Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

An application of the spatial equilibrium model to soybean production in tocantins and neighboring states in Brazil

Abstracts

In the production chain of soybeans in Brazil a sizable part of the corresponding cost structure is the result of logistics costs. Given the location of its production sites, distant from the ocean, the optimization of the transportation costs is essential for preserving competitiveness. Using nonlinear programming, this study proposes a spatial multimodal and temporal equilibrium model. The applicability of the model is tested with a case study regarding the exports of the soybeans produced in three states in the northern part of the Brazilian cerrado region. In the state of Tocantins, the effects of infrastructure investments in the competitiveness of the production are described through four proposed scenarios, while the basic scenario compares the three states. The data are treated using the GAMS/MINOS program. The study asserts that soybean production will be more competitive if warehousing facilities are used extensively and when the project hydroway becomes operational.

logistics; soybeans; warehousing; nonlinear programming


Na cadeia de produção da soja no Brasil, parte substancial da estrutura correspondente dos custos é resultado dos custos logísticos. Dada a localização das áreas produtivas, distante do oceano, a otimização dos custos de transporte é essencial para garantir a competitividade. Usando programação não-linear, este estudo propõe um modelo de equilíbrio espacial temporal e multimodal. A aplicabilidade do modelo proposto é testada com um estudo de caso referente às exportações de soja produzida em três estados na parte norte do cerrado brasileiro. No estado de Tocantins, o efeito na competitividade de investimentos na infraestrutura de transporte estão descritos por meio de quatro cenários, enquanto que os três estados são comparados pelo cenário básico. Os dados são tratados usando o programa GAMS/MINOS. O estudo assegura que a produção de soja nesses estados será mais competitiva se armazéns forem usados mais extensamente e quando o projeto hidroviário tornar-se operacional.

logística; soja; armazenamento; programação não-linear


ARTIGOS REGULARES

An application of the spatial equilibrium model to soybean production in tocantins and neighboring states in Brazil

Betty Clara Barraza De La CruzI; Nelio D. PizzolatoII, * * Corresponding author / autor para quem as correspondências devem ser encaminhadas ; Andrés Barraza De La CruzIII

IUniversidade Federal do Tocantins (UFT). Palmas - TO, Brasil. bettyvan2001@yahoo.com.br IIPontifícia Univ. Católica do Rio de Janeiro (PUC-Rio). Rio de Janeiro - RJ, Brasil. ndp@puc-rio.br IIIUniversidade Federal do Tocantins (UFT). Palmas - TO, Brasil. lacruz@uft.edu.br

ABSTRACT

In the production chain of soybeans in Brazil a sizable part of the corresponding cost structure is the result of logistics costs. Given the location of its production sites, distant from the ocean, the optimization of the transportation costs is essential for preserving competitiveness. Using nonlinear programming, this study proposes a spatial multimodal and temporal equilibrium model. The applicability of the model is tested with a case study regarding the exports of the soybeans produced in three states in the northern part of the Brazilian cerrado region. In the state of Tocantins, the effects of infrastructure investments in the competitiveness of the production are described through four proposed scenarios, while the basic scenario compares the three states. The data are treated using the GAMS/MINOS program. The study asserts that soybean production will be more competitive if warehousing facilities are used extensively and when the project hydroway becomes operational.

Keywords: logistics; soybeans; warehousing; nonlinear programming.

RESUMO

Na cadeia de produção da soja no Brasil, parte substancial da estrutura correspondente dos custos é resultado dos custos logísticos. Dada a localização das áreas produtivas, distante do oceano, a otimização dos custos de transporte é essencial para garantir a competitividade. Usando programação não-linear, este estudo propõe um modelo de equilíbrio espacial temporal e multimodal. A aplicabilidade do modelo proposto é testada com um estudo de caso referente às exportações de soja produzida em três estados na parte norte do cerrado brasileiro. No estado de Tocantins, o efeito na competitividade de investimentos na infraestrutura de transporte estão descritos por meio de quatro cenários, enquanto que os três estados são comparados pelo cenário básico. Os dados são tratados usando o programa GAMS/MINOS. O estudo assegura que a produção de soja nesses estados será mais competitiva se armazéns forem usados mais extensamente e quando o projeto hidroviário tornar-se operacional.

Palavras-chave: logística; soja; armazenamento; programação não-linear.

