Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Capital mobility in developing countries: evidence from panel data

Abstracts

The purpose of this paper is to show that the use of panel data can shed some light on the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle. The use of panel data would bring in two advantages. First, it would avoid the bias towards low capital mobility brought by the use of time-averaged data. Second, it would make possible to take into account specific effects (heterogeneity) like a country's size. Pooling annual data for the period 1960-1996 for 29 developing countries, the estimated impact of saving on investment is considerably smaller and it is possible to conclude that there is some degree of capital mobility in developing countries. Therefore, the high estimated saving-investment correlation seems to be due more to the existence of specific individual country effects than to capital immobility. The coefficient stability through time remains a puzzle though.

capital mobility; panel data; heterogeneity; developing countries


O objetivo deste artigo é mostrar que dados em painel podem ajudar a entender o puzzle de Feldstein-Horioka. O uso de dados em painel traria duas vantagens. Primeiro, faria com que fosse evitado o viés em direção à baixa mobilidade de capitais resultante do uso da média dos dados. Segundo, tornaria possível levar em conta efeitos específicos (heterogeneidade), como o tamanho do país. Usando dados em painel para o período 1960-1996 para 29 países em desenvolvimento, o impacto estimado da poupança sobre o investimento é bem menor, sendo possível concluir que existe um grau intermediário de mobilidade de capitais. Assim, o alto valor estimado para a correlação poupança-investimento parece resultar mais da existência de efeitos específicos individuais do país do que de baixa mobilidade de capitais. A estabilidade dos coeficientes estimados ao longo do tempo permanece, contudo, um puzzle.

mobilidade de capitais; dados em painel; heterogeneidade; países em desenvolvimento


Capital mobility in developing countries: evidence from panel data

Fabiana Rocha* * Endereço para contato: FEA/USP – Av. Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 908. Cid. Universitária. CEP: 05508-010. São Paulo – SP.

Professora do Departamento de Economia da FEA-USP. E-mail: frocha@usp.br

ABSTRACT

The purpose of this paper is to show that the use of panel data can shed some light on the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle. The use of panel data would bring in two advantages. First, it would avoid the bias towards low capital mobility brought by the use of time-averaged data. Second, it would make possible to take into account specific effects (heterogeneity) like a country's size. Pooling annual data for the period 1960-1996 for 29 developing countries, the estimated impact of saving on investment is considerably smaller and it is possible to conclude that there is some degree of capital mobility in developing countries. Therefore, the high estimated saving-investment correlation seems to be due more to the existence of specific individual country effects than to capital immobility. The coefficient stability through time remains a puzzle though.

Key Words: capital mobility, panel data, heterogeneity, developing countries

JEL Classification: C23, F31

RESUMO

O objetivo deste artigo é mostrar que dados em painel podem ajudar a entender o puzzle de Feldstein-Horioka. O uso de dados em painel traria duas vantagens. Primeiro, faria com que fosse evitado o viés em direção à baixa mobilidade de capitais resultante do uso da média dos dados. Segundo, tornaria possível levar em conta efeitos específicos (heterogeneidade), como o tamanho do país. Usando dados em painel para o período 1960-1996 para 29 países em desenvolvimento, o impacto estimado da poupança sobre o investimento é bem menor, sendo possível concluir que existe um grau intermediário de mobilidade de capitais. Assim, o alto valor estimado para a correlação poupança-investimento parece resultar mais da existência de efeitos específicos individuais do país do que de baixa mobilidade de capitais. A estabilidade dos coeficientes estimados ao longo do tempo permanece, contudo, um puzzle.

Palavras-chave: mobilidade de capitais, dados em painel, heterogeneidade, países em desenvolvimento

INTRODUCTION

The empirical evidence on the effective degree of capital mobility in developing countries is extremely scarce when compared to that for developed economies. This happens despite widespread acknowledgment of the importance of the extent of capital mobility in determining, for example, optimal monetary and fiscal policies (Fleming, 1962; Mundell, 1968), the exchange rate (Levich, 1985), the tax rate on income from capital (Feldstein and Horioka, 1980), and to analyze the inflationary tax (Easterly et al., 1995).

