Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Equivalent martingale measures and Lévy processes

Abstracts

In this paper we compute equivalent martingale measures when the asset price returns are modelled by a Lévy process. We follow the approach introduced by Gerber and Shiu (1994).

Lévy Processes; Equivalent Martingale Measures


Neste trabalho calculamos as medidas martingalas equivalentes quando os retornos dos preços dos ativos são modelados por um Processo de Lévy. Seguimos a formulação introduzida por Gerber and Shiu (1994).


Equivalent martingale measures and Lévy processes

José Santiago Fajardo

IBMEC Business School, Av. Rio Branco 108, 9 andar, RJ. - pepe@ibmecrj.br

ABSTRACT

In this paper we compute equivalent martingale measures when the asset price returns are modelled by a Lévy process. We follow the approach introduced by Gerber and Shiu (1994).

Keywords: Lévy Processes; Equivalent Martingale Measures.

JEL Code: G13.

RESUMO

Neste trabalho calculamos as medidas martingalas equivalentes quando os retornos dos preços dos ativos são modelados por um Processo de Lévy. Seguimos a formulação introduzida por Gerber and Shiu (1994).

1. INTRODUCTION

The asset returns behavior has been studied by many authors, and many models have been suggested. Some of them have captured a reasonable part of this behavior, such as fat tails, asymmetry, autocorrelation. For a survey about stylized facts see Rydberg (1997).

The importance of the correct specification of asset returns is very well understood, due to the implications on derivative pricing and Value at Risk calculations. In that sense a class of processes called Lévy processes have shown to be a suitable context for the modelling of these asset returns, since a Lévy process is a simple Markov model with jumps that allow us to capture a huge class of asset returns without the necessity of introducing extreme parameter values. But the most important fact to consider discontinuous processes, as Lévy processes, is the fact that diffusion models cannot consider the discontinuous sudden movements observed on asset prices. For that reason Lévy processes have shown to provide a good fit with real data, as we can see in Carr and Wu (2004) and Eberlein et al. (1998). On the other hand, the mathematical tools behind these processes are very well established and known. Also, it is worth noting that when we adjust Lévy processes with real data we find many difficulties with numerical implementation, see for instance Weron (2001).

After defining the process that better captures the asset return behavior, we can construct the set of equivalent martingale measures (hereafter EMM), under the absence of arbitrage assumption. This set is very important, because knowing this set we know the set of derivative arbitrage free prices. Of course many other applications can be obtained. A good reference for applications of Lévy process in finance is Schoutens (2003).

In this paper we show how to compute EMM when the asset return is modelled by a Lévy process, using the approach introduced by Gerber and Shiu (1994).

The paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we describe the Lévy processes and give some examples. In Section 3, we introduce the stock price model. In Section 4, we discuss the characterization of EMM. In Section 5, we show how to compute an EMM. In Section 6 we compute the EMM in two cases: when we have a diffusion with jumps and when we have a pure jump process. In the last sections we have the conclusions and an appendix.

2. LÉVY PROCESSES

In this section we introduce the Lévy processes. This name is due to the fact that was Paul Lévy, a French mathematician, who studied deeply processes with independent and stationary increments, obtaining the most important results and properties concerning these processes.

Definition 1.We say that {Y(t)}t> 0is a Lévy process if

  • Y has right continuous paths and left limits.

  • Y(0)

    = 0

    , and given 0

    < t

    1

    < t

    2

    < ... < tn, the random variables

Y(t1), Y(t2)-Y(t1),..., Y(tn)-Y(tn-1)

are independent.

  • The distribution of the increment Y(

    t)-Y(

    s)

    is time-homogenous, that is, depends only on t-s.

Observe that the first condition implies that the sample paths can present discontinuities at random times.

A key result in this context is the Lévy-Khintchine formula, that allow us to obtain the characteristic function of any Lévy process {Y(t)}:

jY(t)(z) = E(eizY(t)) = ety(z).

Function y is called characteristic exponent , and is given by:

y(z) = iaz- c2z2+ (eizy - 1 - izy1{|y| < 1})P(dy)

, where a and c > 0 are real constants, and P is a positive measure in I -{0} such that ò(1Ùy2)P(dy) < ¥, that is called Lévy measure and describes the jumps of the process.