1. Introduction

Along its history, Brazil has experienced several economic cycles which, except for gold mining around the 18th century, were all related to agricultural products. The country's own name is due to a type of wood exported in the early days of discovery and colonial occupation. Soon afterwards came the sugar-cane cycle, which introduced slavery in a large scale and left enduring traces in its racial and cultural formation. Rubber extraction in the Amazon forest and coffee cultivation in the south are other important cycles, the latter being responsible for attracting millions of European immigrants and molding the region's present multiracial composition. Presently, the country is at the brink of another cycle, related to ethanol and grain production, especially soybean. The importance of the soybean cycle will be discussed briefly but some of its main effects cannot be ignored, namely: the effective occupation of the country's inland, the halt or even inversion of the urbanization process toward the main capitals, and the advance of a less uneven income distribution in favor of rural areas.

The agribusiness is the most relevant sector of the Brazilian economy, corresponding to approximately 27% of the national GNP and 36.7% of the country's total export earnings. In face of the present worldwide food, energy, and environment crisis two primary products are leading this new economic cycle: sugar cane for producing ethanol and soybeans for producing food. The former has recently emerged but is showing an extraordinary expansion while the production of the latter % the one focused in this research % has forty years of continuous development. Therefore, soybeans are effectively the most significant product of the Brazilian agricultural sector, not only because of the technological and financial resources demanded but also due to the managerial skills required from all players involved in the corresponding production chain.

Soybeans were first introduced in the south of the country where the climate is more akin to those regions around the world where these beans are traditionally cultivated. However, production soon moved northward and found ideal conditions in the cerrado area, a Brazilian type of savannah, in the country's inland. It is important to stress the role played by EMBRAPA, a state company dedicated to agricultural research. This company has developed technical procedures to turn the area, traditionally considered inappropriate for agricultural production, into a highly productive one.

Despite the fact that technical expertise has lead to surprising advances, basic logistics elements still play a predominant role as deterrent to competitiveness. Poor infrastructure and a distance of nearly three thousand kilometers to the maritime ports in the east coast add costs, increase physical losses, and reduce the overall quality of the product. In fact, most of the grain journeys in old trucks, using poorly paved or unpaved roads. To make matters worse for the producers, the short supply of adequate warehouses forces them to transport the grains immediately after harvesting, when prices are lower, transportation tariffs much higher, and terminals unable to handle excessive volumes.

The basis for the study has been the spatial equilibrium model, fundamentally based on a proposal made in the early fifties by the economist Paul Samuelson, a Nobel Prize winner. This model will be briefly reviewed in the present paper, but in short it is basically a transportation model where supply and demand vary according to market prices, which in turn depend on specific elasticities for both supply and demand markets, with allowances for the freight costs involved. In order to reinforce the approach the following advantages are enumerated:

i) it is a generalization of the transportation model whose solution the spatial equilibrium model might also reproduce;

ii) it allows the inclusion of supply and demand elasticity prices;

iii) it might be extended to allow the inclusion of general distribution cost functions; and

iv) it allows the consideration of imperfect and noncompetitive markets.

Given these remarks, this study considers the volumes produced by the state of Tocantins, and two of its neighbors, which are certainly driven by supply and demand functions. In addition, the study considers two main elements of the logistics system: warehousing and transportation infrastructure. The importance of the former was already outlined and refers to the effect of leveling the flow of grains throughout the year to avoid congestion and higher costs; the latter considers the best choice of transportation modes. As a result, a nonlinear spatial temporal multimodal transshipment equilibrium model including supply and demand functions is proposed. To solve the model the modeling language GAMS/MINOS was employed using parameters available or estimated for the year 2005. In order to select the best investment strategy for the state of Tocantins, four scenarios have been considered: the first is the prevailing one, which relies on roads and trucks; the second and third are based on making the Tocantins Hydroway - a main tributary of the Amazon river - operational, but these scenarios differ on the international transshipment port of destination; and the fourth scenario considers the use of an extended railway. It is important to note that both the hydroway and the railway are presently under construction, but the hydroway in particular faces several adverse environmental controversies.

Therefore, the objective of this paper is to propose a spatial multimodal and temporal equilibrium model expressed by a nonlinear programming model to evaluate the soybean production and its subsequent routes for exports. The study is applied to data relevant to three states in the northern region of Brazil - Tocantins, Maranhão, and Piauí - with more emphasis on the State of Tocantins. In these three states, production started recently and today accounts for about 6% of the total country's production, but it shall increase vigorously in the near future. The objective function of the proposed model relies on supply and demand functions, while the restrictions take into consideration the presently neglected warehousing as well as the alternative modes of reaching the maritime ports in the northern region of Brazil. In order to account for the latter, the proposed model considers two periods along the year: the harvesting season which takes three to four months and the rest of the year, called out-of-season or pre-harvest period. Certainly, the amounts exported in the out-of-season period match the volumes warehoused after harvest.