Feldstein and Horioka (1980) suggested the correlation between saving and investment rates as a measure of the degree of capital mobility. Based on a sample of 16 OECD countries, they obtained evidence that saving and investment rates were highly correlated. They in turn concluded that the degree of capital mobility in industrialized countries was low, going against accepted wisdom that these countries had few restrictions on capital flows. The Feldstein-Horioka puzzle refers to the empirical finding that estimates of the saving-investment correlation have remained high, despite the use of more recent data and different econometric techniques. Murphy (1984), Obstfeld (1986), Dooley et al. (1987) and Wong (1990) also found a close association between saving and investment for less industrialized and developing countries, although the estimated correlation was lower on average.

The purpose of this paper is to present some additional empirical evidence on the degree of capital mobility in developing countries, using the procedure based on the correlation between saving and investment formulated by Feldstein and Horioka (1980). Its main contribution is to verify how important are the effects of country heterogeneity in saving and investment rates association. More precisely, it seeks to verify what happens to the FH puzzle when heterogeneity is explicitly accounted for. In order to do so we use three different panel data estimators. The difference among them results from the importance that each gives to the individual and temporal dimensions. The pooled estimator assumes both individual homogeneity and temporal stability. The between estimator, in working with averages, eliminates the temporal variability and emphasizes the inter-country dimension. Just like the pooled indicator, it implies homogeneity among countries. The within indicator, in turn, uses the variability among countries, since it is calculated from the difference between the saving and investment ratio and the averages over time for each country and takes into account the heterogeneity of the data. We also believe that panel data methods can also help us to deal with the dilemma of working only with individual (country by country) data versus temporal (year to year) data that involves the literature. The sample consists of annual data (1960-1996) for 29 developing countries.

The paper is organized in five sections including this introduction. The first section summarizes the main evidence on capital mobility in developing countries in the existing literature. The second section presents the advantages that using panel data techniques may bring to the estimation of the saving-investment correlation. The third section contains a discussion of the results of the estimations, and the last section concludes.

1. PREVIOUS RESULTS FOR DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Feldstein and Horioka (1980) proposed evaluating the degree of capital mobility through the correlation between saving and investment, estimating the following cross-section regression:1 1 Following the literature, we refer to b as a correlation even though it is a coefficient of regression and thus a measure of linear association.

where (I / Y) is the ratio between gross domestic investment and gross national product (GNP), (S / Y) is the ratio between gross national saving and GNP, i is a country index, a and b represent the parameters to be estimated, and u is an error term. Under the null hypothesis of perfect capital mobility, b should be near zero, i.e., there should be no relation between saving and investment. National saving, then, should really be part of an international capital pool free to seek the best rate of return. On the other hand, under the null hypothesis of perfect capital immobility, b should be equal to 1. In this case, all additional saving would go to finance domestic investment.

Using a sample of OECD countries, Feldstein and Horioka (1980) found an estimate b for equal to 0.89 for the period 1960-74. They interpreted this result as implying a low degree of capital mobility among industrialized countries, contradicting the belief that these nations have few barriers to capital flows.

Following Feldstein and Horioka, Dooley et al. (1987) estimated regression (1) using cross-section data for developing countries. Their estimates suggested a close association between saving and investment, indicating a low degree of capital mobility. They found positive correlations for the ratios of saving and investment both in levels and in differences. They also estimated the equations separately for the periods 1960-73 and 1974-84, since a greater degree of capital mobility was expected for the latter period, when industrialized countries reduced their capital controls and the OPEC surpluses were recycled. Surprisingly, the correlations for the first period were smaller than for the second. These results, nevertheless, appear robust to a variety of econometric objections. To deal with the argument of the political reaction of the government and endogeneity of saving, instrumental variables were included in the regressions.2 2 The endogeneity of saving is one of the arguments presented in the literature to try to conciliate a high correlation between saving and investment and a high degree of capital mobility. A special form of endogeneity can arise from the reaction of the government to current account deficits. If the government does not like deficits in its current account (increases in I/Y in relation to S/Y), it responds by adopting a contractionist fiscal policy. Since national saving is the sum of private and public saving, national saving becomes endogenous through its public component. (Summers, 1988). The results, though, were similar to those obtained using ordinary least squares regressions.

