Acessibilidade / Reportar erro

Analytical perspectives in the study of regulatory policies

Abstract

The discussion of regulatory capture is not recent in state studies. However, the criteria to identify capture and the definition of the research protocols to demonstrate and measure the phenomenon have still not reached a consensus. This article carries out a non-exhaustive literature review to identify the main regulatory capture strategies and their respective measurement methods. We organize the regulation studies in four axes of regulatory capture strategies: capture by material incentives, capture by immaterial incentives, capture by threat, and capture by information asymmetry. Furthermore, the study examines the Brazilian case and discusses the contradictory results of recent research on the case of the National Supplementary Health Agency (ANS). We identified that, in general, Brazilian literature starts from a broad approach to understanding regulatory capture. Also, the studies adopt a restrictive approach mainly to explore the “revolving door” mechanism, following a trend in international literature but ignoring other mechanisms with explanatory potential. These findings have implications for research designs in studies of regulation in order to advance analyses beyond initial impressions and toward robust empirical research.

Keywords:
regulatory capture; regulatory agency; regulatory policy; revolving doors

Resumo

A discussão de captura regulatória não é uma agenda recente em estudos do Estado, mas o estabelecimento de critérios para identificação de captura, bem como a definição de protocolos para demonstração e mensuração do fenômeno estão longe de um consenso. O presente artigo tem por objetivo, por meio de uma revisão sistematizada não exaustiva da literatura, identificar as principais estratégias de captura e suas respectivas formas de mensuração. Propõe-se a organização dos estudos de regulação em quatro eixos de estratégias de captura: por incentivos materiais, por incentivos imateriais, por ameaça e por assimetria de informação. Ademais, busca-se examinar a produção sobre o caso brasileiro e discutir os resultados contraditórios de pesquisas recentes sobre o caso da Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS). Identificou-se que, em geral, a literatura brasileira parte de uma abordagem ampla de compreensão de captura e que os trabalhos que se orientam por uma abordagem restritiva exploram, principalmente, o mecanismo de “porta giratória”, seguindo uma tendência da literatura internacional, porém ignorando outros mecanismos com potencial explicativo. Esses achados têm implicações para desenhos de pesquisa em estudos sobre regulação, de forma a avançar as análises além das impressões iniciais e em direção a demonstrações empíricas robustas.

Palavras-chave:
captura; agência reguladora; política regulatória; porta giratória

Resumen

La discusión sobre la captura regulatoria no es una agenda reciente en los estudios del Estado, pero el establecimiento de criterios para la identificación de la captura, así como la definición de protocolos para demostrar y medir el fenómeno están lejos de un consenso. Este artículo tiene como objetivo, a través de una revisión bibliográfica no exhaustiva, identificar las principales estrategias de captura y sus respectivas formas de medición. Se propone organizar los estudios de regulación en cuatro ejes de estrategias de captura: por incentivos materiales, por incentivos inmateriales, por amenaza y por asimetría de información. Además, se busca examinar la producción sobre el caso brasileño y discutir los resultados contradictorios de investigaciones recientes sobre el caso de la Agencia Nacional de Salud Suplementaria (ANS). Se identificó que, en general, la literatura brasileña parte de un enfoque amplio para comprender la captura y que las obras guiadas por un enfoque restrictivo exploran principalmente el mecanismo de “puerta giratoria”, siguiendo una tendencia en la literatura internacional, sin tener en cuenta otros mecanismos con potencial explicativo. Estos resultados tienen implicaciones para diseños de investigación en estudios de regulación, con el fin de avanzar en los análisis más allá de las impresiones iniciales y hacia demostraciones empíricas sólidas.

Palabras clave:
captura; agencia reguladora; política regulatoria; puerta giratoria

1. INTRODUCTION

How can it be shown that a given regulatory policy outcome is a direct result of capture? How is it possible to assert that the influence potential of an interest group has actually resulted in regulatory capture? What is capture? These questions have prompted researchers in the field of regulation for decades and the debate is not limited to the theoretical dimension of the problem, but extends to include the methodological dimension also.

In his seminal study of regulatory agency capture, Stigler (1971Stigler, G. J. (1971). The Theory of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3-21.) initiated the discussion about State actions being directed towards interest groups. Marking a paradigm shift in regulation studies, Stigler was opposed to the figure of the benevolent public agent - the premise of the public interest framing - and put forward his theory of demand for regulation, indicating that regulation is both “acquired” by industry and driven by it for its own benefit.

Stigler’s pioneering spirit (1971Stigler, G. J. (1971). The Theory of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3-21.), which was followed by Peltzman (1976Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a More General Theory of Regulation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211-240.), is recognized as being the foundation of the agenda of regulatory capture, although subsequent research pointed out some gaps in his methodological approach. Criticisms of Stigler’s work - and that of other researchers who tackled the issue using econometric models - is that there was generally little discussion about how capture mechanisms were observed in practice.

In relation to this problem, Carpenter and Moss (2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.) reviewed not only Stigler’s publication, but the production that derived from his work, and pointed out that, generally speaking, capture was not being correctly diagnosed. In a detailed conceptual refinement, the authors maintain that in order to allege that capture exists, there needs to be an effort on three main fronts: 1 present a “falsifiable” model of public interest; 2 demonstrate political change that is favorable to a specific sector, but detrimental to public interest; and 3 demonstrate intention and sufficient action by the sector to justify the causal relationship.

In addition to these three aspects, the authors point to a lack of conceptual accuracy in several works that deal with different mechanisms of influence, corruption or regulatory failure as capture. In this particular sense, it is also important to be careful with regard to the definition of capture that is used.

Although the debate on regulatory capture is nothing new, the way in which the concept has been operationalized in empirical work is still very much open for debate. This issue is identified in the literature as the “capture paradox”, a widely recognized phenomenon, but one for which empirical evidence is limited (Agrell & Gautier, 2012Agrell, P. J; & Gautier, A. (2012). Rethinking regulatory capture. In J. E. Harrington & Y. Katsoulacos (Orgs.), Recent advances in the analysis of competition policy and regulation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing., 2017). The paradox lies in the fact that while there is widespread theoretical recognition of the capture phenomenon, there is an empirical failure to observe the channels by which capture takes place: for example, publicity about bribery agreements, or positions being offered to the regulators by those that are regulated, and vice versa.1 1 For a more in-depth debate on this point, see the Introduction of Carpenter and Moss (2013).

With specific reference to regulation research in Brazil, the scenario is no different. In addition to the fact that there are few works on the subject, there is no agreement as to how the concept of capture should be defined or operationalized. Recent publications about the National [Brazilian] Supplementary Health Agency (ANS), for example, reach contradictory conclusions with regard to agency capture (Baird, 2017Baird, M. F. (2017). Redes de influência, burocracia, política e negócios na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, SP., 2019; Ocké-Reis, Fiuza & Coimbra, 2019Ocké-Reis, C. O; Fiuza, E. P. S; & Coimbra, P. H. H. (2019). Inflação dos Planos de Saúde - 2000/2018 (Nota técnica No 54). Brasília, DF: IPEA.).

The aim of this paper is to advance this research agenda based on a review of recent production on regulatory capture. Following a review of international literature, the initial idea was to identify the main capture mechanisms used and the operationalization practices of the concept.

The intention was to analyze production in the case of Brazil and identify which analytical aspects have been guiding researchers in the country, what choices they adopted for measuring capture, and how these choices can lead to different results when studying the phenomenon.

We intend, therefore, to contribute towards refining the concept of regulatory capture by organizing the theoretical and methodological repertoire that is at the disposal of researchers, and thus help consolidate the agenda in regulatory policy studies in Brazil.

The article is organized as follows: the next section indicates the procedures that were adopted for selecting the academic articles that we reviewed. International literature will then be discussed to better situate the panorama in which production in Brazil is found. The article next discusses the case of Brazil, and by which analytical perspectives the country’s regulatory agencies have been analyzed. Finally, we resume the article’s main contributions and indications for future research that explores the capture phenomenon in developing countries.

2. NOTES ON REVIEW PROCEDURES

Although the article proposes to undertake a non-exhaustive review of the literature, some of the points about the way in which the academic articles were selected are worth discussing. The tree main databases we used in the research were: Web of Science, Scielo and Google Scholar.

Searches in the Web of Science database were filtered using the keywords “captura regulatória” and “regulatory capture”, but limited to the last five years. The results were restricted to the “Article” format in the following areas of knowledge: Economics, Political Science, Management, Business, Public Administration, International Relations, Health Policy Services and Interdisciplinary Social Sciences. On this basis, only articles that had been cited five or more times were selected, which returned a total of 72 articles.