An important consequence of this result is that the triplet (a,c,P) completely characterizes the distribution of the Lévy processes {Y(t)}. In other words we must know if the process has tendency (a ¹ 0), diffusion component (c ¹ 0) and jumps (P ¹ 0).

2.1 Examples

Now we present some examples of Lévy processes:

  • Let {

    B(

    t)}

    t> 0 be a Brownian Motion, that is the increments

    B(

    t)-

    B(

    s) are independent and stationary with normal distribution of 0 mean and variance

    t-s. The characteristic function is given by:

jB(t)(z)=,

that is y(z) = - , from here the triplet that characterizes the Lévy process is (0,1,0), that is, we have just a diffusion.

  • Let {

    N(

    t)} be a Poisson process with parameter l. For each

    t > 0 the random variable

    N(

    t) has a Poisson distribution with parameter l

    t, that is:

P(N(t) = n) = e-lt(lt)n/n!, (n = 0,1,...),

from here

The characteristic exponent is given by:

y(z) = lt(ez-1) = (ezy-1)P(dy), where P(dy) = ld1(dy).

From here d1 is the Dirac delta measure, all the mass is concentrated at point 1. Then, the triplet of this process is (0,0,ld1), we have a process with a finite number of jumps in a finite time interval (finite activity).

  • Diffusion with Jumps: Let {

    Xt} be a process defined by:

Xt = at+ cB(t)+Zk, t > 0.

where a and c are constants, {Bt} is a Brownian Motion, {N(t)} is a Poisson process with parameter l, and {Zn} is a sequence of independent and identically distributed random variables, with distribution F(x). Moreover, W,N,Z are mutually independent. Now, we find y:

then y(z) = az+c2+(ezy-1)P(dy), where P(dy) = lF(dy). Our process has the triplet (a,c,lF), that is we have trend, continuous part and a finite number of jumps in a finite time interval.

In these examples it was relatively easy to find the characteristic exponent, due to the simple structure of jumps, that is we consider just finite activity processes, but when we consider infinite activity processes (infinite number of jumps in a finite time interval) the calculation can be hard, due to the fact that we need to make an analytic integration. Fortunately, for the huge class of Lévy processes considered in the literature, the characteristic exponent have been already computed. Now we can use this class of processes to model asset prices.

3. STOCK PRICE MODEL

We consider a risky asset called stock. We denote by S(t) the stock price at each time t Î [0,T], T < ¥. The evolution of this price is modelled by the following equation:

In this model the sources of risk are modelled by a Lévy process Y (t),0 < t < T, and this process is defined on a given complete probability space (W, , P ) . Denote by F = { (t),0 < t < T} the P- augmentation1 1 The augmented filtration F is defined by ( t) = s( Y( t)È ), where = { E Ì W:$ G Î with E Í G, P ( G) = 0} denotes the set of P-null events. of the natural filtration generated by Y:

Y (t) = s(Y (s),0 < s < t), 0 < t < T.

The positiveness of the stock price will be analyzed in the next section. The interest rate {r(t):0 < t < T}, is assumed to be finite, the appreciation rate {r(t),0 < t < T}, and the volatilities {s(t),0 < t < T} are deterministic continuous functions.

4. EQUIVALENT MARTINGALE MEASURES

An EMM is an absolutely continuous probability measure with respect to P that makes the discounted price process a martingale. Under absence of arbitrage the existence of EMM has been extensively studied. The most general result is due to Delbaen and Schachermayer (1994). They studied the implications of absence of arbitrage when the price process is a semimartingale, and Lévy processes are semimartingales. In this paper we will not discuss the existence of EMM, we will suppose that it exists. But, under minor assumptions, it is easy to verify that the set of EMM in not empty. Moreover, since most of the Lévy processes present random jumps there can be more than one EMM.