Various authors have also tested the saving-investment correlation for individual countries. Thus, equation (1) has been estimated for different countries using time series. Since investment and saving appear to have a unit root, the regressions have been carried out using the first difference of these variables to avoid the problem of spurious correlation. (Granger and Newbold, 1974). Mamingi (1997) and Montiel (1994) used the first difference of saving and of investment, but assumed that these are cointegrated, given that the intertemporal budget constraint does not allow saving and investment to diverge permanently.3 3 In reality, Montiel (1994) is aware that the null hypothesis of no cointegration may possibly be rejected only for a few countries, but using the solvency argument he attributes the failure in not accepting cointegration to the small size of the sample available for developing countries. Mamingi (1997) estimated a time series version of equation (1), adopting the fully modified OLS estimator (Phillips and Hansen, 1990). Montiel (1994), besides the regressions with variables in levels and in differences, estimated an error-correction version of the Feldstein-Horioka regression. A simple specification is chosen, given the small number of observations: the first difference of investment is regressed in a constant, in the lagged residual of the regression from cointegration and the first difference of saving. The regressions were estimated using least squares and instrumental variables.

Bagnai and Manzocchi (1996) try to avoid imposing the cointegration hypothesis. They argue that since saving and investment are I (1), the hypothesis of Feldstein and Horioka of perfect capital immobility corresponds to the hypothesis that (S / Y)i – (I / Y)i is I (0). Given that by definition the difference between saving and investment is equal to the current account balance, if it is not possible to reject the hypothesis of the nonstationary of the current account , one can conclude that there is capital mobility.

The evidence for developing countries using time series data is summarized in Table 1. The results indicate that although capital is far from being perfectly mobile, there is a certain degree of mobility. This, then, goes against common sense that says these countries maintain a significant legal restriction on capital movements (inflows and outflows). Nevertheless, there is no consensus regarding the extent of capital mobility in each country individually. Only two of the 23 countries (Israel and S. Korea) are classified equally by Mamingi (1997), Montiel (1994) and Bagnai and Manzocchi (1996). On the other hand, eight countries are classified differently by the three authors as to their levels of capital mobility (Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, India, Malawi, Malaysia, Senegal and Thailand).

It is important to observe that other measures have been used to assess the extent of capital mobility in developing countries. The interest parity tests are based on the differential in return, i.e., the difference between the domestic and external interest rates, corrected by the exchange rate. With rational expectations, the mean value of the return differential should be zero and the mean deviations should be serially non-correlated. Montiel (1994) conducted uncovered interest parity (UIP) tests for 48 countries during the period January 1985 to December 1990.4 4 Montiel (1994) is the most extensive study of capital mobility in developing countries. Thirty-two countries in the sample presented mean deviations that were different than zero.

The Euler equation tests establish that the expected marginal rates of substitution between current and future units of domestic currency should be equal for foreign and domestic residents. The results for the great majority of countries, according to Montiel (1994), indicate a high degree of capital mobility.