Based on this initial selection, a qualitative analysis of the article abstracts was carried out to select only those whose specific objective was to discuss regulatory capture in theoretical terms, or those that presented empirical analyses of capture. This resulted in a total of 19 articles.

We used the Scielo and Google Scholar databases as a complement to this survey. Searches were carried out for the keywords “captura regulatória”, “capture”, “regulatory capture”, “regulatory policy” and “regulatory agencies”, all limited to the last five years. In the search on Google Scholar, since the volume of production is small this particular criterion was relaxed to include research with regard to Brazil that included some older publications.

In the survey involving the Google Scholar database, we decided to use only the “relevance” filter to avoid making the search very restrictive. In Scielo, the search was restricted to the following areas: Applied Social Sciences, Human Sciences, Health Sciences and Multidisciplinary Studies. The abstracts were also analyzed qualitatively to filter out works in which the focus was on regulatory capture.

We also selected publications by cross-referencing articles that had been initially selected. We included articles that had mobilized many previously selected authors and that were the basis of their discussions. This is how we selected classic texts and those from other works that are basic points of reference for the discussion and that were, perhaps, not included in the initial screening - like Stigler (1971Stigler, G. J. (1971). The Theory of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3-21.), Peltzman (1976Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a More General Theory of Regulation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211-240.) and Dal Bó (2003, 2006). We also included suggestions from anonymous reviewers. In the end, we reviewed 54 publications.

3. CAPTURE OR NON-CAPTURE?

The regulation agenda isdominated by two main explanatory streams: the public interest theory of regulation and the economic or regulatory capture theory (Levine & Forrence, 1990Levine, M. E; & Forrence, J. L. (1990). Regulatory capture, public interest, and the public agenda: Toward a synthesis. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 6, 167-198.; Melo, 2000Melo, M. A. (2000). Política regulatória: Uma revisão de literatura. BIB - Revista brasileira de informação bibliografica em ciências sociais, 50(2), 7-43.). Despite the limitations of the capture theory that are discussed in the literature (Croley, 2011Croley, S. P. (2011). Beyond capture: Towards a new theory of regulation. In D. Levi-Faur (Org.), Handbook on the politics of regulation (pp. 50-69). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing .), the phenomenon has been frequently identified in case studies in a wide variety of markets and still remains a current topic of discussion. The public interest theory of regulation suggests that the objective of regulation is to defend public interest against the actions of private interests, particularly of companies (Balla, 2011Balla, S. (2011). Institutional design and the management of regulatory governance. In D. Levi-Faur (Org.), Handbook on the Politics of Regulation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing .; Mueller, 2001Mueller, B. (2001). Regulação, informação e política: Uma resenha da teoria política positiva da regulação. Revista Brasileira de Economia de Empresas, 1, 9-29.). This approach assumes that regulators are the maximizers of social welfare. Regulating the electricity sector, for example, is justified because it is an activity whose characteristic is that of a natural monopoly.

On the other hand, the economic theory of regulation, to which Stigler-Peltzman made their influential contributions, suggests that, as in any market relationship, politicians and the regulatory elites offer regulation and organized interests demand it (Mueller, 2001Mueller, B. (2001). Regulação, informação e política: Uma resenha da teoria política positiva da regulação. Revista Brasileira de Economia de Empresas, 1, 9-29.). One of the seminal concepts of this literature is regulatory capture; regulation tends to favor those producers that are economically homogeneous and organized in smaller groups rather than diffuse, larger groups (consumers, for example).

When it comes to regulatory capture, academic production is generally divided into two forms of interpretation: broad and restrictive (Dal Bó, 2006Dal Bó, E; Dal Bó, P; & Di Tella, R. (2006). “Plata o Plomo?”: Bribe and Punishment in a Theory of Political Influence. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 41-53.). Broad interpretation not only concerns regulatory agencies, but deals with capture as a generic process in which external interests affect the State’s intervention in the economy; in other words, it has to do with the special interests that affect State intervention in all its forms, and may include areas such as taxes, the choice of foreign or monetary policy, or even the legislation that affects research and development. Restrictive interpretation, on the other hand, understands regulatory capture as being specifically those processes by which regulated agents manipulate the agencies that should exercise control over them.

Starting from this first separation of the literature, it is clear that the definition adopted by Carpenter and Moss (2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.)2 2 According to the authors, regulatory capture is a result or the process by which regulation is consistent and repeatedly moved away from public interest towards the interests of those that are regulated by the deliberate action of these same regulated bodies (p. 15). , and the criticisms resulting from their understanding of capture, come from a restrictive view of regulatory capture, and raise demands for really demonstrating capture and its mechanisms.

For these authors, the definition of capture involves not only providing evidence about diverting public interest, but also demonstrating that there is manipulation by the regulators. Although the production dealing with capture defines the concept as the exchange of favors between the regulator and the regulated (Agrell & Gautier, 2017Agrell, P. J; & Gautier, A. (2017). A theory of soft capture. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 119(3), 571-596.), the requirements in Carpenter and Moss (2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.) for confirmation of the phenomenon is much more rigorous than normally appears in the literature.

It is important to emphasize that independent agencies are subject to pressure from both regulated private sectors and from political party groups interested in implementing a short-term agenda that is contrary to public interest (Stiglitz, 1998Stiglitz, J. (1998). Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: The Private Uses of Public Interests: Incentives and Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(2), 3-22. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.12.2.3
https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.12.2.3...
): in this case, capture by regulated entities, which may occur either legislatively or administratively. Legislative capture by the private sector occurs indirectly, since these actors are not directly involved in the regulatory process. This action path involves the intermediate capture of legislators by way of private favors or benefits so that they represent the interests of the sector in the legislative process of structuring regulation, or defining the agency control mechanisms (McCubbins, Noll & Weingast, 1989McCubbins, M. D; Noll, R. G; & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies. Virginia Law Review, 75(2), 431-482. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/1073179
https://doi.org/10.2307/1073179...
). Administrative capture, in turn, occurs directly between those that are regulated and the regulators, in which the latter resort to multiple strategies to ensure mastery over the regulatory process within the agencies. This form of capture is the main object of analysis in this article and will be further developed in the following sections.

As the focus of this article is essentially a way of demonstrating capture, the production was organized on the basis of the two axes that Dal Bó (2006Dal Bó, E; Dal Bó, P; & Di Tella, R. (2006). “Plata o Plomo?”: Bribe and Punishment in a Theory of Political Influence. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 41-53.) identified; broad interpretation and restrictive interpretation. Using this separation, we prepared a comparative box of how each of these approaches copes with the phenomenon based on three main aspects: explaining capture risk, demonstrating capture, and the capture mechanisms used. Details are shown in Box 1.

Box 1
Differences between broad and restrictive approaches when studying capture

3.1 Capture strategy

Capture can be classified both by the way it occurs - the influence strategy adopted by the regulator - and by the dimension of the negative impact it has on public interest.

Regarding the way this occurs, the literature was organized into four capture mechanism niches: material incentives (Tabakovic & Wollmann, 2018Tabakovic, H; & Wollmann, T. G. (2018). From revolving doors to regulatory capture? Evidence from patent examiners. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.), information asymmetry (Agrell & Gautier, 2012Agrell, P. J; & Gautier, A. (2012). Rethinking regulatory capture. In J. E. Harrington & Y. Katsoulacos (Orgs.), Recent advances in the analysis of competition policy and regulation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing., 2017; Wagner, 2009Wagner, W. E. (2009). Administrative law, filter failure, and information capture. Duke Law Journal, 59(7), 1321-1432.), threats (Dal Bó, Dal Bó & Di Tella, 2006Dal Bó, E; Dal Bó, P; & Di Tella, R. (2006). “Plata o Plomo?”: Bribe and Punishment in a Theory of Political Influence. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 41-53.; Dal Bó & Di Tella, 2003) and immaterial incentives (Kwak, 2013Kwak, J. (2013). Cultural Capture and the Financial Crisis. In D. P. Carpenter & D. Moss (Orgs.), Preventing regulatory capture: Special interest influence and how to limit it (pp. 71-98). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press .).

Material incentives refer specifically to capture strategies that involve bribery, the exchange of favors, and the offer of positions and benefits, among others. Perhaps because of the inherent difficulty that exists in uncovering evidence of irregular payments or the exchange of favors, the literature essentially focuses on analyzing campaign financing strategies when dealing with legislative capture, or the occupation of positions involving the “revolving door” phenomenon when there is administrative capture.

