Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Abstract

Using a simple Cournot duopoly model, this paper provides an important policy implication for trade disputes involving export subsidies. In this paper, the possibility that a foreign export subsidy could benefit the domestic country as well as the foreign country by appropriately using countervailing duties is identified.

Export subsidies; Countervailing duties; Welfare; Countervailing percentage; Cost-efficiency


ARTIGOS

Export subsidies, countervailing duties, and welfare

Yu-Ter Wang

Department of Economics, Ming Chuan University, No. 5, Teh-Ming Rd., Gwei-Shan, Taoyuan 333, Taiwan. E-mail: ytwang@mcu.edu.tw

ABSTRACT

Using a simple Cournot duopoly model, this paper provides an important policy implication for trade disputes involving export subsidies. In this paper, the possibility that a foreign export subsidy could benefit the domestic country as well as the foreign country by appropriately using countervailing duties is identified.

Keywords: Export subsidies; Countervailing duties; Welfare; Countervailing percentage; Cost-efficiency

JEL Classification: F12; F13; L13

1. INTRODUCTION

In the literature on strategic trade policy, Brander and Spencer (1985) show that a foreign export subsidy will increase foreign welfare in the absence of retaliation. Next, Dixit (1988) shows that the optimal domestic response to a foreign export subsidy is to retaliate with a partial countervailing duty (CVD) and Collie (1991, 1994) shows that a foreign country would be deterred from subsidizing exports when the optimal partial CVD is adopted. By contrast, Qiu (1995) offers some factors, including the delay in retaliation, the CVD level and voluntary export restraints, to explain why the CVD measures cannot deter the foreign export subsidy. In a recent study, by separating CVD determination from the import tariff, Wang (2004) finds that whether the optimal CVD can deter the export subsidy set by the foreign government depends on the existing import tariff level.

Until now, however, what is not considered is whether foreign export subsidies can benefit the domestic country as well when it improves foreign welfare. If the answer is affirmative, then why will the domestic country bar the foreign country from subsidizing exports? The purpose of this paper is to examine this issue.

Differing from the previous model in the literature on export subsidies and CVDs, this paper assumes that trade policies are determined in an exogenous way, because of political factors and other such considerations, with the result that optimal trade policies that maximize national welfare are usually unavailable in practice. For instance, the pressure exerted by certain countries, such as Brazil and Australia, in the WTO negotiations has forced the U.S. to promise to remove some of its subsidies on agricultural exports (see also Hansen and Prusa (1997)). Under such a setting, this paper identifies the possibility that a foreign export subsidy can benefit the domestic country as well as the foreign country when the CVD is used appropriately.

2. THE MODEL AND ANALYSIS

In this simple model, only two countries are involved: the domestic and the foreign country. The domestic country's variables are denoted by the subscript d and the foreign country's variables by the subscript f. The industry analyzed is a homogeneous product Cournot oligopoly with one firm located in each country, and the domestic and the foreign markets are assumed to be segmented. The domestic firm produces xd for domestic consumption at a constant average cost, cd , and a fixed cost, Fd , and the foreign firm produces xf, which is exported to the domestic market, at a constant average cost, cf , and a fixed cost, Ff . Thus, total sales in the domestic market are X = xd + xf . The price, denoted by p, in the domestic market is given by the linear inverse demand function p(X) = a _ b X. To further simplify the analysis, b = 1 is assumed without affecting the robustness of the results obtained.1 1 The results obtained here are also robust when the model is extended to a nonlinear demand or a heterogeneous product case. The proof is available upon request. The foreign export subsidy is per unit, and the corresponding specific CVD is j s where j is the percentage of foreign export subsidy to be countervailed (the countervailing percentage).

In the model, trade policy is modeled as a two-stage game. In Stage 0, the domestic and foreign governments commit to the values of their respective trade policy instruments. Next, Stage 1 involves a Cournot-Nash equilibrium in which the domestic and foreign firms simultaneously and independently choose their respective outputs to maximize profits given the export subsidy and CVD set by the two governments.

The profits of both the domestic and the foreign firm are:

where Di = 0(1) as i = d (f).The first-order conditions for a Cournot-Nash equilibrium are:

Solving for the first-order conditions, and letting l = cd / cf, yields the output of the domestic firm, the exports of the foreign firm, and the market price:2 2 For x i > 0( i = d, f) and l > 0 the following conditions are required: a > c d,c f < a < 2c f and (2c f - a)/ c f < l < (a + c f)/ 2c f.

From these we can derive the equilibrium outputs and the market price as functions of the foreign export subsidy s, the countervailing percentage j and the relative cost-efficiency of the domestic country as compared with the foreign country l.