Finally, the consumption-smoothing approach uses the hypothesis of permanent income to assess capital mobility. If the degree of capital mobility is high, the economy as a whole should be able to completely smooth out consumption over the occurrence of shocks. This means that the current account should be used as a buffer to smooth out aggregate consumption in the case of shocks to national cash flow (output less investment less government expenditures). If cash flow is expected to grow on average over the long run, it is optimal for the country to accumulate debt by running current account deficits. If , on the other hand, long-run cash flow is expected to fall, it is optimal for the country to maintain a current account surplus (boost its saving) in order to be able to consume in the future at a level consistent with its permanent income. If the level and the volatility of current account movements are smaller than those forecasted under the full smoothing hypothesis, then capital has a low degree of mobility. Ghosh and Ostry (1995), using this approach, concluded that in 30 of 45 countries the null hypothesis that consumption is completely smoothed out vis-à-vis shocks could not be rejected, suggesting a relatively high degree of capital mobility in developing countries. Hussein and Mello Jr (1999) also used the intertemporal consumption-smoothing model to test the degree of capital mobility in developing countries. They found evidence of very mobile capital in nine of the countries in their sample (Chile, Greece, Ireland, Israel, Malaysia, Mexico, South Africa, South Korea and Venezuela).

2. PANEL DATA TECHNIQUES AND THE SAVING-INVESTMENT CORRELATION

There are basically two arguments in the literature that try to reconcile the existence of a high correlation between saving and investment and the hypothesis of capital mobility. The first is the endogeneity of saving, implying that other factors could produce a correlation between saving and investment even when capital is mobile. Examples of these exogenous factors are: the pro-cyclicity of saving and investment, population growth (Summers, 1988; Obstfeld, 1986); productivity and other shocks (Obstfeld, 1986); the presence of consumption of non-tradable goods (Murphy, 1986; and Wong, 1990); and the reaction of the government to current account imbalances (Summers, 1988; and Wong, 1990). To deal with this problem of endogeneity, Feldstein and Horioka (1980), Feldstein (1983), Tesar (1991) and others work with a cross-section analysis based on sample averages during the time period, trying to eliminate the influence of the economic cycle on the saving-investment correlation. Since I / Y and S / Y are pro-cyclical, the use of annual data implies an upward bias in the estimation of the coefficient b, and to avoid the problem it would be best to work with the mean of the data. Summers (1988) and Feldstein and Bacchetta (1991), in turn, add the variable to the regression. Finally, Feldstein and Horioka (1980), Frankel (1986, 1991) and Dooley et al. (1987) use instrumental variables.

According to Sinn (1992), however, the use of intertemporal models calls attention to a new empirical problem.

Assuming that public bonds mature in a period, the external budget constraint in period t can be written as:

where Mt represents imports, Xt exports, Bt is external debt, rt and is the interest rate (one period). Equation (2) corresponds to the usual external constraint, establishing that a current account deficit must be financed by issuing new debt.

Solving the sequence of type (2) period-to-period constraints yields the following equation:

Equation (3) is the external intertemporal budget constraint. It establishes that when the last term is equal to zero, the amount that a country borrows (lends) in international markets is equal to the present value of its future surpluses (deficits). In other words, a loan in period t must be repaid in the future. When the term at the limit is different than zero, the country is engaging in a Ponzi scheme with its debt, i.e., it is paying past debt by issuing new debt. Simply put, a country cannot borrow or lend indefinitely – current account surpluses (deficits) must be followed by current account deficits (surpluses). By definition, the current account balance of a country in any period is equal to the difference between investment and saving. Given that the sum of the current account balances must be equal to zero in the long run, the same must occur with the difference between saving and investment.5 5 The result of Sinn (1992) is derived for a stagnant (no-growth) economy, but his argument is also valid when there is growth. However, since the averages over the long run of the saving/GNP ratio are approximately equal, the use of average data introduces a correlation between these two variables (see the appendixappendix). Hence, cross-section regressions using the average of long-term investment and saving tend to erroneously signal a low degree of capital mobility.6 6 The cross-section regressions not only result in high correlation coefficients, but also stable ones over time, despite the increase in capital mobility after the mid-1970s. The need to meet the intertemporal budget restriction during all periods can offer an explanation of why in cross-section studies the estimated correlation does not vary much.