The literature that points out the risks arising from information asymmetry evolves in four ways: the supply of biased information; deliberately excessive amounts of information; making the information that is provided complex; and technology capture. With regard to the first aspect, the main incentive for capture is the pressure the principal brings to bear on the agents. According to these authors, regulators agree to receive biased information from those regulated because of bribery incentives, or because of threats, as shown in Box 2.

Concerned that they might fail in its activities - not delivering new regulations - and dealing with a scenario of limited resources - especially the time needed to check all the information coming from the regulated sector - the regulator accepts distorted information from the sector in order to streamline the regulatory process (Agrell & Gautier, 2012Agrell, P. J; & Gautier, A. (2012). Rethinking regulatory capture. In J. E. Harrington & Y. Katsoulacos (Orgs.), Recent advances in the analysis of competition policy and regulation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing., 2017).

These situations are identified as soft capture. The incentive here would be, essentially, the fear of being punished by the principal, which would be constantly demanding regulatory policies. In this sense, although the ambition to maintain one’s position and advancement in one’s career is, in a way, material, it is essentially different from the direct material rewards discussed previously.

Another form of capture related to the disparity that exists in accessing information is capture by information excess, in which the regulated sector offers the regulator excessive volumes of information in order to unbalance and disorient the regulatory activity. This happens, mainly, because of an administrative failure in filtering information, which renders the regulatory process inefficient (Wagner, 2009Wagner, W. E. (2009). Administrative law, filter failure, and information capture. Duke Law Journal, 59(7), 1321-1432.).

A central element of this form of capture is that the cost of providing a large volume of information is lower for one of the parties affected by the regulatory activity; generally, a company and service provider. The other parties involved - perhaps the beneficiaries or consumers - find it difficult to compete with the same level of information and this allows the other party to become dominant in guiding the regulatory activity.

Imbalance in providing the regulator with information can also occur because of the way the information is presented. When Hakenes and Shnabel (2014Hakenes, H; & Schnabel, I. (2014). Regulatory Capture by Sophistication. CEPR Discussion Paper No . DP10100.), for example, examined capture in the financial sector in the United States, they pointed to the existence of capture by sophistication, which is the supply of extremely complex information that the regulator would have difficulty understanding. Imbalance is also caused by other players in the sector, especially the smaller ones, which have less potential for resorting to this strategy.

Another type of capture resulting from information asymmetry is technology capture, which occurs in sectors where the industry is complex, such as the chemical industry. The concept of technology capture, a term that was initially coined to define the supremacy of a market based on domination by a particular technology (Gagnon, 2016Gagnon, M. A. (2016). Shaping the social determinants of value through economic ghostmanagement. In T. H. Jo & F. S. Lee (Eds.), Marx, Veblen, and the foundations of heterodox economics: Essays in honor of John F. Henry. London, UK: Routledge.), was also expanded to include regulatory interactions. In markets of this nature, the regulated sector has mastered the technology that allows it to innovate or make incremental changes in its products that partially answer the demands of the regulator, while at the same time supplying new information about the characteristics of the product, which allows it to bargain with the agencies.

Based on a case study of the chemical industry, Finch, Geiger and Reid (2017Finch, J; Geiger, S; & Reid, E. (2017). Captured by technology? How material agency sustains interaction between regulators and industry actors. Research Policy, 46(1), 160-170. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.08.002
https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.08...
) define this relationship as an interactive and incremental process. In this process, the applied science of these industries prepares technological alternatives for facing up to regulatory demands, while producing fresh and exclusive information about new products, which allows regulation to be negotiated within the terms of the industry that is being regulated.

In cases of capture because of information asymmetry, there is no particular incentive for the regulator to benefit those being regulated, but there are incentives of another nature, be it pressure from the principal, administrative failure or little specialization.

There is also a capture scenario in which the regulator is not willing to cooperate, but ends up giving in to the regulated sector because of threats. In this case, the threats may be of a different nature, but they generally aim to damage the regulator’s reputation. Dal Bó (2003) presents this mechanism in a legislative capture situation, but the concept can be applied to other areas that also deals with administrative capture.

Immaterial incentives are related to cognitive mechanisms, such as a shared identity between the regulator and those regulated. This type of capture, which is not related to material reward, is identified in the literature as “cultural capture” (Kwak, 2013Kwak, J. (2013). Cultural Capture and the Financial Crisis. In D. P. Carpenter & D. Moss (Orgs.), Preventing regulatory capture: Special interest influence and how to limit it (pp. 71-98). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press .). Derived from discussions about cognitive capture, cultural capture occurs when the regulator personally identifies with the group of those that are regulated.

James Kwak identifies three main mechanisms by which this form of capture occurs: group identity; status and relationship networks (Kwak, 2013, p. 80). According to the author, this capture strategy may or may not happen because of deliberate action by the regulated companies. In this sense, this form of capture does not necessarily meet the third criterion established by Carpenter and Moss (2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.) with regard to the intentional action of those regulated, despite leading to the same result. The types of capture discussed so far are set out in Box 2, as are the main mechanisms involved in the process and the incentives of the regulators.

Box 2
Categorization of capture types and mechanisms

Box 2 seeks to summarize and organize the main paths that are indicated by international literature for understanding the phenomenon of capture. It is worth emphasizing, however, that the works discussed previously - and other general production about capture - are restricted to national and state-level policies. In addition, only the relationship between two parties - the regulator and those regulated - is normally examined. But recent research indicates that regulatory activity often relies on the action of a third party, an intermediary (Abbott, Levi-Faur & Snidal, 2017Abbott, K. W; Levi-Faur, D; & Snidal, D. (2017). Theorizing Regulatory Intermediaries: The RIT Model. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 670(1), 14-35. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716216688272
https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716216688272...
; Marques, 2019Marques, J. C. (2019). Private regulatory capture via harmonization: An analysis of global retailer regulatory intermediaries. Regulation & Governance, 13, 157-176. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12252
https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12252...
).

The existence of an intermediary is mainly identified in transnational contexts, in which consultancy firms, auditors, NGOs, and others3 3 The definition of regulatory intermediary is not restricted. It can be any public or private actor who interferes in the regulator-regulated relationship (Abbott et al., 2017, p. 15). frequently collaborate with companies in order to adapt their actions to suit different local contexts. In this sense, there is a third party that should also be considered in any investigation of capture.

This analysis perspective is presented in the literature as the regulatory-intermediary-target (RIT) model, and it explores both the capture of intermediaries by companies and the capture of governments by intermediaries, and vice versa (Abbott et al., 2017Abbott, K. W; Levi-Faur, D; & Snidal, D. (2017). Theorizing Regulatory Intermediaries: The RIT Model. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 670(1), 14-35. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716216688272
https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716216688272...
). This stream in the literature claims that there is a level of meta-governance in commercial relationships and, in this context, capture strategies are even more diverse, such as capture by harmonization, a form of transnational regulatory convergence that results from the action of large companies (Fransen, 2015Fransen, L. (2015). The politics of meta-governance in transnational private sustainability governance. Policy Sciences, 48(3), 293-317. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-015-9219-8
https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-015-9219-...
; Marques, 2019Marques, J. C. (2019). Private regulatory capture via harmonization: An analysis of global retailer regulatory intermediaries. Regulation & Governance, 13, 157-176. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12252
https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12252...
).

So far, what has been discussed are the various capture strategies identified in the literature, but as we pointed out earlier, capture can also be classified on the basis of the dimension of its effects. With regard to the second classification method - the impact of capture - the contribution of Carpenter and Moss (2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.) stands out. In their attempt to nuance the concept of capture in terms of the level of commitment of the regulatory activity, they identify two degrees of capture: strong capture and weak capture. Strong capture is one that compromises the results of the policy in such a way that a better outcome would be for there to be no regulation, or that the policy - or even the agency - should be substituted in its entirety. This would be a Stiglerian-type capture, which identifies a substantial decrease in public interest.4 4 Public interest is a disputed concept, and the parameter for satisfactory regulatory results must take into consideration the socioeconomic differences of the countries being analyzed. This point will be referred to again in the conclusions when discussing contemporary relationships between the state of the private sector, especially in developing countries.

For Carpenter and Moss (2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.), however, this is not the way that all capture actions develop. There are situations in which weak capture is observed, that is, the regulatory capability is compromised, but even so, the results are superior to those of a scenario in which there is no regulation.

In this sense, classification of the type of capture is a relative definition that depends on an assessment of the impact it has on the regulatory result; in other words, to identify whether a capture situation is strong or weak, we must look at the specific case and its consequences and not at the generic way in which capture took place.

