all the tax rates in order to balance the budget, keeping the same proportion of collected revenues for each tax type. The transition can be divided in two distinct periods: the first, from T = 1 to T = 7. The second, after the tax adjustment in T = 8.
In the first period, the labor taxation drops by 10.3%, and labor supply reacts immediately (as well as the capital stock). Aggregate labor supply rises by 5% in T = 1. Government debt increases more than two-fold, going from 30% to 78% of GNP in seven years. The increase in current account deficit during this period is a result of the larger capital stock. The deficit increases from 3.14% to 3.86% in T = 6.
After the tax adjustment, the labor supply drops substantially, which is a result of higher labor taxation.28 28 The consumption tax is raised from 15% to 22.2%, while the labor tax goes from 20% to 27.5% and the capital tax goes from 13% to 18.1%. Since the total capital stock is exactly proportional to the aggregate labor supply, this implies that in year T=8, the total capital stock will be 2% smaller than its value in the initial steady state, and 6.4% smaller than in T = 7.29 29 Such dive explains why the current account balance goes from a deficit to a huge surplus (21% of GNP) in year T = 7. The fall in capital stock leads to a decrease in the stock of foreign liability from 180% to 163% in T = 8. The substantially higher capital tax induces a reduction in domestic capital accumulation and this leads to an increase in the current account deficit, which stays above the value in the initial steady state until T=47 and stays above 4% of GNP from T = 8 to T = 18.30 30 In T=25, the domestic capital stock is 4% below the initial level. Consequently, there is an increase in the dependence on foreign capital. The K*/Y ratio increases from 165% to 180% in T=40, and then falls smoothly to the long run level.
In the long run, debt accumulation leads to permanently higher consumption and capital taxes than in the initial steady state.31 31 Consumption tax will be 2.2% higher and capital tax will be 1.3% higher then under the PAYG steady state. Labor tax falls from 30.4% to 22%. In T = 150, the domestic capital stock is 15% higher than in T = 0, compared to a 55% increase when the transition happens under a balanced-budget tax scheme. The debt accumulation leads to smaller long run reductions in the stock of foreign liability driven by social security reform, compared to the balanced budget policies. In the long run, the K*/Y ratio falls to 128% (compared to 40% of GNP under balanced-budget policies). Since the current account in its steady state is equal to n(K*/Y), a higher capital-ratio leads to a higher transaction account deficit, which falls from 3.14% to 2.42% of GNP.
The intergenerational redistribution going on under the open economy do not differ from a closed economy. In order to compare with the results of the new experiments below, I give a brief overview of the conflicts between the generations. Figure 5 plots the rest of life utility ratio across the cohorts alive during the transition.32 32 One measure of these utility differences is the equivalent percentage increase in full lifetime resources (assets plus the present value of earnings based on working full time) needed in the original PAYG regime to produce each cohort's realized level of utility under the specified alternative regime. Here, I will use the concept of rest of life (ROL) wealth equivalent, instead of lifetime wealth equivalent. The reason for doing so is that agents too old experience almost no losses in their lifetime utility, since the weight of their last years is small in their total life. So, I prefer to look at the ratio between their ROL utility when living x years under the transition scheme and their ROL utility if they had lived the same x years under the old PAYG regime. Such criterion makes the welfare impact independent on the number of years being considered.
The consumption tax policy put most of the tax burden over the individuals "born" before year T = -25.33 33 The "birth date" is the year when the individual complete 20 years. Hence, the chronological age (in T = 1) of an individual "born" in T = -25 is 45 years old. The capital tax scheme focuses on middle aged workers and is the least preferred option for individuals "born" between T = -40 and T = -18. Curiously, it is the most preferable among the extremely young ("born" between T = -9 and T = 1), because it leads to a fast recovery after some initial depression on income. The labor tax policy is the most equitable scheme, and imposes a relatively higher tax burden on the initial youth. Individuals "born" after T = -18 have less welfare gains under such a tax scheme. The debt-financing scheme redistributes the lifetime income from the unborn generations to the old and middle aged individuals in T = 1, with a permanently lower welfare impact in the long run.
Note that no tax path is strictly preferred by any of the generations alive by the time of the reform. In particular, the status quo is preferred by individuals born between years T = -42 and T = -26. Under this simple model is possible to potentially explain substantial resistance to switching to a private scheme. The reform financed by labor tax leads to smaller intergenerational redistribution, but it is not the most preferred by any of the individuals alive, since it leads to slow convergence.