There are then, two opposing arguments. The economic cycle argument implies that when annual data are used, the coefficient b is greater than that calculated using the average of the data, while the intertemporal budget constraint argument suggests the opposite.

To avoid these two potential sources of bias, panel techniques are employed. The use of annual data tries to avoid the bias implied by the solvency argument and the inclusion of time dummies controls for temporal factors common to all countries (e.g., the international economic cycle).

The second argument for a high correlation between saving and investment even in the presence of capital mobility is given by the country-size effect. This appears in two versions. Murphy (1984) and Baxter and Crucini (1993) suggest that if a country is large enough to affect the world interest rate, an increase in its national saving will reduce international interest rates and consequently increase domestic investment. Harberger (1980), in turn, argues that "as countries become larger, they become more diversified and the need to borrow from abroad in the event of shock declines."

If the country-size argument is important, the estimation of a regression in which the countries in the sample are treated identically in their capacity to influence international market conditions will imply a bias in the correlation coefficient. In this sense, the use of panel data brings the additional advantage of controlling for country-specific effects such as size.

3. RESULTS

The sample is composed of a set of annual observations of the ratios of saving and investment from 1960 to 1996 for 29 developing countries: Argentina, Botswana, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras, Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Israel, Jamaica, S. Korea, Malawi, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Paraguay, Philippines, Senegal, Singapore, Thailand and Venezuela. The data were obtained from the World Bank Indicators (1998). Domestic investment corresponds to gross investment in the private sector and by the government, and saving to the sum of private sector and government saving. Both are divided by the gross domestic product (GDP) in order to convert them into rates. The data set ends in 1996 so the results can be compared to the cross-section estimates already available for developing countries, that do not consider samples much longer than this.

Initially, only whether country-specific effects exist is examined. In order to do so four estimation procedures are used: pooled, between, within and an error-components (random effects) model. The difference among the estimators derives from the importance given by each to individual and temporal dimensions. The pooled estimator assumes both individual homogeneity and temporal stability. The between estimator is obtained from the average ratios of saving and investment in the period for each country. In this way, it eliminates the temporal variability and emphasizes the dimension among countries. Just as the pooled estimator, the between one implies homogeneity among countries. Empirical studies, such as those discussed previously, generally used the between estimator with the argument that the economic cycle influences saving and investment in the same direction. The within estimator is calculated from the difference in the ratio of saving and investment and the averages over time for each country. It uses the variability among countries and takes into account the heterogeneity of the data. The random effects model incorporates heterogeneity among the countries in including a specific non-observable effect in the error term.

Table 2 shows the results of the different estimators for the sample period along with two sub-periods (1960-74 and 1975-96).

Except for the period 1960-74, the correlation coefficient between saving and investment for the between estimator is relatively high.7 7 It is difficult to establish a period to divide the sample, since developing countries alternated periods of greater and lesser capital controls that do not necessarily coincide. We chose the mid-1970s because it is considered the main point of inflection in international capital flows. Moreover, this estimator and the pooled one present similar values in all sample periods. The within and random effects estimators are quite similar, although only in the period 1975-96 does the Hausman Test (Hausman, 1978) indicate that the random effects model is superior to the fixed effects one.

In any event, both the within and random effects estimates are statistically different from zero and one at the 1% level of significance, indicating rejection of both the hypothesis of perfect mobility and that of perfect immobility. However, the values are well below that considered a benchmark for industrial countries by Murphy (1984), which is 0.6.

The null hypothesis of the existence of an individual fixed effect is strongly accepted for the 29 countries for all the samples. The results indicate, then, that when the heterogeneity of countries is specified, lower values of the saving-investment correlation are obtained. The question that remains unanswered is the persistence in the value of the estimated coefficient. Even though the within coefficient is lower in the second sub-interval than in the first, suggesting a relative increase in capital mobility over time, this change is not significant.8 8 Dooley et al. (1987) also did not find evidence of increased capital mobility after 1973, both for industrialized and developing countries. Indeed, the positive correlations between saving and investment appear to be higher in the period after 1973.