3.2. Measuring capture

As was discussed previously, the capture paradox reveals how fragile the empirical framework of academic research is for supporting the capture argument (Agrell & Gautier, 2012Agrell, P. J; & Gautier, A. (2012). Rethinking regulatory capture. In J. E. Harrington & Y. Katsoulacos (Orgs.), Recent advances in the analysis of competition policy and regulation. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.; Carpenter & Moss, 2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.). While the theoretical models vary immensely, the possibilities for measuring influence and capture are restricted.

The capture research agenda is vast and investigates everything from the relationship between capture and regulatory results, and the impact of the “revolving door” on regulatory practices, to the effect of consumer pressure on regulation (Dal Bó, 2006Dal Bó, E; Dal Bó, P; & Di Tella, R. (2006). “Plata o Plomo?”: Bribe and Punishment in a Theory of Political Influence. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 41-53.). Identification of capture risks also ends up permeating various pieces of research, as does an assessment of the autonomy and transparency of regulatory processes.

Regardless of the problem that one might be seeking to confront, measuring capture is an essential step in any investigation. Most works, however, are not dedicated to demonstrating capture itself, but to mapping out the interests of those that are regulated, and the decisions that have been taken in their favor.

We can say that a large volume of production on capture is, in fact, generally geared towards identifying situations in which those that are regulated have influence potential, rather than identifying policy manipulation itself.

Among those who have attempted to identify capture empirically, the most frequent measurement strategies found in literature are: 1. Corruption measures; 2. Tracking campaign financing; and 3. Mapping out the career paths of directors/managers in order to assess the “revolving door” phenomenon - the latter being one of the most common approaches in recent studies (Dal Bó, 2006Dal Bó, E; Dal Bó, P; & Di Tella, R. (2006). “Plata o Plomo?”: Bribe and Punishment in a Theory of Political Influence. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 41-53.). Data collection methods generally involve interviews, the prosopography of regulatory agency directors, and documentary analysis of regulatory decisions.

4. CAPTURE IN BRAZILIAN REGULATORY AGENCIES

4.1. What is studied?

Despite their substantial contribution to the field, it is no easy task to demonstrate capture under the terms proposed by Carpenter and Moss (2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.). Although there is very little production on this subject involving Brazil, some researchers have ventured to explore the vulnerabilities of agencies empirically, and starting from different perspectives.5 5 As the aim of the work is to explore production relating to regulatory capture, only publications dealing with relations between agencies and the regulated market were reviewed in the section. To analyze autonomy vis-a-vis government and political influence, see Correa, Melo, Mueller and Pereira (2019) and Vieira, Gomes and Guarido (2019).

Vilarinho (2010Vilarinho, P. F. (2010). A percepção da captura política da saúde suplementar no Brasil. Cadernos EBAPE.BR, 8(4), 694-709.), for example, does a remarkable job in mapping out the interests of the various actors involved in the field of supplementary health in Brazil. Although he did not develop a model of public interest, he tried to identify the interests of the consumers of supplementary health services.

Starting with a conceptual model of active and defensive capture tactics, Vilarinho (2010Vilarinho, P. F. (2010). A percepção da captura política da saúde suplementar no Brasil. Cadernos EBAPE.BR, 8(4), 694-709.) presents a box that summarizes perceptions with regard to capture in the field of supplementary health. Despite discussing a possible change in policy in favor of private groups, such as promoting the group health plan model to the detriment of individual plans, the tactics he presented are generally only indications of the way health insurance companies work. The point raised by the author suggests the intention and political potential of the health insurance companies, but there is no strong evidence of their action, therefore it cannot be seen as a causal relationship.

Also touching only on capture potential, Ianoni (2017Ianoni, M. (2017). Interesses financeiros e captura do Estado no Brasil. Revista de Economia Política, 37(2), 324-342. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0101-31572017v37n02a04
https://doi.org/10.1590/0101-31572017v37...
) presents a case study of the Brazilian Central Bank, the National Treasury Department and the investment agency, Best Brazil, to discuss the possible capture of macroeconomic policy. The author argues that the institutionalization of relationship initiatives with investors has intensified communication between the financial market and the state. Despite drawing attention to this new channel of influence, the author’s aim is not to demonstrate actual capture.

The institutionalization of instruments that favor the regulated sector is also the subject of analysis by Milanez and Santos (2020Milanez, B. & Santos, R. S. P. (2020). Mineração e captura regulatória: A estratégia da Anglo American em Conceição do Mato Dentro (MG), Brasil. Revista Pós Ciências Sociais, 16(32), 69-91. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.18764/2236-9473.v16n32p69-91
https://doi.org/10.18764/2236-9473.v16n3...
) in the mining sector. Based on a case study of mining company Anglo American, in Minas Gerais, the authors highlight the following as being the main evidence of capture: tax exemptions; facilitating and reducing the costs of expropriating areas; the revolving door; and fractionalizing the environmental licensing process. Their work is not dedicated to exploring the motives of the agents, or to demonstrating the action of those that are regulated, but it suggests that there is an alignment between the State and the market in terms of corporate interests, which could be classified as cultural capture.

From another viewpoint, focusing on the mechanisms of social participation in the decision-making process of the agencies, Mariana Batista (2012Batista, M. (2012). Mecanismos de participação e atuação de grupos de interesse no processo regulatório brasileiro: O caso da Agência Nacional de Energia Elétrica (Aneel). Revista de Administração Pública, 46(4), 969-992.) identifies the fact that those regulated are over-represented in public hearings of the [Brazilian] National Energy Agency (Aneel). Despite this, the difference between the proportion of commentaries accepted by way of demands in public hearings is not very large between producers and consumers6 6 The absolute number of proposals presented by the producers is much larger than the number of consumers, which the author discusses as being a problem of collective action. ; 26.7% for the former and 19.9% for the latter.

Therefore, despite questioning the initial hypothesis, that those that are regulated would benefit much more than consumers, Batista (2012Batista, M. (2012). Mecanismos de participação e atuação de grupos de interesse no processo regulatório brasileiro: O caso da Agência Nacional de Energia Elétrica (Aneel). Revista de Administração Pública, 46(4), 969-992.) concentrates on discussing the agency’s vulnerability to social participation mechanisms, which could be classified as capture by information.

Other studies have chosen to explore the perspective of the agents in the agencies, and their connections with interest groups. To this end, Vieira (2015Vieira, A. S. A. (2015). Agências reguladoras independentes? Especialização e captura nas trajetórias de carreira dos reguladores federais brasileiros (Dissertação de Mestrado). Escola Brasileira de Administração Pública e de Empresas, Fundação Getulio Vargas, Rio de Janeiro, RJ.) analyzes the careers of directors and board members of ten Brazilian regulatory agencies in an attempt to explore aspects of specialization and capture by political parties. Along these same lines, De Bonis (2016De Bonis, D. F. (2016). Os limites do desenho institucional: Uma investigação empírica dos mecanismos da influência presidencial sobre as agências reguladoras independentes no Governo Federal brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Escola de Administração de Empresas de São Paulo, Fundação Getulio Vargas, São Paulo, SP.) and Peci et al. (2020Peci, A; Santos, A. M; & Araújo, B. C. P. O. (2020). Quo Vadis? Career paths of Brazilian regulators. Regulation & Governance, 1-17. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348
https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348...
) make valuable contributions to the study of the careers of regulators, but because they focus on recruitment processes and careers, their works make no attempt to look in more depth at capture demonstrations per se.

With an equal focus on individuals who held director positions at ANS, Marcello Baird (2017Baird, M. F. (2017). Redes de influência, burocracia, política e negócios na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, SP., 2019) has recently made use of documentary analysis and a network approach to map out the channels of external influence on the ANS. Baird tried to reconstitute the main disputes in the agency since it was set up, and in doing so he explored billing data, campaign financing and the structure of relationship networks. The work’s conclusions also question the growing argument about the unrestricted favoring of regulated groups, pointing to the resistance role of the specialized bureaucracy in containing external influences.

Conversely, research conducted by Carlos Ocké-Reis on ANS (Ocké-Reis et al., 2019Ocké-Reis, C. O; Fiuza, E. P. S; & Coimbra, P. H. H. (2019). Inflação dos Planos de Saúde - 2000/2018 (Nota técnica No 54). Brasília, DF: IPEA.; Ocké-Reis & Cardoso, 2011Peci, A; Santos, A. M; & Araújo, B. C. P. O. (2020). Quo Vadis? Career paths of Brazilian regulators. Regulation & Governance, 1-17. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348
https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348...
) points out that agency capture by those that are regulated is evident, especially when the organization’s inability to contain health plan premium increases is observed.7 7 Retrieved from https://www.valor.com.br/empresas/6244647/em-18-anos-preco-de-plano-de-saude-sobe-quase-o-dobro-da-inflacao The aim of these authors, however, was not to demonstrate capture actions, but to point out the clear benefits enjoyed by regulated groups. The specific case of ANS will be discussed later when the strategies of each study will be compared in more depth.