Domestic welfare is by definition the sum of the consumer's surplus, the profits of the domestic firm, and the CVD revenues:

where CS = u (X) – p (X)X. Totally differentiating Wd with respect to s, using (3)–(5) and letting s = 0 yields:

where jd = (1 – l) cf / (a – cf ). From (7), it is clear that a foreign export subsidy will increase (reduce) the domestic welfare when the countervailing percentage and hence the CVD is high (low) enough. The reason for this is as follows. Foreign export subsidies benefit consumers and harm the domestic firm while countervailing duties benefit the domestic firm and the government and harm consumers. Therefore, when the CVD is high (low) enough, the benefit from a foreign export subsidy will be greater (smaller) than the loss to the domestic country and domestic welfare will increase (decrease).

In particular, in the linear demand case, when the foreign firm is more cost-efficient (i.e.l > 1) than the domestic country so that consumers benefit more, the domestic country will benefit from foreign export subsidies even if no CVD is imposed (i.e.j = 0) . However, when the foreign firm is less cost-efficient, a CVD will be needed if the domestic country is to benefit from the foreign export subsidies.

Foreign welfare is defined as the exporting firm's profits minus the subsidy expenditure:

Totally differentiating Wf with respect to s, using (3) – (5) and letting s = 0 yields:

From (9), it can be seen that, if the countervailing percentage and hence the CVD used is low enough, a foreign export subsidy will increase foreign welfare. This is because the profits of the foreign firm increase by more than the sum of the export subsidy and the decrease in the foreign firms profits resulting from the imposition of the CVD. Therefore, if the CVD is absent, the foreign country will certainly benefit from export subsidization (see Brander and Spencer (1985)). However, if the CVD is sufficiently high, the loss from the export subsidy will dominate the benefit and thus the foreign welfare will be reduced.

The above analysis tells us that, for the domestic and the foreign country to benefit from a foreign export subsidy, the lowest level of CVD at which the domestic country can benefit from a foreign export subsidy must be lower than the highest level of CVD at which a foreign export subsidy can benefit the foreign country. On the contrary, if jd > 1/4 the foreign welfare will be reduced because of its own export subsidy policy.

By combining (7) and (9), we see that when l > 1 , i.e. the cost-efficiency of the foreign country is higher than that of the domestic country, a foreign export subsidy will always benefit the domestic and the foreign country even if the CVD is not used.

3. CONCLUSION

By using a simple model setting, this paper provides an important policy implication for trade disputes involving export subsidies. Generally speaking, imposing a sufficiently high CVD will make the foreign country lose as a result of adopting an export subsidy policy, while a sufficiently low CVD may result in a lower level of welfare for the domestic country due to the export subsidies of the foreign government. Accordingly, to find and adopt an appropriate CVD will be necessary for both the domestic and the foreign country to benefit from a foreign export subsidy. In this paper, the possibility that a foreign export subsidy can benefit the foreign country and the domestic country by appropriately using a CVD is identified.

Submitted: October 2004; accepted: February 2005.

  • BRANDER, J. A.; SPENCER, B. J., 1985. Export subsidies and international market share rivalry. Journal of International Economics 18: 83-100.
  • COLLIE, D. R., 1991. Export subsidies and countervailing tariffs. Journal of International Economics 31: 309-324.
  • __________ . 1994. Strategic trade policy and retaliation. Japan and the World Economy 6: 75-88.
  • DIXIT, A. K., 1988. Anti-dumping and countervailing duties under oligopoly. European Economic Review 32: 55-68.
  • HANSEN, W. L.; PRUSA, T. J., 1997. The economics and politics of trade policy: An empirical analysis of ITC decision making. Review of International Economics 5: 249-272.
  • QIU, L. D., 1995. Why can't countervailing duties deter export subsidization? Journal of International Economics 39: 249-272.
  • WANG, Y. T., 2004. Countervailing duties, foreign export subsidies and import tariffs. Japanese Economic Review 55: 153-171.
  • 1
    The results obtained here are also robust when the model is extended to a nonlinear demand or a heterogeneous product case. The proof is available upon request.
  • 2
    For x
    i > 0(
    i = d, f) and l > 0 the following conditions are required: a > c
    d,c
    f < a
    < 2c
    f and (2c
    f - a)/ c
    f < l < (a + c
    f)/ 2c
    f.
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      21 Mar 2006
    • Date of issue
      Dec 2005

    History

    • Accepted
      Feb 2005
    • Received
      Oct 2004
    Centro de Economia Política Rua Araripina, 106, CEP 05603-030 São Paulo - SP, Tel. (55 11) 3816-6053 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
    E-mail: cecilia.heise@bjpe.org.br