This paper is so organized: Section 2 presents the state of Tocantins and its two neighbor states and shortly reviews the history of soybean expansion in Brazil. Section 3 presents the spatial equilibrium model along with a brief literature review of this theory and some of its well-known applications. Section 4 describes the proposed model. Section 5 evaluates and discusses the main findings for each of the four scenarios relevant to the state of Tocantins. Section 6 makes a brief evaluation of the relative competitiveness of the three states based on the existing transportation structure, and Section 7 draws some conclusions.

2. Soybean production and the state of Tocantins

According to the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA, 2007), four countries account for 90% of the world's soybean production: the United States: 39%; Brazil: 25%; Argentina: 19%, and China: 7%. Regarding consumption, the United States, China, the European Union, Japan, and Mexico account for 77% of the world's consumption. In contrast with the United States and Argentina, which turn most of their soybeans into oil and soymeal, the Brazilian production is predominantly exported as raw grains.

Most of the state of Tocantins is covered by the cerrado biome, in which early and primitive cattle raising activities predominate, while the northern part of the state borders the Amazon forest, which is assumed to be preserved. In recent years this state has been converted into productive agricultural areas, and modern soybean production is expanding at a rapid pace. Presently, using old trucks and poorly paved roads, the agricultural production of the state is transported nearly 400 km to the north where it reaches the railway that connects the mineral area of Carajás to the port of Itaqui. Once on the railway, the grain is conveyed to the referred port from where it is shipped to Europe and Asia. Two new prospective routes are being developed and will be available in the near future. One is the southward railway extension. This construction is under way and the long-term plan is to extend the railway to the center of the country and from there further south, as indicated by its name: South-North Railway. The other connection would use the Tocantins river, whose hydroway is also under construction. Employing barges the grain would reach the Amazon River where it is able to reach either Itaqui or Vila do Conde, both international ports. This hydroway, however, is facing two types of environmental restrictions. First, despite its water volume a canal is required to overcome some rapids that exist in the area; second, the river crosses an indian reserve whose population is questioning the effects of the required explosions on fishing and the environment in general.

The state of Tocantins is portrayed in Figure 1 together with its two neighbors and all other states of the country. Its total area is 27,842,000 hectares, and potentially it could be a large producer of soybeans. About 50% of the territory is considered appropriate for agriculture, but in 2006 only 2.3% of the area was cultivated. Human occupation of the state is a relatively recent phenomenon and agriculture has become attractive to producers from other parts of the country for at least three reasons:

• Favorable edaphic and climate factors such as leveled topography, regular rains, many large rivers, high temperatures, and thick soil depth. With the adoption of modern technologies, such factors can provide a substantial productivity increase in yet unexplored areas.

• Relative economic advantage. Producers from the south have turned to these lands because of their low prices, having in mind not only production earnings but also large future capital gains resulting from real estate investment.

• Large potential profits derived from economies of scale in the operation. Thank to the low cost of land, either for buying or renting, the size of the cultivated area for a given capital investment can be much larger.


3. Brief history of spatial equilibrium models

The origin of the spatial equilibrium model can be traced back to the classical work by Cournot in 1898 who, according to Samuelson (1952), established that, considering two spatially separated markets and their transportation costs, the competitive prices are determined by the intersection of demand and supply curves, and equilibrium prices are influenced among other factors by the transportation costs.

Samuelson was the first to state that spatial equilibrium between different markets might be solved by mathematical programming, and formulated the problem as the maximization of the area under all excess demand curves, plus the area of all excess supply curves, minus the total transportation costs. Later, his work was extended by Takayama & Judge (1964) who used quadratic programming, and linear supply and demand functions. In several regions, their algorithm is being extensively used to find spatial equilibrium conditions and to determine the commercial exchange of goods between interrelated regions. Recently, given the advance in computer capacities and new computing strategies, the size of the models has been amplified (Takayama, 1995).

Caixeta-Filho & Macaulay (1989) investigated the wheat production in Australia under the spatial equilibrium model. In particular, the authors examined the effect of eliminating the existing transport barriers among states, showing that supply and demand elasticities would simplify political measures and policies, which incorporate market imperfections, such as non-elastic supply and demand functions.

Among many other contributions, Nagurney (1993) stated several properties of the economic functions involved; Waquil (1996) examined agricultural exchanges within Mercosur, the South American Common Market; Kawaguchi et al. (1997) studied the commerce of milk in Japan; Crammer et al. (1993) investigated the world rice market; Fuller et al. (2003) evaluated the liberalization of the rice trade between Mexico and the US; Garcia (2000) considered the maize market in Mexico; Dennis (1999) evaluated the steam coal transportation in the US; Chen et al. (2002) also studied the rice trade among countries; Yan et al. (2002) made extensions to Cournot theories; Gabriel et al. (2001) suggested extensions to large problems related to the natural gas system in the US.