In this brief summary of the production that deals with capture in Brazilian agencies, it is clear that there is a diversity of results and that the scope of the research varies substantially. It is possible to note, however, that most of this research focuses on identifying potential capture risk scenarios and their possible effects (such as an increase in health insurance premiums, and participation asymmetry in regulatory activity, among others).

Production dealing with the case of Brazil has generally made no effort to examine the mechanisms by which capture may have happened in the agencies. It is clear, therefore, that there is a vast unexplored field involving the relationships that exist between the State and the market in regulatory agencies. While the revolving door is the most recurrent capture mechanism, cultural capture and threat dimensions and multiple forms of information asymmetry remain little explored in the Brazilian context.

We can say, therefore, that this literature largely starts with a broad approach to capture, in which a detailed demonstration of mechanisms is not at the heart of the matter. The establishment of more restrictive criteria for establishing capture can, however, lead to variations in the interpretation of the phenomenon. An example of this is the case of ANS, which will be discussed in the following subsection.

4.2 The case of the ANS: where do differences in the results come from?

Brazil has one of the largest public health systems in the world. Despite this, approximately 25% of the Brazilian population has private health insurance cover, particularly by way of collective agreements (i.e., as part of a package of benefits provided by employers). The main regulations relating to the supplementary health sector are Law No. 9656/98, which establishes the rules for the sector’s operations, and Law No. 9961/2000, which instituted the Brazilian Supplementary Health Agency (ANS) that has powers to regulate and supervise health insurance companies, including with regard to premium adjustments and the minimum right to care of the beneficiaries of health plans, and the list of health procedures and events covered (Costa, 2008Costa, N. R. (2008). O regime regulatório e o mercado de planos de saúde no Brasil. Ciência & Saúde Coletiva, 13(5), 1453-1462. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1413-81232008000500011
https://doi.org/10.1590/S1413-8123200800...
).

The growth of the supplementary health sector is usually attributed to a growing demand from a population that is dissatisfied with the services of the SUS [Unified Health System - Brazilian public health care system], a concept known as exclusionary universalization, or the “unwanted child” of the Health Reform bill that instituted the Public Health System (Favaret & Oliveira, 1990Favaret, P Filho; & Oliveira, P. J. (1990). A universalização excludente: Reflexões sobre as tendências do sistema de saúde. Planejamento e Políticas Públicas, 3, 139-162.). The demands of consumers - both in the media and in the judiciary - dissatisfied with the decisions taken by insurance companies and health plans to increase premiums and impose cover restrictions, prompted the federal executive to expand and propose new regulatory bases for the sector. According to Pereira (2003Pereira, C. (2003). O marco regulatório no setor de saúde suplementar: Contextualização e perspectivas. In J. Montone & A. J. W. Castro (Orgs.), Regulação e Saúde (pp. 93-120). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar.), choosing an independent regulatory agency model was a form of organizational innovation for regulating a sector that, until then, had been responsible for generating increasing political “wear and tear” on the federal executive. It was also a way of transferring responsibilities for any potential new problems to this autonomous bureaucratic body.

Since then, the case of supplementary health care in Brazil has been emblematic and is the focus of most of the research into regulation in the country (Costa, 2008Costa, N. R. (2008). O regime regulatório e o mercado de planos de saúde no Brasil. Ciência & Saúde Coletiva, 13(5), 1453-1462. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1413-81232008000500011
https://doi.org/10.1590/S1413-8123200800...
; Pereira, 2003Pereira, C. (2003). O marco regulatório no setor de saúde suplementar: Contextualização e perspectivas. In J. Montone & A. J. W. Castro (Orgs.), Regulação e Saúde (pp. 93-120). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar.; Pietrobon, Prado & Caetano, 2008Pietrobon, L; Prado, M. L; & Caetano, J. C. (2008). Saúde suplementar no Brasil: O papel da Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar na regulação do setor. Physis: Revista de Saúde Coletiva, 18(4), 767-783. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-73312008000400009
https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-7331200800...
; Salvatori & Ventura, 2012Salvatori, R. T; & Ventura, C. A. A. (2012). A Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar - ANS: Onze anos de regulação dos planos de saúde. Organizações & Sociedade, 19(62), 471-488. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1984-92302012000300006
https://doi.org/10.1590/S1984-9230201200...
; Sestelo, Souza & Bahia, 2014Sestelo, J. A. de F; Souza, L. E. P. F. de & Bahia, L. (2014). Saúde suplementar no Brasil: Revisão crítica da literatura de 2000 a 2010. Saúde em Debate, 38(102). Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.5935/0103-1104.20140056
https://doi.org/10.5935/0103-1104.201400...
). The findings of the studies that are interested in the political economics of supplementary health care regulation generally point to the capture risk and meeting the demands of the regulated sectors to the detriment of the user.

A recent technical note from the Institute for Applied Economic Research, (IPEA) (Ocké-Reis et al., 2019Ocké-Reis, C. O; Fiuza, E. P. S; & Coimbra, P. H. H. (2019). Inflação dos Planos de Saúde - 2000/2018 (Nota técnica No 54). Brasília, DF: IPEA.), ignited the debate about capture ofthe National Supplementary Health Agency (ANS) when it questioned the methodology used for calculating the way plans are adjusted. The researchers pointed out that the accumulated inflation of the plans was much higher than the general rate of inflation, and than the medical sector rate, specifically. Their conclusion, that the ANS is incapable of regulating the inflation in health care plans, supports the perception of capture. This analysis arouses the suspicion of capture that comes from previous works, which address everything from the price of the plans (Ocké-Reis & Cardoso, 2011Ocké-Reis, C. O; Fiuza, E. P. S; & Coimbra, P. H. H. (2019). Inflação dos Planos de Saúde - 2000/2018 (Nota técnica No 54). Brasília, DF: IPEA.), and the latent interests in dispute at the agency (Vilarinho, 2010Vilarinho, P. F. (2010). A percepção da captura política da saúde suplementar no Brasil. Cadernos EBAPE.BR, 8(4), 694-709.), to the financing of electoral campaigns by health plan companies, which would suggest legislative capture (Scheffer & Bahia, 2011Scheffer, M; & Bahia, L. (2011). Representação política e interesses particulares na saúde: O caso do financiamento de campanhas eleitorais pelas empresas de planos de saúde privados no Brasil. Interface - Comunicação, Saúde, Educação, 15(38), 947-956. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1414-32832011000300030
https://doi.org/10.1590/S1414-3283201100...
, 2013Scheffer, M; & Bahia, L. (2013). O financiamento de campanhas pelos planos e seguros de saúde nas eleições de 2010. Saúde em Debate, 37(96), 96-103. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-11042013000100011
https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-1104201300...
).

Nevertheless, when researching the networks of political influence in the ANS since its creation, Marcello Baird (2017Baird, M. F. (2017). Redes de influência, burocracia, política e negócios na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, SP., 2019Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295.) comes to differing conclusions about the agency’s capture. In a detailed analysis of the ANS’s actions between 2000 and 2014, mainly by way of network analysis, interviews and documentary analysis, the author found no evidence of targeted action by the regulators to manipulate the sector’s policies or force the deregulation of supplementary health care.

Conversely, he observed that the period when the agency’s executive board had a greater connection with the business community was when there was greater regulation of the health care sector (Baird, 2019Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295., p. 23), with increased transparency for consumers, an expansion of waiting period portability, the implementation of the risk pool to stabilize adjustments for the beneficiaries of collective health plans, and the establishment of maximum periods of care cover, among others.

With regard to concentration in the industry, and specifically the sale of Amil in 2012 - the largest transaction in the sector - Baird points out that, despite the speed with which the ANS authorized the sale, the measure was not unprecedented and there was no change in any of the rules in the period that exclusively favored the companies involved (Baird, 2019Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295., p. 21).

Understanding the weakness of this argument, Baird (2019Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295.) proposed an analysis of the “revolving door” phenomenon to examine whether members of the ANS’s executive board who were linked to the regulated sector had a distinct voting pattern. Yet again, no evidence was found to support the capture argument.