Assuming that there is no arbitrage we can describe the set of EMM. To do that we use some properties of Lévy processes. From the Lévy-Ito decomposition we know that all Lévy processes must be a linear combination of a standard Brownian Motion ({B(t)}) and a quadratic pure jump process2 2 A process X is said to be a quadratic pure jump process if á N ñ cº 0, where á N ñ c is the continuous part of its quadratic variation á N ñ. Remember that á N ñ is the process such that ( N( t)) 2- á N ñ t is a martingale. {N(t)} which is independent of the Brownian Motion B(t), then

Y(t) = cB(t)+N(t),

Now assume that3 3 E(·) denotes the expectation with respect to P

E[exp(-bY(1))] < ¥, " b Î (-b1,b2)

and

e-bxdP(x) < ¥, "b Î (-b1,b2)

where 0 < b1,b2< ¥. The first assumption states that Y(t) has all moments finite and the second one is technical and will let us separate integrands. With this in mind we can return to the jumps and transform N(t) into:

N(t) = M(t)+at,

where {M(t)} is a discontinuous martingale and a = EN(1). As a consequence the original process can be written as

Now we can use the Generalized Ito's Lemma4 4 See appendix. to obtain the solution to equation (2):

dS(t) = S(t-)[rt dt+stdY(t)] = (ast+rt)S(t-)dt+stS(t-)(cdB(t)+dM(t))

When the coefficients rt and st are deterministic continuous function the solution of this equation is given by the Doléans-Dade exponential5 5 See Jacod and Shiryaev (1987). :

with (3) we obtain:

to ensure that St > 0, a.s. "t Î [0,T], we need that

1+stDM(t) > 0, "t Î [0,T]

If we assume the convention 's > 0', we only need that the jumps of M(t) be bounded from below, i.e. DM(t) > -. It means that we consider only "semi-fat tailed'' distributions as Poisson, Gamma, Hyperbolic and Normal Inverse Gaussian and we eliminate processes with heavy tails. It is worth noting that the stable distributions (without including the Gaussian case) were eliminated when we supposed that Y(t) has all moments finite.

Now we can characterize all the absolutely continuous measures with respect to P, and then we can find necessary and sufficient conditions for these measures to be EMM, see for instance Chan (1999).

Our main concern now is how to compute in a very fast way one of these EMM. In the next section we present one way to do that.

5. GERBER AND SHIU'S APPROACH

In this section we present the approach introduced by Gerber and Shiu (1994). Using a parameter q Î we define a new probability by:

Where f(q) = EeqY(1). When the stock price process has constant coefficients, Gerber and Shiu (1994) prove that for a given constant r it is possible to find a solution q to the following equation:

Then we can verify that the process (t) = e-rtS(t) is a martingale under Pq,i.e. Pq is an EMM. Moreover, the original process is still a Lévy process under this new probability and is called the Esscher transform of the original process. In our model we consider time dependent functions, then we consider the generalized Esscher transform:

we can prove that this new probability is an EMM for some qs. Since we can verify that equation (7) has an unique solution for which f(qs) < ¥ and qsÎ (-b1,b2) "s,

Although, this choose can be arbitrary, we can say that this measure minimizes relative entropy6 6 See Chan (1999). with respect to P, i.e. this EMM is the EMM closest to P in terms of its information contents, since P contains information about the behavior of the market, but of course another criterion to choose EMM can be used.

6. EXAMPLES

In this section we compute the EMM for two cases. A diffusion with jumps and a pure jump process. We make this choice because the pure diffusion case is very well understood. Remember that Black and Scholes used the following EMM for the geometric Brownian motion case:

The presence of jumps in the stock price model will affect the density of the EMM as we will see in the examples below.

6.1 Brownian Motion and Two Jumps Process

We consider the following parameter s = 36% and r = 0 in (2), and r = 16%. Now assume that N(t) = , where Ni is a Poisson process with rate 1. So:

  • P =

  • a = EN(t) = 0

Finally take c = 1. Then the triplet of this process is (0,1,P). Now we apply the approach presented in the last section to find an EMM. We obtain the parameter q that satisfies equation (7):

This expression can be simplified to:

the solution to this equation is q*» -0.2959. In equation ( 5):

we also have Y(t) = B(t)+N(t) and

where the first equality is due to the independence of B(t) and N(t) and the second one is due to the fact that N1(t) and N2(t) are independent. Now we use the expected value of a log-normal random variable and equation (1) with l = 1 and t = 1, to obtain:

then log(f(q*)) = 0.0657. From here we have

This is the density of the EMM.