According to Samuelson (1952), the market equilibrium might be obtained by maximizing the Net Social Payoff Function (NSP) which is given by adding the consumer's and the producer's surplus, or EC and EP. In the following expressions, Pd(q) and Ps(q) represent the demand and the supply function, respectively. The expression poqo, the product of the equilibrium price and quantity, is, in the first case, the amount paid by consumers and, in the second case, the amount received by producers. These functions are given by:

The sum results in the expression ET, where ET = EC + EP:

The spatial equilibrium model assumes that production and consumption in two different areas connected by a transportation network satisfy the following equilibrium conditions:

- the demand price is equal to the supply price plus the transportation cost, if commercialization between this pair of markets exists; and

- the demand price is lower than the supply price plus the transportation cost, if no commercialization exists between these markets.

Nonlinear supply and demand functions

Suppose that s and d identify soybean production and consumption, respectively, in each area s = 1,2...S and d = 1,2...D. Assume that supply and demand functions follow the expressions below, where the exponents a and b are nonnegative rational numbers. These parameters a and b vary according to the production area s and the demanding area d respectively.

Xst and Pst are the quantity supplied and the price in region s in period t. The usual assumption is that the intercept of the supply curve ¸st might be higher, equal or lower than zero and the slope of the supply curve γst is higher than zero.

Demand function

Ydt and Pdt are the quantity demanded and the price to the consumer in region d in period t. Again, the usual assumption is that the intercept of the demand curve αdt is higher than zero and the slope of the demand curve βdt is lower than zero.

Assuming that γst>0 and β<0, expressions (3.1) and (3.2) may be represented as follows:

Where: νst {>, =, <}0, ηst >0 , λdt > 0 and ωdt < 0.

The supply function Pst is differentiable, non-negative, and non-decreasing, while the quantities produced are equal or larger than zero. The demand function Pdt is positive, differentiable, and non-increasing in the interval in which the demanded quantities are non-negative.

From this point, Samuelson (1952), working with linear supply and demand functions, has shown that market equilibrium is obtained by maximizing the NSP (Net Social Payoff) function, given by the consumer surplus, plus the producer surplus, less the transportation cost between both regions.

Slope and intercept of nonlinear functions

According to Alston et al. (1995) and Kawaguchi et al. (1997), apud Garcia (1999), the supply and demand functions are obtained based on the supply price elasticity, demand price elasticity, price to the producer, price to the consumer, amount produced and quantity consumed in a given period of time. The slope and the intercept of the supply and the demand functions are obtained in the following way:

In the case of the demand function:

The slope βdt is equal to:

Where βdt is the slope of the demand function in region d in period t, εdt is the demand elasticity of the sales price, Ydt and are respectively the consumer and the producer price of soybeans in region d in period t. Since the elasticities are known in the literature, the previous expression allows determining the slope βdt. The intercept of the demand function in region d in period t is given by (3.5) using the slope calculated in (3.6).

In an analogous way, in the case of the supply function we have:

The slope γst is given by:

Where γst is the slope of the supply function in region s in period t, µst is the soybean price elasticity, Xst and Pst are respectively the supply and the price of soybeans in region s in period t. The intercept of the supply function in region s in period t is given by (3.8) using the values of the slope, the supplied amount, and the price paid to the producer calculated in (3.9) according to the expression:

Where εst is the price elasticity of the excess supply and εdt is the price elasticity of the excess demand. The functions determined by them are called supply excess function and excess demand function, respectively.

Spatial and temporal multimodal model flowchart

The objective of the spatial equilibrium model is to maximize the NSP function, thus maximizing the areas below the demand curves, plus the areas above the supply curves, minus the transportation and warehousing costs. The model uses the basic structure proposed by Takayama & Judge (1971), and Bivings (1997), whose origin lays in the pioneering work by Samuelson (1952). The main differences between the models discussed in the literature and the one proposed in this work are:

(a) The supply and demand functions are nonlinear;

(b) Intermodal transportation;

(c) The transshipment points;

(d) The consideration of the temporal analysis as a proxy for warehousing; and

(e) Warehousing costs.

The flowchart in Figure 2 illustrates the proposed transportation model.


The supply and demand functions

As a consequence, considering the small production of the State of Tocantins - as will be examined later in the case study - some simplifications ought to be introduced in the supply and demand functions. Firstly, the state's production is unable to have any measurable influence in international prices; therefore, the excess demand function might be seen as constant. Secondly, using eight years of available data, a simplified linear and nonlinear supply function of the following form was tested:

where

Hectt = area in hectares planted in a given period t;

Pricet-1= price of soybeans in period t-1;

Year = variable of tendency or time expressed in years;

Dummy = auxiliary variable.