In examining the “revolving door” phenomenon, one of the relevant contributions of Baird (2019Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295.) was his effort to add nuances to his analyses of the possible effects of this exchange of positions. In examining the voting pattern of directors with regard to normative resolutions, Baird identified that there was little disagreement between the “public health specialists” and the “liberals” within the agency. This reveals the fragility of the explanatory potential of the revolving door analyses when conducted in a way that is disassociated from examining the political actions of the actors.

It is important to highlight that Baird’s empirical findings (2017Baird, M. F. (2017). Redes de influência, burocracia, política e negócios na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, SP., 2019Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295.) are presented as influence potential and not capture. Since the work starts with a more restrictive view of capture and no process was identified that revealed the manipulation of those that are regulated, the use of the influence concept is appropriate.

In this sense, the research raised situations of conflict and recognized the existence of measures that favored the regulated sector but found no evidence of deliberate actions by companies. There is also no absence of measures favoring the beneficiaries that resulted in high costs for the health insurance companies.

At this point it is clear that one element that differentiates the research into ANS capture is the operationalization of the capture concept. As was previously discussed, the distinction between broad and restrictive approaches can be valuable for understanding the disagreements that exist in the conclusions reached regarding the case of supplementary health care in Brazil.

The findings that support the capture argument emphasize the benefits that have been enjoyed by the regulated sector in a broad scenario, especially with regard to the adjustment of plans (Ocké-Reis et al., 2019Ocké-Reis, C. O; Fiuza, E. P. S; & Coimbra, P. H. H. (2019). Inflação dos Planos de Saúde - 2000/2018 (Nota técnica No 54). Brasília, DF: IPEA.; Ocké-Reis & Cardoso, 2011Peci, A; Santos, A. M; & Araújo, B. C. P. O. (2020). Quo Vadis? Career paths of Brazilian regulators. Regulation & Governance, 1-17. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348
https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348...
). These works, however, tend to minimize the agency’s decisions in favor of the beneficiaries and to the detriment of the health insurance companies, as in the case of the establishment of maximum period of care and other decisions that were very costly for the sector.

The results that were found using a broad approach do not analyze the process, reconstitute the decision history or seek to identify the causal mechanisms that justify the capture argument. Ocké-Reis (2019Ocké-Reis, C. O; Fiuza, E. P. S; & Coimbra, P. H. H. (2019). Inflação dos Planos de Saúde - 2000/2018 (Nota técnica No 54). Brasília, DF: IPEA., 2011Peci, A; Santos, A. M; & Araújo, B. C. P. O. (2020). Quo Vadis? Career paths of Brazilian regulators. Regulation & Governance, 1-17. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348
https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348...
) and Vilarinho (2010Vilarinho, P. F. (2010). A percepção da captura política da saúde suplementar no Brasil. Cadernos EBAPE.BR, 8(4), 694-709.) do not suggest or test an action model for those that are regulated, nor do they add any evidence about the agency’s decision-making processes. Likewise, the works of Scheffer and Bahia (2011Scheffer, M; & Bahia, L. (2011). Representação política e interesses particulares na saúde: O caso do financiamento de campanhas eleitorais pelas empresas de planos de saúde privados no Brasil. Interface - Comunicação, Saúde, Educação, 15(38), 947-956. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1414-32832011000300030
https://doi.org/10.1590/S1414-3283201100...
, 2013Scheffer, M; & Bahia, L. (2011). Representação política e interesses particulares na saúde: O caso do financiamento de campanhas eleitorais pelas empresas de planos de saúde privados no Brasil. Interface - Comunicação, Saúde, Educação, 15(38), 947-956. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1414-32832011000300030
https://doi.org/10.1590/S1414-3283201100...
) make no connection between campaign financing for elected politicians with their actual performance in parliament and executive office. It is not generally the purpose of these works to examine capture mechanisms in detail. This is essentially the concern of the restrictive approach to the subject, to which Baird’s work (2017Baird, M. F. (2017). Redes de influência, burocracia, política e negócios na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, SP., 2019Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295.) is linked.

Despite not proposing a model of public interest in the terms proposed by Carpenter and Moss (2013Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.), Baird (2017Baird, M. F. (2017). Redes de influência, burocracia, política e negócios na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, SP., 2019Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295.) faces up to the process investigation that could reveal the actions of those that are regulated that are oriented towards altering the direction of regulatory policy. His conclusions do not examine the merit of judging whether plan adjustments are excessive or not, but he reveals the absence of any evidence to support identification of the capture phenomenon itself.

5. FINAL CONSIDERATIONS

Sartori (1970Sartori, G. (1970). Concept Misformation in Comparative Politics. The American Political Science Review, 64(4), 1033-1053.) warned us about the importance of being careful when conceptualizing a social phenomenon a few decades ago. Correct definition of the concepts is the main guide for correctly applying the method and supporting the inferences.

With its focus on the concept of capture and its various mechanisms, this article is committed to this task. Throughout the article we sought to organize the main forms of regulatory capture identified by the literature, and the mechanisms that are associated with the phenomenon. Although there is great diversity in the capture strategies presented, we identified four major groups of capture: capture by material incentives; capture by immaterial incentives; capture by threat; and capture by asymmetric information.

With regard to the definition and operationalization of the concept of capture, we revisited Dal Bó’s (2006Dal Bó, E; Dal Bó, P; & Di Tella, R. (2006). “Plata o Plomo?”: Bribe and Punishment in a Theory of Political Influence. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 41-53.) discussion of the existence of broad and restrictive approaches to the phenomenon. The main differences between the two views were detailed and, from analysis of the ANS case in Brazil, we concluded that the starting approach is an important element for explaining the contradictory results evidenced by the literature (Baird, 2017Baird, M. F. (2017). Redes de influência, burocracia, política e negócios na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, SP., 2019; Ocké-Reis et al., 2019Ocké-Reis, C. O; Fiuza, E. P. S; & Coimbra, P. H. H. (2019). Inflação dos Planos de Saúde - 2000/2018 (Nota técnica No 54). Brasília, DF: IPEA.; Ocké-Reis & Cardoso, 2011Peci, A; Santos, A. M; & Araújo, B. C. P. O. (2020). Quo Vadis? Career paths of Brazilian regulators. Regulation & Governance, 1-17. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348
https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348...
).

We also identified that most studies on Brazilian regulatory agencies start with a broad approach to capture, without any concern with regard to demonstrating the causal mechanisms that might explain the capture actions adopted by those that are regulated. This shows that there is an abundance of unexplored paths in the study of regulation in Brazil.

Finally, this study leaves an additional suggestion for researchers who are interested in the subject of regulatory capture; when studying this phenomenon they should prioritize alternative approaches that go beyond the economic theory of regulation. Capture literature is generally seen as being essentially a negative aspect of the relationship between markets and governments, which materializes as a risk to democratic legitimacy and institutional accountability (Thaw, 2014Thaw, D. (2014). Enlightened Regulatory Capture. Washington Law Review, 89, 329-377., p. 335). Despite the recurrent and contemporaneous nature of the agenda, however, this negative view and the very concept of capture are questioned by a stream that proposes alternative explanations of the relationship between State and market. This literature suggests two main interpretations of this relationship: 1. the State as a driver of corporate lobbying; and 2. the State acting cooperatively with regulated sectors.

Based on case studies in the telecommunications and aviation sectors, Cornelia Woll (2008Woll, C. (2008). Firm interests: How governments shape business lobbying on global trade. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.) discusses the first interpretation - the opposite path to capture - in which the State motivates changes in the lobby of those that are regulated instead of the lobby changing public policy. Recognizing the limitations of economic theory, Woll (2008) suggests other explanatory variables for the change in the regulatory lobby. According to her, the new institutions created by the State altered the preference of companies and this redefinition particularly changed the ideas they had about their identity and the beliefs they had about their international operations.

Also with regard to the role of the private sector in convergence with public interest, and based on a case study in the cybersecurity area, Thaw (2014Thaw, D. (2014). Enlightened Regulatory Capture. Washington Law Review, 89, 329-377.) discusses the process he identifies as enlightened regulatory capture, in which capture mechanisms are used by companies to achieve public and private objectives, even though this is costly for them.

In another influential work, Woll and Artigas (2007Woll, C; & Artigas, A. (2007). When trade liberalization turns into regulatory reform: The impact on business-government relations in international trade politics. Regulation & Governance, 1(2), 121-138.) point out that the State and the market interact in terms of regulatory policies - a discussion that initially appears in the literature with the normative proposal of “negotiated regulation” (Harter, 1983Harter, P. J. (1983). The Political Legitimacy and Judicial Review of Consensual Rules. American University Law Review, 32, 471.). To explore the issue, the authors suggest that the regulatory lobby is essentially different from the pressure lobby, because the former requires the constant building of company reputations and legitimacy vis-à-vis governments, and this is incompatible, therefore, with the predatory view of capture.