In order to account for the effects of the economic cycle (supposing the existence of an international cycle), we estimated a least squares dummy variable (LSDV) model, extended to include the specific effect of time: 9 9 The random effects model including a specific time component along with individual effects é y it = a | b'x it | e it | u i | w t. The estimate obtained, although not presented here, is very similar to that of the fixed effects model.

where yit is equal to I(i,t)/Y(i,t ), xit is equal to S(i,t)/Y(i,t ), the index i represents the country and t time. The model has a general constant and a "group" effect for each country. It assumes that the differences over the units can be captured by differences in the constant term, i.e., ai removes the fixed differences among countries (size). The model also has a "time" effect for each period. gt is included to eliminate time-related factors common to all the countries included in the sample.10 10 If the product varies positively among countries, saving and investment can move together even if capital is mobile, and this must be considered empirically.

The estimates of equation 4 are presented in Table 3 below.

The estimated coefficients fall a bit. They are still statistically different from zero and one, indicating rejection of the hypotheses of perfect mobility and perfect immobility. The hypothesis of the existence of a specific fixed effect is accepted in all periods. If the country effects are considered separately, the hypothesis of no country effects is rejected at the 1% level (F statistic equals to 16.802). When a model with country effects is compared with another with country and time effects, the F statistic (5.916) indicates that the international economic cycle is also a significant element in the analysis.

CONCLUSIONS

It has been more than 25 years since Feldstein and Horioka (1980) established that averages of saving and investment- expressed as ratios of GDP- were highly correlated, and still there is interest in their puzzle.

As an indicator of capital mobility the saving-investment correlation of Feldstein and Horioka has some advantages over other indicators in the literature. For example, it does not have to deal with the problem of heterogeneity of assets, as occurs with the tests of parity conditions, and does not incorporate multiple hypotheses as the Euler equation tests or the consumption-smoothing approach. The Feldstein-Horioka test, however, is vulnerable to indirect sources of co-movement between saving and investment, especially the economic cycle and country size. Here we try to deal with both problems by using panel data techniques. The use of a model with group and time effects allows removal of fixed differences among countries (size) and temporal factors common to all countries (world economic cycle). Besides this, given that the intertemporal budget constraint implies that saving and investment are approximately equal when averaged data, it is possible to work with annual data. The basic idea is to verify if these properties of panel data methods may be in fact useful in the context of the Feldstein-Horioka debate.

We estimate the saving-investment correlation for a group of 29 developing countries during the period 1960-1996, according to four procedures: pooled, between, within and a random effects model. Initially we consider only the possible existence of differences among the countries, and subsequently also the existence of a common cyclical factor. In both cases, we conclude that the relatively high saving-investment correlation coefficient for the between estimator may indicate the presence of atypical countries in the sample (which biases the estimates upward) rather than a low degree of capital mobility. In other words, a high correlation coefficient in cross-section analyses appears to result from specific individual effects. The estimated coefficient is 0.40, implying that both the hypothesis of perfect mobility and that of perfect immobility are rejected. Nevertheless, this value is well below the 0.60 considered by Murphy (1984) as a representative value for industrialized countries. This result is quite different from other estimates derived from the standard Feldstein-Horioka regressions. Dooley et al. (1987) ordinary least squares regressions that relate saving and investment ratios for 48 developing countries produce estimates of 0.455 and 0.610 for the periods 1960-73 and 1974-84, respectively. Montiel (1994) ordinary least squares estimates indicate that of 62 countries, only 19 produced point estimates of the correlation coefficient below 0.6 during the period 1970-1990. Therefore it seems to be evidence that the high coefficient of correlation in cross section studies is not due to imperfect capital mobility but to the existence of specific individual country effects. The stability of the estimated correlation coefficient over time remains a puzzle, however.

(Recebido em abril de 2005. Aceito para publicação em março de 2006).