Certainly, for a better adjustment the nonlinear equation would be recommended:

The exponents f1, f2, f3 and f4 are assumed to be rational numbers and the function takes the following form:

, which corresponds to (3.8)

4. The proposed model formulation

The indexes of the model are:

t: periods, (t = 1,2,...T);

d: consumer regions, (d = 1, 2,...D);

s: producer regions, (s = 1, 2,...S);

u: transshipment points, (u = 1,2,...U);

w: ports, (w = 1,2,...,W);

k: transportation mode (k = c, f, h), where c = trucks, f = railway, and h = hydroway.

The variables involved are represented as:

NSP = Net Social Payoff Function;

λdt = Cost-coefficient intercept of the demand equation d in period t;

ωdt = Cost-coefficient slope of the demand equation d in period t;

vst = Cost-coefficient intercept of the supply equation s in period t;

ηst = Cost-coefficient slope of the supply equation s in period t;

Ydt = Amount of soybeans consumed in region d in period t;

Xst = Amount of soybeans supplied by region s in period t;

= Unit transportation cost from region s to point u by trucks in period t;

= Unit transportation cost from point u to port w using mode k in period t;

= Unit transportation shipment from port w to overseas consumer d in period t;

= Amount shipped from port w to overseas consumer d in period t;

= Amount sent from region s to point u by trucks in period t;

= Amount sent from producer region s through point u to port w in period t using mode k;

= Amount shipped overseas from points s, u and w to consumer d in period t;

= Unit soybean warehousing cost in the producer region s in period t;

= Amount of soybeans warehoused in region s in period t;

= Transshipment cost at point u in period t;

= Transshipment cost at port w in period t;

CAPst,t|1 = Warehousing capacity at the end of period t.

The model includes the objective function (4.1), Max NSP, subjected to restrictions (4.2) through (4.7). All expressions are explained and justified further below.

subject to:

The objective function, Max NSP, is to be understood as the excess demand, plus the excess supply, minus the costs of transportation, warehousing, and transshipment. The explanation is separated by parts:

This first set of expressions is given by the integral of the demand function given in (3.4) from zero up to Ydt , the amount demanded in region d in period t at price Pdt. In fact:

Analogously, the integration of the supply function given in (3.3) from zero to Xst results in:

The proposed model assumes that vst>0.

The transportation costs consider the four modes, and the total transportation costs from the producing regions to the transshipment points plus the transshipment costs are given by:

The total transportation costs from the transshipment points to the ports are given by the expression:

The transportation costs from ports w to consumers d are given by:

The warehousing costs are given by the expression:

Restrictions (4.2) through (4.7) have the following interpretations:

(4.2) This restriction states that in each period the amount consumed in each region is smaller or equal to the amounts transported to the same region;

(4.3) This restriction states that in every period t for every producing region s production plus the amount warehoused from period t-1 to t shall be larger or equal to the amount transported by trucks from this region to all transshipment points u in period t plus the stocks from t to t+1;

(4.4) Restrictions on the total quantities dispatched to all ports w, from each transshipment point u in each period t by all transport modes, which shall be smaller or equal to the quantities received at this transshipment point u by trucks from the given region s in the same period d;

(4.5) This restriction from ports to consumers states that for every port the volume sent to all consumers shall be smaller or equal to the amounts received from all producing regions for each period t;

(4.6) Warehousing capacity restriction for every producing region;

(4.7) Non-negativity restrictions.

No capacity restriction was assigned to the transportation modes. Although capacities could be easily introduced in the model, the overlook of capacities seems realistic since the availability of trucks is elastic; the North-South Railway is projected to carry 15 million tons per year, a figure that largely surpasses the present production, and the hydroway designed capacity of two million tons per year is much larger than the present production or the one devised for the near future.

5. Results and discussion

In this section the results of the model are discussed and evaluated. Models that represent the real world may be quite useful if a careful validation of their effectiveness is previously done. The state of Tocantins is the object of a case study for which detailed data for the year 2005 has been collected including warehousing, spatial and temporal cost data. The results are then compared with the existing and projected infrastructure.

It is important to recall that the application was simplified to T = 2, which includes two yearly periods of unequal duration. One is the in-season that lasts three to four months, in which the harvest takes place. During this period, all tactical decisions such as selling, immediate exports, and warehousing have to be made. The second period is the rest of the year, or the out-of-season period, in which decisions are made regarding exports of the warehoused soybean.

The nonlinear spatial equilibrium model was applied for each one of the four devised scenarios, in order to find for each period: the exports, the best warehousing strategy, and the alternative routes by which the products may flow. Next, for each scenario, the results are summarized and the corresponding interpretations are assessed.