In this sense, Levi-Faur (2013Levi-Faur, D. (2013). The Odyssey of the Regulatory State: From a “Thin” Monomorphic Concept to a “Thick” and Polymorphic Concept. Law & Policy, 35(1-2), 29-50. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/lapo.12000
https://doi.org/10.1111/lapo.12000...
) suggests the concept of a regulatory State for development, an attempt to reconcile regulatory studies with the literature about the developmental state, in which developing countries could benefit from the autonomy model in State−Society relations (Evans, 1995Evans, P. (1995). Embedded autonomy: States and industrial transformation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.). In other words, particularly in the context of developing countries such as Brazil, the concept of regulatory capture is insufficient for explaining these contemporary capitalist relations.

The study by Shadlen and Fonseca (2013Shadlen, K. C; & Fonseca, E. M. (2013). Health Policy as Industrial Policy: Brazil in Comparative Perspective. Politics & Society, 41(4), 561-587. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329213507552
https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329213507552...
), for example, shows how the National Health Surveillance Agency acted in a “guardianship” process when it helped private actors acquire the capabilities needed to survive the new regulations, which were aimed at increasing competition in the pharmaceutical market and, consequently, reducing the price of medicines. In acquiring these new skills, companies changed their preferences in relation to the regulation, which they were previously opposed to. Therefore, an important agenda in the regulatory literature is to reflect on this multidimension quality of public interest, and to foster greater dialogue between scholars of the regulatory and developmental states (Amann, 2006Amann, E. (2006). Regulating development: Evidence from Africa and Latin America. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing .; Dubash & Morgan, 2012Dubash, N. K; & Morgan, B. (2012). Understanding the rise of the regulatory state of the South. Regulation & Governance, 6(3), 261-281. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1748-5991.2012.01146.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1748-5991.2012...
).

An important point about this alternative literature is that, despite offering robust explanations of cases that are not clarified by economic theory, its findings are not necessarily incompatible with findings of capture. It also allows an application that is more appropriate to the context of countries from the Global South, the scenarios of which differ from those in the United States and countries in the European Union in various political and economic aspects. In this sense, it is doubtful whether one can simply import theories into developing countries, such as the Capture Theory, that have been developed to explain phenomena that occur in developed countries (Amann, 2006Amann, E. (2006). Regulating development: Evidence from Africa and Latin America. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing .; Dubash & Morgan, 2012Dubash, N. K; & Morgan, B. (2012). Understanding the rise of the regulatory state of the South. Regulation & Governance, 6(3), 261-281. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1748-5991.2012.01146.x
https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1748-5991.2012...
).

Therefore, studies such as the one by Woll and Levi-Faur make room for a new agenda on relations between the State and the market and their applications in developing countries, which is also little explored. This could be an investigation into which factors lead to cooperation and which factors lead to regulatory capture. In this sense, we understand that identifying the mechanisms that materialize capture, and not just an analysis of the results of the regulatory process, is an important undertaking for connecting the discussion about the relational context of regulatory agencies and the economic development agenda.

Identifying these characteristics and the remarks about measuring capture that were discussed in this article, therefore, have not only theoretical implications, but practical ones also. There is a growing interest in the study of regulatory agencies in Brazil due to the environment of political dispute that has emerged in these organizations and the public policy implications of the relationships between the State and the market. Considering how relevant the agenda is to the academic community and for instructing the actions of public administration, the conceptual rigor and adequacy of its applications is what allows us, therefore, to move from mere impressions of the subject to a more robust demonstration of the phenomenon.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

IAL holds a teaching assistant scholarship at the São Paulo School of Business Administration of the Fundação Getulio Vargas (FGV EAESP). EMF receives financial assistance from Fapesp (2015/18604-5), the CNPq (407382/2018-6) and FGV’s Applied Research Network.