As can be seen in Table A.1, only in nine of the 29 countries in the sample is the difference between saving and investment greater than 5%. This is not to say, however, that these countries did not respond to international capital flows through movements in their current accounts. A good example is Chile. In 1981 there was a large increase in its current account, followed by a rapid decline in 1983. In reality, in two years it passed from current account deficit of 10% of GNP to a surplus of nearly 3% of GNP. However, as can be seen in the table, the difference between the saving/GNP ratio and the investment/GNP ratio is only 0.2% when mean data are considered.

  • Bagnai, A.; Manzocchi, S. Unit root tests of capital mobility in the less developed countries. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, v. 132, n. 3, p. 545-557, 1996.
  • Baxter, M.; Crucini, M. Explaining saving-investment correlations. American Economic Review, 83, p. 416-436, 1993.
  • Dooley, M.; Frankel, J.; Mathieson, D. International capital mobility: what do saving-investment correlations tell us? IMF Staff Papers, v. 34, n. 3, p. 503-530, 1987.
  • Easterly, W. R.; Mauro, P.; Schmidt-Hebbel, K. Money demand and seigniorage maximizing inflation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, v. 27, n. 2, p. 583-603, 1995.
  • Feldstein, M. Domestic saving and international capital movements in the short run and the long run. The European Economic Review 21, p. 129-151, 1983.
  • Feldstein, M.; Bacchetta, P. National saving and international investment. In: Bernheim, D.; Shoven, J. (eds.), National saving and economic performance. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991, p. 201-220.
  • Feldstein, M.; Horioka, C. Domestic saving and international capital flows. Economic Journal, 90, p. 314-329, June 1980.
  • Fleming, J. M. Domestic financial policies under fixed and under floating exchange rates. IMF Staff Papers, v. 9, n. 3, p. 369-380, 1962.
  • Frankel, J. International capital mobility and crowding-out in the U.S. economy: imperfect integration of financial markets or of goods markets? In: Hafer, R. (ed.), How open is the U.S. economy? Lexington: Lexington Books for the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, 1986, p. 33-67.
  • _______. Quantifying international capital mobility in the 1980s. In: Bernheim, D.; Shoven, J. (eds.), National saving and economic performance. Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1991, p. 227-260.
  • Ghosh, A. R.; Ostry, J. D. The current account in developing countries: a perspective from the consumption-smoothing approach. The World Bank Economic Review, v. 9, n. 2, p. 305-333, 1995.
  • Granger, C. W. J.; Newbold, P. Spurious regression in econometrics. Journal of Econometrics, v. 2, n. 2, p. 111-120, 1974.
  • Harberger, A. C. Vignettes on the world capital market. American Economic Review, v. 70, Papers and Proceedings, p. 331-337, 1980.
  • Hausmann, J. Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, p. 1251-1271, November 1978.
  • Hussein, K. A.; Mello Jr., L. R. International capital mobility in developing countries: theory and evidence. Journal of International Money and Finance, 18, p. 367-381, 1999.
  • Levich, R. M. Empirical studies of exchange rates: price behavior, rate determination and market efficiency. In: Jones, R. W.; Kenen, P. B. (eds.), Handbook of international economics, v. II. Amsterdan: Elsevier, 1985.
  • Mamingi, N. Saving-investment correlations and capital mobility: the experience of developing countries. Journal of Policy Modeling, v. 19, n. 6, p. 605-626, 1997.
  • Montiel, P. Capital mobility in developing countries: some measurement issues and empirical estimates. World Bank Economic Review, v. 8, n. 3, p. 311-350, 1994.
  • Mundell, R. A. International economics. New York: MacMillan, 1968.
  • Murphy, R. G. Capital mobility and the relationship between saving and investment in OECD countries. Journal of International Money and Finance, v. 3, p. 327-342, 1984.
  • _______. Productivity shocks, non-traded goods and optimal capital accumulation. European Economic Review, 30, p. 1081-1095, 1986.
  • Obstfeld, M. Capital mobility in the world economy: theory and evidence. Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, 24, p. 55-104, 1986.
  • Obstfeld, M.; Rogoff, K. The six major puzzles in international macroeconomics: is there a common cause?. NBER Working Paper 7777, 2000.
  • Phillips, P. C. B.; Hansen, B. E. Statistical inference in instrumental variables regression with I (1) processes. Review of Economic Studies, v. 57, n. 1, p. 99-125, 1990.
  • Sinn, S. Saving-investment correlations and capital mobility: on the evidence from annual data. Economic Journal, 102, p. 1162-1170, September 1992.
  • Summers, L. H. Tax policy and international competitiveness. In: Frenkel, Jacob A. (ed.), International aspects of fiscal policies. NBER Conference Report, Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1988, p. 340-375.
  • Tesar, L. Saving, investment and international capital flows. Journal of International Economics, 31, p. 55-78, 1991.
  • Wong, D. What do saving-investment relationships tell us about capital mobility? Journal of International Money and Finance, v. 9, p. 60-74, 1990.