GAMS, General Algebraic Modeling System, was designed to solve linear, nonlinear, and integer programming models. Data are supplied either as text files, data sets or spread sheets and the models might be simply written. The results can be visualized and exported to text editors or spread sheets. The model developed for the case study was executed in a personal computer with 800 MHz Pentium III processor, 256 Mb RAM and Windows XP 2002 operational system. Execution time of the MINOS optimizer was around 0.031 seconds.

Scenario 1:

Scenario 1 corresponds to the present structure in which the soybeans are transported by trucks 385 km northwards until they reach the transshipment point in the Carajás Railway at the railway station of Estreito. The application of the model under these conditions results in the proposed solution portrayed in Figure 4. From the production point, the railway carries the product along 731 km until the port of Itaqui, 6,795 km away from Europe and 20,242 km from China.


Production in the state is presently projected to be 603,994 tons, 14,030 tons higher than the production in 2005, of which 59,844 tons are exported during the harvest season and 544,150 tons remain warehoused for exports along the rest of the year. The total logistics cost per ton is US$ 40.10, while the Net Social Payoff objective function reaches US$ 230,475,400.

Scenario 2:

Scenario 2 corresponds to the proposed structure in which the Tocantins Hydroway is made operational. The application of the model under these conditions results in the solution portrayed in Figure 5. Accordingly, the soybeans make a short 20 km travel by trucks to reach the barges in the river, from where they journey 1,322 km to the port of Vila do Conde, 7,038 km away from Europe and 19,618 km from China.


Production in the state would be projected to be 611,795 tons, 21,831 tons higher than the production in 2005, of which 67,645 tons would be exported during the in-season period and 544,150 tons would remain warehoused to be exported along the year, in the out-of-season period. Exports directed to China correspond to 89.4% while 10.6% goes to the European Union. The total logistics cost per ton is US$ 29.60, while the Net Social Payoff objective function would reach US$ 236,857,900.

Scenario 3:

Scenario 3 corresponds to the proposed structure in which the soybeans are conveyed 20 km by trucks to the transshipment point at the Tocantins Hydroway, from where they travel 370 km northward to the railway station of Estreito. The application of the model under these conditions results in the proposed solution depicted in Figure 6. The railway carries the product along 731 km to the port of Itaqui, 6,795 km away from Europe and 20,242 km from China.


Production in the state is projected to be 605,156 tons, 15,192 tons higher than the production in 2005, of which 61,006 tons are exported during the harvest season and 544,150 tons remain warehoused for exports along the year, in the out-of-season period. Exports directed to China correspond to 90.3% while 9.76% goes to the European Union. The total logistics cost per ton is US$ 38.50, while the net Net Social Payoff objective function reaches US$ 233,442,700.

Scenario 4:

Scenario 4 corresponds to the extension of the North-South Railway to the center of the state of Tocantins. The application of the model under these conditions results in the solution represented in Figure 7. Accordingly, the soybeans are transported 50 km by trucks to reach the transshipment point at the railway station of Guaraí, from where they journey 1,026 km up to the port of Itaqui and then to the European Union or China. The proposal is to export 60,598 tons during the in-season period and to warehouse 544,150 tons for exports in the out-of-season period. The total logistics cost per ton is US$ 39.06, while the Net Social Payoff objective function reaches US$ 233,103,900.


Production in the state is projected to be 604,748 tons, 14,784 tons higher than the production in 2005, of which 60,598 tons are exported during the in-season period and 544,150 tons remain warehoused for exports in the out-of-season period. The total logistics cost per ton would be US$ 39.06, while the Net Social Payoff objective function would reach US$ 233,103,900.

6. The states of Maranhão and Piauí

Maranhão and Piauí are two neighboring states of Tocantins, as shown in Figure 1. Regarding their cultural background, historical development, and edaphic and climate factors these three states share many points in common. One is the presence of the cerrado biome in the southern part of Maranhão and Piauí, which drives the agricultural production towards similar products. Another common point is the early colonization based on an extensive cattle raising economy in which the herds used to move continuously in search of grass and the humans would follow them, eventually establishing small settlements in favorable areas. In contrast with most of the other states of the country, the geometrical form of the state of Piauí, being wide in the south and with a short ocean front, is often viewed as a confirmation of such occupation theory.

The advent of large scale soybean production had an effect similar to the one previously discussed of motivating local farmers and also attracting others from all over the country to buy inexpensive land and to convert uneconomical cattle raising into highly productive areas. However, all these farmers face exactly the same logistics problems described before, which impact shipping costs from these inland areas to the international ports along the north and east coast. In addition, there is an absolute absence of warehousing facilities within every rural property, and the roadway network would be best described as an unpaved pathway network, hardly usable during the rain season.