7. Summary of the Experiments
The final welfare impact of each reform over the alive and the future generations will be a result both of the direct impact of the tax instruments on their lifetime income and of the indirect impact, through general equilibrium effects of the reforms. The main conclusions from the simulations are summarized below:
First, the convergence is faster if the tax policy shifts more lifetime resources from the initial old to the initial youths, as it is the case under cold turkey, consumption tax transition and capital tax transition. The intuition is simple: old individuals are dis-saving and do not work. Shifting lifetime resources from this group will rapidly reduce aggregate consumption and will increase aggregate labor supply.
Secondly, consumption tax schemes lead to substantial welfare losses to the initial older generation, but higher lifetime wealth for those born in the ten years following the tax switch, even when there is no elimination of retirement benefits. Even when the PAYG remains unchanged and there is only a switch from labor tax to consumption tax in the financing of retirement benefits, the welfare gain of the individuals in T=10 are just slightly smaller than the gains obtained by the same individuals if benefits were reduced to zero. Such welfare improvement is driven by the fast convergence.
Third, increasing capital tax can lead to substantially negative impacts on the domestic capital, especially if benefits are not eliminated, as it is the case in experiment L. Such tax scheme transfers lifetime resources from high savers middle aged to prodigal youths, hurting especially the initial middle-aged individuals.
Fourth, three alternative ways to transfer lifetime resources from youths and unborn to initial elderly are: labor tax transition, government debt accumulation or postponing the elimination of the social security tax. These alternatives were shown respectively in experiments D, F, G, H and I. Gradually decreasing the social security tax or replacing the social security tax by a labor tax benefits the older individuals because they hardly work. For the opposite reason, this will cause welfare losses to youngsters. Such a tax scheme will be the most equitable since no agent will be more than 2% worse off than she would be under the alternative of no reform.
Postponing the tax adjustment, by accumulating government debt, mostly benefits the middle aged and elderly, and raises the long run tax rate. Hence, it is a redistribution from all future generations to the alive ones.
Delaying the elimination of the social security tax transfers lifetime resources from the current youths and individuals born in the first 25 years of the transition to the elderly and middle aged, and (in cases H and I) to the individuals born after year T = 50. The group of "losers" will not enjoy the large tax relieve coming from the elimination of the social security tax. The elderly will not suffer any elimination of retirement benefits. The individuals born after T = 50 will enjoy even greater tax reduction, since the accumulation of a surplus reduces the stock of government debt.
Fifth, special attention is devoted to the demand for foreign capital during the transition. Fully privatizing the system generates substantial reductions in the stock of foreign liability in the long run, but the short run results are completely different and may determine the interruption of the transition if the country faces a temporary borrowing constraint. The most obvious example is when capital tax finances the remaining retirement benefits. Experiment C shows that under such tax scheme the current account deficit would reach 5% of GNP on average in the first ten years. Financing this demand for foreign capital would require the stock of foreign liability to reach 200% of GNP in the first twenty years.
On the other hand, a consumption tax scheme would render a fast transition. The demand for foreign capital would decrease substantially, and by the year T = 25 the ratio /GN Pt would reach 120%, compared to 186% under a capital tax. It is clear that a capital tax transition might make the economy more subject to some sort of financial instability during the first years of the transition. Alternatively, increasing the government debt during the transition and postponing the tax adjustment would keep the foreign liability above the initial steady state level for nearly 50 years. Hence, the same conclusions for the capital tax apply in this case.
Last but not least, although it was not a goal of this paper to look at long run impacts of the reform, I find that a substantial share of the welfare improvement of ending the PAYG system in this model could be accomplished by just switching the tax base. Replacing a consumption tax for the old labor tax renders a 7% improve in welfare of the generations in the new steady state (experiment K). Nonetheless, a switch from labor to capital-income tax leads to only 2% increase in welfare after 150 years of transition. Long run results of decreasing the replacement rate from 100% to 30% are about 75% of the total welfare gain of full privatization (experiment J). Such a result argues strongly in favor of some sort of mixed system, with a minimum retirement income financed by a small tax on labor.
8. Conclusions
This paper differs from Ferreira (2002) and Kotlikoff (1996) on the assumption of free capital mobility, which leads to an exogenous and (assumed) constant interest rate. Because the production function presents constant returns to scale, this implies that the marginal productivity of capital is homogeneous of degree zero, and leads to a constant capital-labor ratio. Hence the marginal productivity of labor is constant as well.