appendix

  • *
    Endereço para contato: FEA/USP – Av. Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 908. Cid. Universitária. CEP: 05508-010. São Paulo – SP.
  • 1
    Following the literature, we refer to
    b as a correlation even though it is a coefficient of regression and thus a measure of linear association.
  • 2
    The endogeneity of saving is one of the arguments presented in the literature to try to conciliate a high correlation between saving and investment and a high degree of capital mobility. A special form of endogeneity can arise from the reaction of the government to current account deficits. If the government does not like deficits in its current account (increases in I/Y in relation to S/Y), it responds by adopting a contractionist fiscal policy. Since national saving is the sum of private and public saving, national saving becomes endogenous through its public component. (Summers, 1988).
  • 3
    In reality, Montiel (1994) is aware that the null hypothesis of no cointegration may possibly be rejected only for a few countries, but using the solvency argument he attributes the failure in not accepting cointegration to the small size of the sample available for developing countries.
  • 4
    Montiel (1994) is the most extensive study of capital mobility in developing countries.
  • 5
    The result of Sinn (1992) is derived for a stagnant (no-growth) economy, but his argument is also valid when there is growth.
  • 6
    The cross-section regressions not only result in high correlation coefficients, but also stable ones over time, despite the increase in capital mobility after the mid-1970s. The need to meet the intertemporal budget restriction during all periods can offer an explanation of why in cross-section studies the estimated correlation does not vary much.
  • 7
    It is difficult to establish a period to divide the sample, since developing countries alternated periods of greater and lesser capital controls that do not necessarily coincide. We chose the mid-1970s because it is considered the main point of inflection in international capital flows.
  • 8
    Dooley
    et al. (1987) also did not find evidence of increased capital mobility after 1973, both for industrialized and developing countries. Indeed, the positive correlations between saving and investment appear to be higher in the period after 1973.
  • 9
    The random effects model including a specific time component along with individual effects é y
    it = a | b'x
    it | e
    it | u
    i | w
    t. The estimate obtained, although not presented here, is very similar to that of the fixed effects model.
  • 10
    If the product varies positively among countries, saving and investment can move together even if capital is mobile, and this must be considered empirically.
  • Publication Dates

    • Publication in this collection
      17 Aug 2007
    • Date of issue
      Sept 2007

    History

    • Accepted
      Mar 2006
    • Received
      Apr 2005
    Departamento de Economia; Faculdade de Economia, Administração, Contabilidade e Atuária da Universidade de São Paulo (FEA-USP) Av. Prof. Luciano Gualberto, 908 - FEA 01 - Cid. Universitária, CEP: 05508-010 - São Paulo/SP - Brasil, Tel.: (55 11) 3091-5803/5947 - São Paulo - SP - Brazil
    E-mail: estudoseconomicos@usp.br