In the case of Maranhão, the flow of products requires their transport to the production centroid of Balsas, from where 385 km of paved road convey the products to Imperatriz, where they are transshipped to the railway and move to the port of Itaqui. According to EMBRAPA (1997), apud Giordano (1999), in local currency freight costs per ton from the farms to Balsas averages R$ 17, from Balsas to Imperatriz R$ 12, from Imperatriz to Itaqui R$ 9.50, and from Itaqui to the port of Rotterdam R$ 27.70. According to the same study, these transportation costs represent US$ 68/ton, in contrast to similar farm-to-Rotterdam logistics costs of US$ 28 and US$ 43 in the United States and Argentina, respectively.

In the state of Piauí the problems are similar, but access to the port of Itaqui, 611 km away from the production area, is made entirely by trucks through paved roads. Therefore, one single transportation mode over a not too distant port makes the operation more economical. In any case, production in this state is still smaller than in the other two, as shown by Table 1.

A complete study similar to that of Tocantins was not made for Maranhão and Piauí; only Scenario 1 was considered. Thus, for the existing transportation structure the results are summarized in Table 2.

Therefore, costs in the states of Maranhão and Piauí are 16.5% and 15.3% more competitive than those of Tocantins. On the other hand, if the Tocantins hydroway becomes operational its production will become more competitive than the other two states, and its transportation costs per ton will be reduced to US$ 29.60, according to Figure 5, Scenario 2. Note, however, that no similar evaluation of possible alternative logistics costs study was made for these two states.

7. Conclusions

The global demand for soybeans is expanding very quickly since this is a valuable grain used in different forms by humans and by animals. The former use it as cooking oil and consume these beans as a rich and nutritious product, while the latter, around the world, have soybeans as one of the main ingredients for cattle raising and poultry production. In a number of poor countries, the present increase in domestic income is contributing to expand, usually indirectly, the demand for soybean. For example, a typical conversion rate of grain into meat is 2.8:1, i.e. an additional 1 million tons of meat would require 2.8 million tons of grain.

Brazil appears to be the only country that has suitable land potentially able to be converted into large-scale soybean production and to export the additional production, since its cattle herd grazes and human consumption is limited. However, problems in the country's infrastructure are restraining its faster development. Thus, the objective of this research was to propose a model for evaluating the competitiveness of soybean production in a recently occupied state in the northern part of the country, the state of Tocantins. In the area considered in the case study, productivity is very high, but the logistics to export the product is costly and very inefficient, although alternative routes might devised, evaluated, and developed. Since the product is exported in its raw form, the supply peak occurs during the harvest period, when transport tariffs are costly, all transport modes congested, and prices for the product depressed. Therefore, warehousing part of the production would reduce the incidence of these problems and help improve competitiveness.

In addition, the study has also examined the soybean production of the states of Maranhão and Piauí, that are neighbors of Tocantins and share similar difficulties. For these two states an evaluation of the existing logistics structure was carried out but no alternative scenarios have been developed. An interesting finding is that the production of Tocantins is less competitive than the one of the two states, but this situation might be reversed if the hydroway is made operational.

The present study has proposed a spatial multimodal and temporal equilibrium model expressed by a nonlinear programming model to evaluate a number of logistics routes for reaching the maritime ports at lower costs. The study has considered four different scenarios and this has reduced the size of the model. When the entire infrastructure depicted by these scenarios becomes available, a comprehensive model might be devised to determine mixed logistics strategies. Results of the study are interesting and suggest priorities in infrastructure investments to deal with a problem of national interest.

Acknowledgements

This first and second authors would like to thanks the CNPq, the National Council for Scientific and Technological Development of Brazil, who supported in part this research.

Note

A previous version of this paper was presented in the IFORS 2008: "Contribution to the Competitivity Evaluation: An Application of the Spatial Equilibrium Model to the Soybean Production in the State of Tocantins in Brazil"; Betty Barraza de la Cruz, Nelio D. Pizzolato and Andrès Barraza de la Cruz; IFORS 2008, Sandton, South Africa, 13-18 julho July 2008, p. 44.