Taking as the example the case where the PAYG is eliminated, in Ferreira (2002) the variation in the relative factor prices lessens the impact of social security reforms on capital accumulation. Under an open economy, there will be a much larger impact on the domestic capital accumulation (since the interest rate does not fall as a result of higher savings). Under the closed economy, the marginal productivity of labor increases and hence there is an increase in aggregate labor supply in the long run.
Under the open economy case, the effect of changes in the relative price of labor (resulting from the tax elimination) is more than offset by income effects resulting from higher capital income, and there is a slight fall in aggregate labor supply. The aggregate total capital (which is equal to the capital owned by residents in the closed economy case) will follow the same path of the aggregate labor supply, since wage and interest rate are constant over the transition.
Incorporating features of an open economy in this paper allows one to think about impact on the current account of reforms of large magnitude. Results in this paper shows that financing the transition to a fully funded system will lead to completely different impacts on the current account, depending on the tax chosen.
This paper was received in Jan. 2003 and approved in Aug. 2003
- Altig, D., Auerbach, A. J., Kotlikoff, L. J., Smetters, K. A., & Walliser, J. (2001). Simulating fundamental tax reform in the United States. American Economic Review, 91(3):574-95.
- Altonji, J., Hayashi, F., & Kotlikoff, L. (1997). Parental altruism and inter-vivo transfers: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 105(6):1121-1166.
- Auerbach, A. & Kotlikoff, L. (1987). Dynamic Fiscal Policy Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
- Barreto, F. & Oliveira, L. (2000). Transição para regimes previdenciários de capitalização e seus efeitos macroeconômicos de longo prazo no Brasil. Estudos Econômicos, 31(1):57-87.
- Boldrin, M. & Rustichini, A. (1998). Political equilibria with social security. Review of Economic Dynamics, 3:41-78.
- Bugarin, M., Ellery Jr., R., Gomes, V., & Teixeira, A. (2002). The Brazilian depression in the 1980s and 1990s. Unpublished manuscript, 2002.
- Cooley, T. & Soares, J. (1999). A positive theory of social security based on reputation. Journal of Political Economy, 107(1):135-160.
- De Nardi, M., Imrohoroglu, S., & Sargent, T. (1999). Projected US demographics and social security. Review of Economic Dynamics, 2(3):575-615.
- Deaton, A., Gourinchas, P., & Paxson, C. (2002). Social security and inequality over the life cycle. In Feldstein, M. & Liebman, J. (eds.), editor, The Distributional Aspects of Social Security and Social Security Reform University of Chicago Press, Chicago. NBER Conference report Series.
- Ferreira, S. (2002). Macroeconomic and welfare effects of social security reforms. proceedings of the North American meeting of the econometric society. Summer. Los Angeles.
- Ghez, G. & Becker, G. (1975). The Allocation of Time and Goods over the Life Cycle Columbia University Press, New York.
- Imrohoroglu, A., Imrohoglu, S., & Joines, D. (2002). Time inconsistency preferences and social security. Proceedings of the North American Meeting of the Econometric Society, Summer. Los Angeles.
- Imrohoroglu, S., Huang, H., & Sargent, T. (1995). Two computations to fund social security. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 1(1):7-44.
- Issler, J. & Piqueira, N. (2000). Estimating relative risk aversion, the discount rate, and the intertemporal elasticity of substitution in consumption for Brazil using three types of utility function. Brazilian Review of Econometrics, 20(2):201-239.
- Kotlikoff, L. (1996). Simulating the privatization of social security in general equilibrium. In Feldstein, M., editor, Privatizing Social Security - Chicago and London, pages 265-306. University of Chicago Press.
- Kotlikoff, L., Smetters, K., & Walliser, J. (1998a). Opting out of social security and adverse selection. NBER Working Paper: 6430.
- Kotlikoff, L., Smetters, K., & Walliser, J. (1998b). Social security: Privatization and progressivity. American Economic Review, 88(2):137-141.
- McGarry, K. & Schoeni, R. (1995). Transfer behavior: Measurement and the redistribution of resources within the family. Journal of Human Resources, 30(5):S184-S226.
- Obstfeld, K. & Rogoff, M. (1996). Foundations of International Macroeconomics MIT Press, Cambridge.
Appendix A
Appendix C
Publication Dates
-
Publication in this collection
14 Jan 2005 -
Date of issue
Sept 2004
History
-
Received
Jan 2003 -
Accepted
Aug 2003