6.2 Normal Inverse Gaussian Process

We consider the parameters s = 1 and r = 0 in (2) and a Normal Inverse Gaussian distribution for the jump component7 7 We make this choice, once Eberlein et al. (1998) and Barndorff-Nielsen (1998), showed that this process has a good fit with real data. 8 For more details see Shiryaev (1999, Ch. III, 5C). . That is N(1) has a NIG(a,b,m,d) distribution, which has the following density:

where K1 is the modified Bessel function of the third kind. The Lévy measure is given by:

and we consider a Lévy process with the following triplet (0,0,P). That is Y(t) = N(t), and this type of process is called a pure jump process. From here we have

Then, in equation (6) we have

To obtain parameter q, we use the parameters obtained by Fajardo and Farias (2004) for Brazilian Bovespa index . The parameters are,

(a,b,m,d) = (31.9096,-0.0035,0.0233,0.0012)

Assuming r = 13%, the solution to equation (10) is q*» 80.65 . Replacing these values in equation (9), we obtain:

Now in (5), we have the density of the EMM:

(t) = e{80.65 Y(t)-324.27t}.

From the fact that NIG distributions are closed under convolutions, we have Y(t) ~ nig(a,b,tµ,td) and from the fact that under the change of measure () the process N is still a Lévy process and N(1) still has a NIG distribution, with the same a, d and µ, but b* = b+q*. That is the new density is nig(31.91,80.65,0.0233,0.0012). We use the convolution property to obtain the distribution of Y(T). Then it has a density nig(31.9096,80.65,0.0233T,0.0012T). From here, depending on the maturity T, we can compute expectations under the EMM in order to obtain derivative prices.

In comparison with the EMM obtained in the Black and Scholes (BS) model we can see that jumps are also present in the density of the EMM. In the case of the pure jump process we have just jumps in the density. The presence of jumps is very important since it provides a better adjustment with real data and when we price derivatives, as European call, we can find a significant difference with the price obtained using the EMM of the BS. As was pointed out by Fajardo and Farias (2004). They used Generalized Hyperbolic distributions to study Brazilian data. Here the presence of jumps is more important since emerging markets are affected by many shocks that produce such a diversity of jumps. For a discussion about which type of jumps can be observed in asset returns see Aït-Sahalia (2004) and Huang and Wu (2004).

As observed there can be many EMM, the complete abstract characterization can be found in Chan (1999). Then you can obtain a spread for derivative prices. Depending in how complex be the structure of jumps describing the underlying asset that spread can be very high.

7. CONCLUSIONS

In this paper we have used a Lévy process to model asset price returns, which allow us to capture more stylized facts from real data. It is worth noting that there are many difficulties with the numerical implementation. Then, we have shown how to compute EMM using the approach introduced by Gerber and Shiu (1994). We compute the EMM in two cases. Of course many other examples can be done.

Interesting processes not considered in this paper are processes with dependent increments and non-time-homogenous processes, as the time-changed Lévy process. With these processes we can model the autocorrelation observed in the square and absolute returns of the stocks and consider more flexible structures for implied volatilities on option prices, facts that cannot be modelled with Lévy processes.

Bibliography

Aït-Sahalia, Y. (2004). Disentangling diffusion from jumps. Journal of Financial Economics, 74:487-528.

Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E. (1998). Processes of normal inverse gaussian type. Finance and Stochastics, 2:41-68.

Carr, P. & Wu, L. (2004). Time-changed Lévy processes and option pricing. Journal of Financial Economics, 71:113-141.

Chan, T. (1999). Pricing contingent claims on stocks driven by Lévy processes. Annals of Applied Probability, 9(2):504-528.

Delbaen, F. & Schachermayer, W. (1994). A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing. Mathematische Annalen, 300:463-520.

Eberlein, E. & Keller, U. (1995). Hyperbolic distributions in finance. Bernoulli, 1:281-299.

Eberlein, E., Keller, U., & Prause, K. (1998). New insights into smiles, mispricing and value at risk: The hyperbolic model. Journal of Business, 71:371-405.

Fajardo, J. & Farias, A. (2004). Generalized hyperbolic distributions and brazilian data. Brazilian Review of Econometrics, 24(2):249-271.

Gerber, H. & Shiu, E. (1994). Option pricing by esscher transform. Transactions of the Society of Actuaries, 46:99-191.

Huang, J. & Wu, L. (2004). Specification analysis of option pricing models based on time-changed lévy processes. Journal of Finance, LIX(3):1405-1440.

Jacod, J. & Shiryaev, A. N. (1987). Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes. Springer-Verlag, New York.

Rydberg, T. (1997). Why financial data are interesting to statisticians. Technical Report 5, Centre for Analytical Finance, Aarhus University.