Recebido em 08/2008; aceito em 10/2009

Received August 2008; accepted October 2009

  • (1) Bivings, E.L. (1997). The seasonal and spatial dimensions of sorghum market liberalization in México. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79, 383-393.
  • (2) Bulhões, R. & Caixeta-Filho, J.V. (1999). Aplicação de um modelo de equilíbrio espacial para análise da competição entre os portos de Paranaguá e Santos para movimentação de soja. In: Congreso Chileno de Ingeniería de Transportes 9, 1999. Santiago de Chile. Atas..., Santiago de Chile, 351-363.
  • (3) Caixeta Filho, J.V. & Macaulay, T.G. (1989). A utilização de modelos de equilíbrio espacial para a avaliação econômica de políticas agrícolas: estudo de caso australiano. In: XXVII Congresso Brasileiro de Economia e Sociologia Rural. São Paulo. Anais..., Sober, São Paulo, 232-245.
  • (4) Chen, C.-C.; McCarl, B.A. & Chang, C.-C. (2004). Spatial equilibrium modeling with imperfectly competitive markets: an application to rice trade Available at: <http://agecon2.tamu.edu/people/faculty/mccarl-bruce/papers/736.pdf> Accessed on: 19 Jul. 2004.
  • (5) Cramer, G.L.; Wailes, E.J. & Shui, S. (1993). Impacts of liberalization trade in the world rice market. Agric. Econ, 75, 219-226.
  • (6) Dennis, S.M. (1999). Using spatial equilibrium model to analyze transportation rates: an application to steam coal in the Unites States. Transportation Research, part E, 35, 145-154.
  • (7) Fuller, S.; Fellin, L. & Salin, V. (2003). Effect of liberalized U.S.-México rice trade: A spatial, multiproduct equilibrium analysis. Agribusiness, 19, 1-17.
  • (8) Fuller, S.; Fellin, L.; Lalor, A. & Klindworth, K. (2000). Agricultural Transportation Challengers for the 21st Century: Effect of improving South American Transportation Systems on U.S. and South American Corn and Soybean Economies. Agricultural Marketing Service, 1-40, Oct 2000.
  • (9) Gabriel, S.A.; Manik, J. & Vikas, S. (2001). Computational experience with a large-scale, multi-period, spatial equilibrium model of the North American natural gas system. Network and Spatial Economics, 3, 97-122.
  • (10) Garcia, J.A. (1999). Distribución espacial e intertemporal de la producción de maíz en México. Montecillo, Texcoco. 158p. Teses (Doctoral en Ciencias). Colegio de Postgraduados en Ciencias Agrícolas.
  • (11) Garcia, J.A.; Matus, J.A.; Martinez, M.A.; Santiago, M. & Martinez, A. (2000). Determination of the optimal demand of maize storage in México. Agrociencia, 34, 773-784.
  • (12) GEIPOT - Empresa Brasileira de Planejamento de Transportes (1999). Corredores Estratégicos de Desenvolvimento - Relatório Final GEIPOT, Brasília.
  • (13) IBGE - Instituto Brasileiro de Geografia e Estatística (2007). Mapa Geográfico Brasil-TO Available at: <http://www.ibge.gov.br>. Accessed on: 3 Dec. 2007.
  • (14) Nagurney, A. (1993). Network Economics: A variational inequality approach. Kluwer Academic Publisher, Boston, USA.
  • (15) Samuelson, P.A. (1952). Spatial Price Equilibrium and Linear Program. American Economic Review, 42, 283-303.
  • (16) Takayama, T. (1995). Thirty years with spatial and intertemporal economics. The Annals of Regional Science, 28, 305-322.
  • (17) Takayama, T. & Judge, G. (1964). Equilibrium among spatially separated markets: a reformulation. Econometrica, 519-524.
  • (18) Takayama, T. & Judge, G. (1971). Spatial and Temporal Price and Allocation Models North Holland, Amsterdam. 528p.
  • (19) Tôsto, S.G. (1996). Mercado interno de grãos de soja: Modelos de equilíbrio e desequilíbrio. Viçosa, MG. 114p. Dissertação (Mestrado em Economia Rural). Universidade Federal de Viçosa.
  • (20) USDA-United States Department of Agriculture (2007). World agricultural outlook board. <http://usda.mannlib.cornell.edu?mannUsda/viewDocumentInfo.do?documentID=1194>. Accessed on January 03, 2007.
  • (21) Waquil, P.D. (1996). Alocação ótima de produtos agropecuários no Mercosul: um modelo de equilíbrio espacial com produtos intermediários. Revista Brasileira de Economia e Sociologia Rural, 34(1/2), 87-109, Brasília, Jan/Jun 1996.
  • (22) Yan, C.W. et al. (2002). The Cournot competition in the spatial equilibrium model. Energy Economics, 24, 139-154.
  • *
    Corresponding author / autor para quem as correspondências devem ser encaminhadas
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      18 Oct 2010
    • Date of issue
      Aug 2010

    History

    • Received
      Aug 2008
    • Accepted
      Oct 2009
    Sociedade Brasileira de Pesquisa Operacional Rua Mayrink Veiga, 32 - sala 601 - Centro, 20090-050 Rio de Janeiro RJ - Brasil, Tel.: +55 21 2263-0499, Fax: +55 21 2263-0501 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
    E-mail: sobrapo@sobrapo.org.br