REFERÊNCIAS

  • Abbott, K. W; Levi-Faur, D; & Snidal, D. (2017). Theorizing Regulatory Intermediaries: The RIT Model. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 670(1), 14-35. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716216688272
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0002716216688272
  • Agrell, P. J; & Gautier, A. (2012). Rethinking regulatory capture. In J. E. Harrington & Y. Katsoulacos (Orgs.), Recent advances in the analysis of competition policy and regulation Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.
  • Agrell, P. J; & Gautier, A. (2017). A theory of soft capture. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 119(3), 571-596.
  • Amann, E. (2006). Regulating development: Evidence from Africa and Latin America Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing .
  • Baird, M. F. (2017). Redes de influência, burocracia, política e negócios na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (Tese de Doutorado). Universidade de São Paulo, São Paulo, SP.
  • Baird, M. F. (2019). Da Hegemonia Sanitarista ao Predomínio Liberal: investigando os fatores que impediram uma inflexão liberal na Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar (ANS) (2004-2014). Dados, 62(4), e20180295.
  • Balla, S. (2011). Institutional design and the management of regulatory governance. In D. Levi-Faur (Org.), Handbook on the Politics of Regulation Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing .
  • Batista, M. (2012). Mecanismos de participação e atuação de grupos de interesse no processo regulatório brasileiro: O caso da Agência Nacional de Energia Elétrica (Aneel). Revista de Administração Pública, 46(4), 969-992.
  • Carpenter, D; & Moss, D. (2013). Preventing Regulatory Capture: Special Interest Influence and How to Limit it Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.
  • Correa, P; Melo, M; Mueller, B; & Pereira, C. (2019). Political interference and regulatory resilience in Brazil. Regulation & Governance, 13(4), 540-560. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12274
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12274
  • Costa, N. R. (2008). O regime regulatório e o mercado de planos de saúde no Brasil. Ciência & Saúde Coletiva, 13(5), 1453-1462. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1413-81232008000500011
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S1413-81232008000500011
  • Croley, S. P. (2011). Beyond capture: Towards a new theory of regulation. In D. Levi-Faur (Org.), Handbook on the politics of regulation (pp. 50-69). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing .
  • Dal Bó, E. (2006). Regulatory capture: A review. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(2), 203-225. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/grj013
    » https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/grj013
  • Dal Bó, E; Dal Bó, P; & Di Tella, R. (2006). “Plata o Plomo?”: Bribe and Punishment in a Theory of Political Influence. American Political Science Review, 100(1), 41-53.
  • Dal Bó , E ; &Di Tella, R . (2003). Capture by Threat. Journal of Political Economy, 111(5), 1123-1154.
  • De Bonis, D. F. (2016). Os limites do desenho institucional: Uma investigação empírica dos mecanismos da influência presidencial sobre as agências reguladoras independentes no Governo Federal brasileiro (Tese de Doutorado). Escola de Administração de Empresas de São Paulo, Fundação Getulio Vargas, São Paulo, SP.
  • Dubash, N. K; & Morgan, B. (2012). Understanding the rise of the regulatory state of the South. Regulation & Governance, 6(3), 261-281. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1748-5991.2012.01146.x
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1748-5991.2012.01146.x
  • Evans, P. (1995). Embedded autonomy: States and industrial transformation Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
  • Favaret, P Filho; & Oliveira, P. J. (1990). A universalização excludente: Reflexões sobre as tendências do sistema de saúde. Planejamento e Políticas Públicas, 3, 139-162.
  • Finch, J; Geiger, S; & Reid, E. (2017). Captured by technology? How material agency sustains interaction between regulators and industry actors. Research Policy, 46(1), 160-170. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.08.002
    » https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2016.08.002
  • Fransen, L. (2015). The politics of meta-governance in transnational private sustainability governance. Policy Sciences, 48(3), 293-317. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-015-9219-8
    » https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-015-9219-8
  • Gagnon, M. A. (2016). Shaping the social determinants of value through economic ghostmanagement. In T. H. Jo & F. S. Lee (Eds.), Marx, Veblen, and the foundations of heterodox economics: Essays in honor of John F. Henry London, UK: Routledge.
  • Hakenes, H; & Schnabel, I. (2014). Regulatory Capture by Sophistication. CEPR Discussion Paper No . DP10100
  • Harter, P. J. (1983). The Political Legitimacy and Judicial Review of Consensual Rules. American University Law Review, 32, 471.
  • Ianoni, M. (2017). Interesses financeiros e captura do Estado no Brasil. Revista de Economia Política, 37(2), 324-342. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/0101-31572017v37n02a04
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/0101-31572017v37n02a04
  • Kwak, J. (2013). Cultural Capture and the Financial Crisis. In D. P. Carpenter & D. Moss (Orgs.), Preventing regulatory capture: Special interest influence and how to limit it (pp. 71-98). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press .
  • Levi-Faur, D. (2013). The Odyssey of the Regulatory State: From a “Thin” Monomorphic Concept to a “Thick” and Polymorphic Concept. Law & Policy, 35(1-2), 29-50. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/lapo.12000
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/lapo.12000
  • Levine, M. E; & Forrence, J. L. (1990). Regulatory capture, public interest, and the public agenda: Toward a synthesis. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 6, 167-198.
  • Marques, J. C. (2019). Private regulatory capture via harmonization: An analysis of global retailer regulatory intermediaries. Regulation & Governance, 13, 157-176. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12252
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12252
  • McCubbins, M. D; Noll, R. G; & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Structure and Process, Politics and Policy: Administrative Arrangements and the Political Control of Agencies. Virginia Law Review, 75(2), 431-482. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.2307/1073179
    » https://doi.org/10.2307/1073179
  • Melo, M. A. (2000). Política regulatória: Uma revisão de literatura. BIB - Revista brasileira de informação bibliografica em ciências sociais, 50(2), 7-43.
  • Milanez, B. & Santos, R. S. P. (2020). Mineração e captura regulatória: A estratégia da Anglo American em Conceição do Mato Dentro (MG), Brasil. Revista Pós Ciências Sociais, 16(32), 69-91. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.18764/2236-9473.v16n32p69-91
    » https://doi.org/10.18764/2236-9473.v16n32p69-91
  • Mueller, B. (2001). Regulação, informação e política: Uma resenha da teoria política positiva da regulação. Revista Brasileira de Economia de Empresas, 1, 9-29.
  • Ocké-Reis, C. O; & Cardoso, S. S. (2011). A regulamentação dos preços dos planos individuais de saúde. Revista de Economia Política, 31(3), 455-470. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0101-31572011000300008
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S0101-31572011000300008
  • Ocké-Reis, C. O; Fiuza, E. P. S; & Coimbra, P. H. H. (2019). Inflação dos Planos de Saúde - 2000/2018 (Nota técnica No 54). Brasília, DF: IPEA.
  • Peci, A; Santos, A. M; & Araújo, B. C. P. O. (2020). Quo Vadis? Career paths of Brazilian regulators. Regulation & Governance, 1-17. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348
    » https://doi.org/10.1111/rego.12348
  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a More General Theory of Regulation. The Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211-240.
  • Pereira, C. (2003). O marco regulatório no setor de saúde suplementar: Contextualização e perspectivas. In J. Montone & A. J. W. Castro (Orgs.), Regulação e Saúde (pp. 93-120). Rio de Janeiro, RJ: Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar.
  • Pietrobon, L; Prado, M. L; & Caetano, J. C. (2008). Saúde suplementar no Brasil: O papel da Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar na regulação do setor. Physis: Revista de Saúde Coletiva, 18(4), 767-783. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-73312008000400009
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-73312008000400009
  • Salvatori, R. T; & Ventura, C. A. A. (2012). A Agência Nacional de Saúde Suplementar - ANS: Onze anos de regulação dos planos de saúde. Organizações & Sociedade, 19(62), 471-488. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1984-92302012000300006
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S1984-92302012000300006
  • Sartori, G. (1970). Concept Misformation in Comparative Politics. The American Political Science Review, 64(4), 1033-1053.
  • Scheffer, M; & Bahia, L. (2011). Representação política e interesses particulares na saúde: O caso do financiamento de campanhas eleitorais pelas empresas de planos de saúde privados no Brasil. Interface - Comunicação, Saúde, Educação, 15(38), 947-956. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S1414-32832011000300030
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S1414-32832011000300030
  • Scheffer, M; & Bahia, L. (2013). O financiamento de campanhas pelos planos e seguros de saúde nas eleições de 2010. Saúde em Debate, 37(96), 96-103. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-11042013000100011
    » https://doi.org/10.1590/S0103-11042013000100011
  • Sestelo, J. A. de F; Souza, L. E. P. F. de & Bahia, L. (2014). Saúde suplementar no Brasil: Revisão crítica da literatura de 2000 a 2010. Saúde em Debate, 38(102). Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.5935/0103-1104.20140056
    » https://doi.org/10.5935/0103-1104.20140056
  • Shadlen, K. C; & Fonseca, E. M. (2013). Health Policy as Industrial Policy: Brazil in Comparative Perspective. Politics & Society, 41(4), 561-587. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329213507552
    » https://doi.org/10.1177/0032329213507552
  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The Theory of Economic Regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3-21.
  • Stiglitz, J. (1998). Distinguished Lecture on Economics in Government: The Private Uses of Public Interests: Incentives and Institutions. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12(2), 3-22. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.12.2.3
    » https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.12.2.3
  • Tabakovic, H; & Wollmann, T. G. (2018). From revolving doors to regulatory capture? Evidence from patent examiners Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.
  • Thaw, D. (2014). Enlightened Regulatory Capture. Washington Law Review, 89, 329-377.
  • Vasconcelos, G. (2019, maio 08). Em 18 anos preço de plano de saúde sobre quase o dobro da inflação. Valor Econômico Recuperado de https://www.valor.com.br/empresas/6244647/em-18-anos-preco-de-plano-de-saude-sobe-quase-o-dobro-da-inflacao
    » https://www.valor.com.br/empresas/6244647/em-18-anos-preco-de-plano-de-saude-sobe-quase-o-dobro-da-inflacao
  • Vieira, A. S. A. (2015). Agências reguladoras independentes? Especialização e captura nas trajetórias de carreira dos reguladores federais brasileiros (Dissertação de Mestrado). Escola Brasileira de Administração Pública e de Empresas, Fundação Getulio Vargas, Rio de Janeiro, RJ.
  • Vieira, J. N. S; Gomes, R. C; & Guarido, E. R Filho . (2019). Avaliação da independência das agências reguladoras dos setores de energia elétrica, telecomunicações e petróleo no Brasil. Revista do Serviço Público, 70(4), 576-607. Recuperado de https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v70i4.3512
    » https://doi.org/10.21874/rsp.v70i4.3512
  • Vilarinho, P. F. (2010). A percepção da captura política da saúde suplementar no Brasil. Cadernos EBAPE.BR, 8(4), 694-709.
  • Wagner, W. E. (2009). Administrative law, filter failure, and information capture. Duke Law Journal, 59(7), 1321-1432.
  • Woll, C. (2008). Firm interests: How governments shape business lobbying on global trade Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
  • Woll, C; & Artigas, A. (2007). When trade liberalization turns into regulatory reform: The impact on business-government relations in international trade politics. Regulation & Governance, 1(2), 121-138.
  • 1
    For a more in-depth debate on this point, see the Introduction of Carpenter and Moss (2013).
  • 2
    According to the authors, regulatory capture is a result or the process by which regulation is consistent and repeatedly moved away from public interest towards the interests of those that are regulated by the deliberate action of these same regulated bodies (p. 15).
  • 3
    The definition of regulatory intermediary is not restricted. It can be any public or private actor who interferes in the regulator-regulated relationship (Abbott et al., 2017, p. 15).
  • 4
    Public interest is a disputed concept, and the parameter for satisfactory regulatory results must take into consideration the socioeconomic differences of the countries being analyzed. This point will be referred to again in the conclusions when discussing contemporary relationships between the state of the private sector, especially in developing countries.
  • 5
    As the aim of the work is to explore production relating to regulatory capture, only publications dealing with relations between agencies and the regulated market were reviewed in the section. To analyze autonomy vis-a-vis government and political influence, see Correa, Melo, Mueller and Pereira (2019) and Vieira, Gomes and Guarido (2019).
  • 6
    The absolute number of proposals presented by the producers is much larger than the number of consumers, which the author discusses as being a problem of collective action.
  • 7
    Retrieved from https://www.valor.com.br/empresas/6244647/em-18-anos-preco-de-plano-de-saude-sobe-quase-o-dobro-da-inflacao
  • [Translated version] Note: All quotes in English translated by this article’s translator.

Publication Dates

  • Publication in this collection
    09 July 2021
  • Date of issue
    May-Jun 2021

History

  • Received
    27 May 2020
  • Accepted
    17 Sept 2020
Fundação Getulio Vargas Fundaçãoo Getulio Vargas, Rua Jornalista Orlando Dantas, 30, CEP: 22231-010 / Rio de Janeiro-RJ Brasil, Tel.: +55 (21) 3083-2731 - Rio de Janeiro - RJ - Brazil
E-mail: rap@fgv.br