Sato, K.-I. (1999). Lévy processes and infinitely divisible distributions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Schoutens, W. (2003). Lévy Processes in Finance: Pricing Financial Derivatives. John Wiley and Sons.

Shiryaev, A. N. (1999). Essential of Stochastic Finance: Facts, Models and Theory. World Scientific Pub. Co.

Weron, R. (2001). Lévy-stable distributions revisited: Tail index does not exclude the Lévy-stable regime. International Journal of Modern Physics, C12:209-223.

For any measurable function f(t,x) we have

and for any C2 function f, we have the Generalized Itô's formula for cadlag semimartingales X1,...,Xn:

where fi = , fij = and [Xi,Xj]c is the continuous part of the mutual variation

  • Aït-Sahalia, Y. (2004). Disentangling diffusion from jumps. Journal of Financial Economics, 74:487-528.
  • Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E. (1998). Processes of normal inverse gaussian type. Finance and Stochastics, 2:41-68.
  • Carr, P. & Wu, L. (2004). Time-changed Lévy processes and option pricing. Journal of Financial Economics, 71:113-141.
  • Chan, T. (1999). Pricing contingent claims on stocks driven by Lévy processes. Annals of Applied Probability, 9(2):504-528.
  • Delbaen, F. & Schachermayer, W. (1994). A general version of the fundamental theorem of asset pricing. Mathematische Annalen, 300:463-520.
  • Eberlein, E. & Keller, U. (1995). Hyperbolic distributions in finance. Bernoulli, 1:281-299.
  • Eberlein, E., Keller, U., & Prause, K. (1998). New insights into smiles, mispricing and value at risk: The hyperbolic model. Journal of Business, 71:371-405.
  • Fajardo, J. & Farias, A. (2004). Generalized hyperbolic distributions and brazilian data. Brazilian Review of Econometrics, 24(2):249-271.
  • Gerber, H. & Shiu, E. (1994). Option pricing by esscher transform. Transactions of the Society of Actuaries, 46:99-191.
  • Huang, J. & Wu, L. (2004). Specification analysis of option pricing models based on time-changed lévy processes. Journal of Finance, LIX(3):1405-1440.
  • Jacod, J. & Shiryaev, A. N. (1987). Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes Springer-Verlag, New York.
  • Rydberg, T. (1997). Why financial data are interesting to statisticians. Technical Report 5, Centre for Analytical Finance, Aarhus University.
  • Sato, K.-I. (1999). Lévy processes and infinitely divisible distributions Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
  • Schoutens, W. (2003). Lévy Processes in Finance: Pricing Financial Derivatives John Wiley and Sons.
  • Shiryaev, A. N. (1999). Essential of Stochastic Finance: Facts, Models and Theory World Scientific Pub. Co.
  • Weron, R. (2001). Lévy-stable distributions revisited: Tail index does not exclude the Lévy-stable regime. International Journal of Modern Physics, C12:209-223.

appendix

  • 1
    The augmented filtration
    F is defined by
    (
    t) = s(
    Y(
    t
    ), where
    = {
    E Ì W:$
    G Î
    with
    E
    Í
    G,
    P (
    G) = 0} denotes the set of
    P-null events.
  • 2
    A process
    X is said to be a quadratic pure jump process if á
    N ñ
    cº 0, where á
    N ñ
    c is the continuous part of its quadratic variation á
    N ñ. Remember that á
    N ñ is the process such that (
    N(
    t))
    2- á
    N ñ
    t is a martingale.
  • 3
    E(·) denotes the expectation with respect to
    P
  • 4
    See
    appendixappendix.
  • 5
    See Jacod and Shiryaev (1987).
  • 6
    See Chan (1999).
  • 7
    We make this choice, once Eberlein et al. (1998) and Barndorff-Nielsen (1998), showed that this process has a good fit with real data.
    88 of Xi and Xj For more details see Shiryaev (1999, Ch. III, 5C).
  • 8
    of
    Xi and
    Xj
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      05 Apr 2007
    • Date of issue
      Dec 2006
    Fundação Getúlio Vargas Praia de Botafogo, 190 11º andar, 22253-900 Rio de Janeiro RJ Brazil, Tel.: +55 21 3799-5831 , Fax: +55 21 2553-8821 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
    E-mail: rbe@fgv.br